C.10. Import Penetration of Goods and Services Sources

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

C.10. Import Penetration of Goods and Services Sources C. INTERNATIONAL TRADE OF GOODS AND SERVICES C.10. Import penetration of goods and services ■ The highest penetration of imports of goods and for Ireland (–22 percentage points from 2000) and services is observed in smaller countries such as Canada (–8 percentage points). For these countries the Luxembourg (import penetration rate of 218% reason was not decreasing import values but the fact in 2007), Belgium (88%), the Slovak Republic (86%), that their gross domestic product (GDP) increased Hungary (80%) and Ireland (78%). Import penetration significantly more than the value of imports. The is lowest in larger countries such as the Japan (16.2%) opposite was true for the Slovak Republic, where and the United States (16.4%). imports increased more than GDP. ■ Among OECD accession countries, Estonia had the ■ The import penetration rates for trade of services highest import penetration rate (77% in 2007), show Luxembourg to have by far the highest degree of followed by Slovenia (70%). While the import import penetration (150%, up by 55 percentage points penetration rates of Slovenia, Israel and Chile from 2000). The OECD countries with the lowest increased between 2000 and 2007, the rates of Estonia import penetration of services were Mexico (1.6%), and especially of the Russian Federation decreased. Turkey (2%), the United States (2.7%) and Japan (3%). ■ Of the OECD enhanced engagement countries, China had the highest import penetration rate (35% in 2007, up by 13 percentage points from 2000), Sources followed by South Africa (33%). India’s import •OECD, Trade Indicators Database, May 2009. penetration rate also showed a rather strong increase • United Nations Statistics Division, National Accounts (25% in 2007, up by 12 percentage points from 2000). Main Aggregates Database, 2009. ■ Import penetration rates for goods from OECD For further reading countries for 2000 and 2007 show that the Slovak • OECD Trade Indicators, www.oecd.org/std/its/ Republic had the highest import penetration rate (78% tradeindicators. in 2007, up by 16 percentage points from 2000). • United Nations Statistics Division, National Accounts Distinct negative changes in the ratios were observed Main Aggregates Database, unstats.un.org/unsd/snaama. The rate of import penetration The rate of import penetration (MPij) for a country i and a product j corresponds to the share of domestic demand (Dij) in country i for product j, which is met by imports Mij. MPij = 100 Mij/Dij. If P, X and M stand respectively for a country’s output, export and imports, its domestic demand, D will be equal to D = P – X + M and then the import penetration in country i for product j will be MPij = 100 Mij/(Pij – Xij+ Mij). Competitiveness on the domestic market, as measured by the rate of import penetration, is based on the notion that a national industry endeavours to win, or at least keep, its shares in its own market. A low import penetration rate does not necessarily reflect import barriers but may be due to a good matching of output to domestic demand by highly competitive domestic firms capable of confronting foreign competition. Conversely, a high import penetration rate may reflect weak competitiveness on the part of domestic firms, especially when the export ratio is low. The size of the countries involved is also very important. The level of import penetration is usually greater in small countries because they are more open to the world economy and because of the way they specialise. As they are unable to specialise in many sectors, they become more dependent on imports. In the longer term, however, if the import penetration rate rises faster than domestic demand and is not accompanied by equivalent gains in export markets, this could indicate some deterioration of competitiveness. 76 OECD ECONOMIC GLOBALISATION INDICATORS © OECD 2010 C. INTERNATIONAL TRADE OF GOODS AND SERVICES C.10. Import penetration of goods and services Figure C.10.1. Import penetration of goods and services, 2000 and 2007 Current prices, in percentage 2000 2007 % 163 100 218 OECD countries OECD OECD 90 accession enhanced countries engagement 80 countries 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Italy Korea Spain Japan IsraelChile China IndiaBrazil Ireland Austria Finland Poland Iceland GreeceMexico FranceTurkey Belgium Hungary Sweden NorwayCanada EstoniaSlovenia Denmark Germany Portugal Australia Indonesia Netherlands Switzerland Luxembourg New Zealand United States South Africa Slovak RepublicCzech Republic United Kingdom OECD30 average Russian Federation 1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/841351801071 Figure C.10.2. Import penetration of goods, Figure C.10.3. Import penetration of services, 2000 and 2007 2000 and 2007 Current prices, in percentage Current prices, in percentage 2000 2007 2000 2007 Lux. 150% (2007) 96% (2000) Slovak Republic Luxembourg Belgium Ireland Czech Republic Denmark Hungary Belgium Luxembourg Netherlands Netherlands OECD30 average Austria Iceland Switzerland Sweden Poland Hungary Ireland Austria OECD30 average Norway Sweden Finland Germany Switzerland Korea Czech Republic Denmark Slovak Republic Finland Germany Portugal United Kingdom Canada Korea Mexico New Zealand Iceland Spain Greece Canada Norway Italy Spain Poland Turkey Portugal Italy France France Greece New Zealand Australia United Kingdom Japan Australia United States United States Turkey Japan Mexico (2006) 8070 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 0210 0304050 % % 1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/841436083618 1 2 http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/841441777180 Information on data for Israel: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/888932315602. OECD ECONOMIC GLOBALISATION INDICATORS © OECD 2010 77 From: Measuring Globalisation: OECD Economic Globalisation Indicators 2010 Access the complete publication at: https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264084360-en Please cite this chapter as: OECD (2010), “Import penetration of goods and services”, in Measuring Globalisation: OECD Economic Globalisation Indicators 2010, OECD Publishing, Paris. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264084360-30-en This work is published under the responsibility of the Secretary-General of the OECD. The opinions expressed and arguments employed herein do not necessarily reflect the official views of OECD member countries. This document and any map included herein are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area. You can copy, download or print OECD content for your own use, and you can include excerpts from OECD publications, databases and multimedia products in your own documents, presentations, blogs, websites and teaching materials, provided that suitable acknowledgment of OECD as source and copyright owner is given. All requests for public or commercial use and translation rights should be submitted to [email protected]. Requests for permission to photocopy portions of this material for public or commercial use shall be addressed directly to the Copyright Clearance Center (CCC) at [email protected] or the Centre français d’exploitation du droit de copie (CFC) at [email protected]..
Recommended publications
  • THE OECD-WTO BALANCED TRADE in SERVICES DATABASE (BPM6 Edition)
    1 THE OECD-WTO BALANCED TRADE IN SERVICES DATABASE (BPM6 edition) Antonella Liberatore (OECD), Steen Wettstein (WTO)1 January 2021 Complete, consistent and balanced bilateral trade in services statistics are vital for the empirical analysis of international trade as well as for policy-making and trade negotiations. Unfortunately, such data are not readily available. This paper presents the work of OECD and WTO to build an updated version of the Balanced Trade in Services (BaTIS) dataset, a complete and consistent trade in services matrix to serve as input for the compilation of the TiVA Inter-Country Input-Output Tables and as a tool for the analysis of trade patterns in general. This second edition of BaTIS provides annual data for 2005-2019, covering 202 economies, broken down by the 12 main EBOPS 2010 service categories. This paper accompanies the dataset and describes its compilation methodology in detail, including the collection and cleaning of the reported data, the different methodologies used to estimate missing information, and the final balancing of the export and import flows. 1 This contribution reflects a description of a methodology and does not represent the position or opinions of OECD, WTO or their respective Members, nor the official position of any staff members. The definition of geographical territories in this report is merely statistical and does not imply an expression of opinion by the OECD or the WTO Secretariat concerning the status of any country or territory, the delimitation of its frontiers, its official name, nor the rights and obligations of any WTO member in respect of WTO agreements.
    [Show full text]
  • Lecture 10 2-18 Outline and Slides 0.Pdf
    Economics 2 Professor Christina Romer Spring 2016 Professor David Romer LECTURE 10 INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND TRADE POLICY February 18, 2016 I. OVERVIEW II. REVIEW OF COMPLETE SPECIALIZATION A. Example of the United States and China B. Terms of trade and world prices III. INCOMPLETE SPECIALIZATION A. Changing opportunity cost within each country B. Optimal level of specialization C. Consumption possibilities with trade IV. SUPPLY AND DEMAND ANALYSIS OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE A. Export good B. Import good V. WELFARE AND EMPLOYMENT EFFECTS OF TRADE A. Welfare analysis of trade 1. Export good 2. Import good B. Employment effects of trade VI. TRADE POLICY A. Some definitions B. Effects of a tariff C. Welfare analysis of a tariff D. Possible arguments for protection Economics 2 Christina Romer Spring 2016 David Romer LECTURE 10 International Trade and Trade Policy February 18, 2016 Announcements • Midterm 1 Logistics: • Tuesday, February 23rd, 3:30–5:00 • Sections 102, 104, 107, 108 (GSIs Pablo Muñoz and David Green) go to 245 Li Ka Shing Center (corner of Oxford and Berkeley Way). • Everyone else come to usual room (2050 VLSB). • You do not need a blue book; just a pen. • You also do not need a watch or phone. Announcements (continued) • Collecting the Exams: • If you finish before 4:45, you may quietly pack up and bring your exam to the front. • After 4:45, stay seated. • We will collect all of the exams by passing them to the nearest aisle. • Please don’t get up until all of the exams are collected. • Academic honesty: Behave with integrity.
    [Show full text]
  • GLOSSARY of INTERNATIONAL TRADE TERMS 2016 Guide
    CALIFORNIA FASHION ASSOCIATION 444 South Flower Street, 37th Floor · Los Angeles, CA 90071 ·ph. 213.688.6288 ·fax 213.688.6290 Email: [email protected] Website: www.californiafashionassociation.org GLOSSARY OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE TERMS 2016 Guide Sponsored By: Prepared by: CALIFORNIA FASHION ASSOCIATION 444 South Flower Street, 37th Floor, Los Angeles, CA 90071 Phone: 213-688-6288, Fax: 213-688-6290 [email protected] | www.californiafashionassociation.org 1 CALIFORNIA FASHION ASSOCIATION 444 South Flower Street, 37th Floor · Los Angeles, CA 90071 ·ph. 213.688.6288 ·fax 213.688.6290 Email: [email protected] Website: www.californiafashionassociation.org THE VOICE OF THE CALIFORNIA INDUSTRY The California Fashion Association is the forum organized to address the issues of concern to our industry. Manufacturers, contractors, suppliers, educational institutions, allied associations and all apparel-related businesses benefit. Fashion is the largest manufacturing sector in Southern California. Nearly 13,548 firms are involved in fashion-related businesses in Los Angeles and Orange County; it is a $49.3-billion industry. The apparel and textile industry of the region employs approximately 128,148 people, directly and indirectly in Los Angeles and surrounding counties. The California Fashion Association is the clearinghouse for information and representation. We are a collective voice focused on the industry's continued growth, prosperity and competitive advantage, directed toward the promotion of global recognition for the "Created in California"
    [Show full text]
  • Non-Tariff Measures Overview Glossary of Related Terms
    Non-Tariff Measures Overview Glossary of Related Terms Note: With thanks to the following for definitions provided here: Deardorff's Glossary of International Economics, the 1 United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD), the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), the United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization (UNESCO) and the World Trade Organization (WTO). Terms Definition Absolute Advantage (AA) The ability to produce a good at lower cost, in terms of real resources, than another country. In a Ricardian model, cost is in terms of labor only. Absolute advantage is neither necessary nor sufficient for a country to export a good. Ad Valorem Equivalent The ad valorem tariff that would be equivalent, in terms of its effects on trade, Terms price, or some other measure, to a nontariff barrier. Ad Valorem Tariff (A Tariff defined as a percentage of the value of an imported good. Percentage of Price) Adjustment Assistance Government program to assist workers and/or firms whose industry has declined, either due to import competition (trade adjustment assistance) or from other causes. Such programs usually have two (conflicting) goals: to lessen hardship for those affected, and to help them change their behavior -- what, how, or where they produce. AGOA U.S. legislation enacted May 2000 providing tariff preferences to African countries that qualify, including trade facilitation and technical assistance to producers. As of January 2016, 40 countries were listed as eligible. Several countries have had their eligibility removed and some later reinstated over the years. Anti-Dumping Measures A complaint by a domestic producer that imports are being dumped, leading to an anti-dumping duty if both dumping and injury are found in the resulting investigation.
    [Show full text]
  • EXCHANGE RATE PASS-THROUGH INTO IMPORT PRICES Jose´ Manuel Campa and Linda S
    EXCHANGE RATE PASS-THROUGH INTO IMPORT PRICES Jose´ Manuel Campa and Linda S. Goldberg* Abstract—We provide cross-country and time series evidence on the can be raised, then, about whether measured degrees of mon- extent of exchange rate pass-through into the import prices of 23 OECD countries. We find compelling evidence of partial pass-through in the short etary policy effectiveness are fragile and regime-specific if the run,especiallywithinmanufacturingindustries.Overthelongrun,producer- degree of exchange rate pass-through is highly endogenous to currency pricing is more prevalent for many types of imported goods. macroeconomic variables.2 The degree of aggregate exchange Countries with higher rates of exchange rate volatility have higher pass-through elasticities, although macroeconomic variables have played rate pass-through, and its determinants, are therefore important a minor role in the evolution of pass-through elasticities over time. Far for the effectiveness of macroeconomic policy. more important for pass-through changes in these countries have been the Although pass-through of exchange rate movements into dramatic shifts in the composition of country import bundles. a country’s import prices is central to these macroeconomic stabilization arguments, to date only limited relevant evi- I. Introduction dence on this relationship has been available.3 The first goal hough exchange rate pass-through has long been of of our paper is to provide extensive cross-country and time Tinterest, the focus of this interest has evolved consid- series evidence on exchange rate pass-through into the erably over time. After a long period of debate over the law import prices of 23 OECD countries.
    [Show full text]
  • Importing, Exporting and Aggregate Productivity in Large Devaluations∗
    Importing, Exporting and Aggregate Productivity in Large Devaluations∗ Joaquin Blaum.† July 2017 Abstract A standard mechanism linking large real depreciations to declines in aggregate productivity is that firms’ access to foreign inputs is restricted. Recent quantitative trade models of importing predict that the economy’s aggregate import share should decrease following a real depreciation. I provide evidence that in fact the aggregate import share increases after a large depreciation. Using Mexican micro data, I show that the increase in the overall import intensity is explained by the expansion and entry of new exporters, which are intense importers. I develop a model of joint importing-exporting and discipline it to match salient features of the Mexican micro data. I study a counterfactual devaluation and show that the calibrated model can generate an increase in the aggregate import share and compositional effects in line with the data. A model with importing only cannot generate either, and predicts a decrease in aggregate productivity that is twice as large. JEL Codes: F11, F12, F14, F62, D21, D22 ∗I thank Ben Faber, Pablo Fajgelbaum, Michael Peters, Jesse Schreger and seminar participants at Brown, Atlanta Fed, LACEA-TIGN in Montevideo, Di Tella University, Nottingham GEP, SED in Edinburgh, SAET in Faro and the NBER IFM SI Meeting. I am grateful to Rob Johnson and Sebastian Claro for excellent discussions. I also thank the International Economics Section of Princeton University for its hospitality and funding during part of this research. †Brown University. Email: [email protected] 1 1 Introduction Large economic crises in emerging markets are associated with sharp contractions in output and aggregate productivity as well as strong depreciations of the exchange rate - e.g.
    [Show full text]
  • Topic 12: the Balance of Payments Introduction We Now Begin Working Toward Understanding How Economies Are Linked Together at the Macroeconomic Level
    Topic 12: the balance of payments Introduction We now begin working toward understanding how economies are linked together at the macroeconomic level. The first task is to understand the international accounting concepts that will be essential to understanding macroeconomic aggregate data. The kinds of questions to pose: ◦ How are national expenditure and income related to international trade and financial flows? ◦ What is the current account? Why is it different from the trade deficit or surplus? Which one should we care more about? Does a trade deficit really mean something negative for welfare? ◦ What are the primary factors determining the current-account balance? ◦ How are an economy’s choices regarding savings, investment, and government expenditure related to international deficits or surpluses? ◦ What is the “balance of payments”? ◦ And how does all of this relate to changes in an economy’s net international wealth? Motivation When was the last time the United States had a surplus on the balance of trade in goods? The following chart suggests that something (or somethings) happened in the late 1990s and early 2000s to make imports grow faster than exports (except in recessions). Candidates? Trade-based stories: ◦ Big increase in offshoring of production. ◦ China entered WTO. ◦ Increases in foreign unfair trade practices? Macro/savings-based stories: ◦ US consumption rose fast (and savings fell) relative to GDP. ◦ US began running larger government budget deficits. ◦ Massive net foreign purchases of US assets (net capital inflows). ◦ Maybe it’s cyclical (note how US deficit falls during recessions – why?). US trade balance in goods, 1960-2016 ($ bllions). Note: 2017 = -$796 b and 2018 projected = -$877 b Closed-economy macro basics Before thinking about how a country fits into the world, recall the basic concepts in a country that does not trade goods or assets (so again it is in “autarky” but we call it a closed economy).
    [Show full text]
  • JA Economics® Course Overview and Outline
    JA Economics® | Course Overview and Outline Initial JA Economics® Course Release Overview and Outline Spring 2019 Market for Goods JA Economics is a one-semester course that connects high and Services school students to the economic principles that influence their daily lives as well as their futures. It addresses each BANK of the economics standards identified by the Council for Production of Goods and Household Economic Education as being essential to complete a high Services + + Consumer school economics course. Course components equip students to: Market for Labor • Learn the necessary concepts applicable to state and national educational standards • Apply economic reasoning and skills in the world around them • Synthesize elective concepts through a cumulative, tangible deliverable (optional case studies and/or projects) • Demonstrate the skills necessary for future financial literacy pathway success • Integrate College and Career Readiness anchor standards in Reading, Informational Text, Speaking and Listening, and Vocabulary Volunteers engage with students through a variety of activities that includes subject matter guest speaking and coaching or advising for case study and project course work. Volunteer activities help students better understand the relationship between what they learn in school, their future career, and their successful participation in today’s global economy. Through a variety of experiential activities presented by the teacher and volunteer, students better understand the relationship between what they learn
    [Show full text]
  • Currency Wars, Trade Wars and Global Demand
    Currency Wars, Trade Wars and Global Demand Olivier Jeanne Johns Hopkins University∗ September 2018 Abstract I present a tractable model of a global economy with downward nominal wage rigidity in which countries attempt to boost their em- ployment and welfare by depreciating their currencies and making their goods more competitive|a "currency war"|or by imposing a tariff on imports|a "trade war." A currency war can be waged with a range of policy instruments|by lowering the nominal interest rate, by raising the inflation target or by capital controls. Trade wars de- press global demand and employment and may lead to large welfare losses (amounting to more than 10 percent of potential GDP under our benchmark calibration). The welfare effects of currency wars depend on the policy instruments but are nonnegative when all countries use the same instruments. The uncoordinated use of capital controls may lead to symmetry breaking, with a fraction of countries competitively devaluing their currency and lending their surpluses to deficit coun- tries at a low interest rate. Currency wars may lead to a large welfare transfer from the countries that do not use capital controls to those that do. ∗Olivier Jeanne: Department of Economics, Johns Hopkins University, 3400 N.Charles Street, Baltimore MD 21218; email: [email protected]. This paper is a distant successor to, and replaces, Jeanne (2009). I thank seminar participants at the NBER Conference on Capital Flows, Currency Wars and Monetary Policy (April 2018)|and especially my discussant Alberto Martin|at the Board of the US Federal Reserve System, the University of Maryland, the Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies in Geneva for their comments.
    [Show full text]
  • 1St STOP CHECKLIST: IMPORT/EXPORT
    1st STOP CHECKLIST: IMPORT/EXPORT REQUIREMENTS & REGULATIONS [] Import and export businesses are federally regulated. Contact the agencies listed below for information: IMPORT EXPORT U.S. Customs Services The Bureau of Export Administration Cincinnati area: (859) 767-7002 Washington D.C.: (202) 482-4811 Cleveland area: (440) 891-3800 Web Site: www.bis.doc.gov Columbus area: (614) 497-1865 Web Site: www.cbp.gov [] If you will be a customs broker, contact a U.S. Customs Service office listed above. A customs broker helps importers and exporters move their goods through customs. [] If you will import or export tobacco products, contact the Ohio Department of Taxation for permit and regulation information. For federal information, contact the Bureau of Alcohol, Tobacco and Firearms (ATF) at (800) 398-2282. The ATF is on-line at www.atf.gov. [] If you will import or export firearms, contact the Bureau of Alcohol, Tobacco and Firearms (ATF) at The ATF is on-line at www.atf.gov. Or call at Cincinnati Columbus Cleveland (513) 684-3351 (614) 827-8470 (216) 522-3374 [] If you will import or export alcoholic beverages, contact the Ohio Department of Liquor Control at (614) 644-2360 for permit information. Information is on-line at http://www.com.state.oh.us/liqr. [] If you will import or export furniture, bedding, upholstered or stuffed items, contact the Ohio Department of Commerce’s Division of Industrial Compliance, Bedding and Upholstered Furniture Section for licensing and inspection information. They can be reached at (614) 644-2223. The Ohio Department of Commerce is on-line at www.com.state.oh.us/dico.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics 181: International Trade Homework # 4 Solutions Ricardo Cavazos and Robert Santillano University of California, Berkeley Due: November 21, 2006
    Economics 181: International Trade Homework # 4 Solutions Ricardo Cavazos and Robert Santillano University of California, Berkeley Due: November 21, 2006 1. The nation of Bermuda is “small” and assumed to be unable to affect world prices. It imports strawberries at the price of 10 dollars per box. The Domestic Supply and Domestic Demand curves for boxes are: S = 60 + 20P D = 1160 − 15P (a) Assume Bermuda is Completely open to trade. What is the equilibrium price and quantity consumed? How much is produced domestically, and how much is imported? Sine they are open to trade, the equilibrium price will be determined by the world market. There- fore, using the Domestic Supply and Demand equations, and recognizing that Import Demand is given by MD = D − S = 1100 − 35P , we get: P w = 10 D = 1160 − 15 × 10 = 1010 S = 60 + 20 × 10 = 260 MD = 1100 − 35 × 10 = 750 (b) Now consider the effect of an import quota of 400 boxes. What happens to the price of straw- berries and quantity consumed? The effect of an import quota is to limit imports at exactly 400. Using the import demand equation expressed above, we can solve for new equilibrium prices to be: 400 = 1100 − 35P ⇒ P q = 20. With this higher price, we can simply go through the same calculations as before to get: Dq = 1160 − 15 × 20 = 860 Sq = 60 + 20 × 20 = 460 MDq = 1100 − 35 × 20 = 400 1 (c) Who wins and who loses? Discuss consumers, domestic producers, and importers (Be sure to compute the change in their welfare). To answer this, it is useful to look at a diagram.
    [Show full text]
  • National Protectionism and Common Trade Policy
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Koopmann, Georg Article — Digitized Version National protectionism and common trade policy Intereconomics Suggested Citation: Koopmann, Georg (1984) : National protectionism and common trade policy, Intereconomics, ISSN 0020-5346, Verlag Weltarchiv, Hamburg, Vol. 19, Iss. 3, pp. 103-110, http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/BF02928302 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/139912 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu ARTICLES EC National Protectionism and Common Trade Policy by Georg Koopmann, Hamburg* The EC recently created a new instrument of trade policy to deter illicit trade practices. A major part of its purpose is to strengthen the Community's authority in the area of trade policy and counter the spread of international protectionism within the Community.
    [Show full text]