Group Inequality and the Severity of Civil Conflict

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Group Inequality and the Severity of Civil Conflict GROUP INEQUALITY AND THE SEVERITY OF CIVIL CONFLICT JOHN D. HUBER AND LAURA MAYORAL1 January 1, 2019 ABSTRACT Civil conflicts, which have been much more prevalent than inter-state conflicts over the last fifty years, vary enormously in their intensity, with some causing millions of deaths and some far fewer. The central goal of this paper is to test an argument from previous theoretical research that high inequality within an ethnic group can make inter-ethnic conflict more violent because such inequality decreases the opportunity cost to poor group members of fighting, and also decreases the opportunity cost to rich group members of funding the conflict. To test this argument, we create a new data set that uses individual-level surveys to measure inequality within ethnic groups. The analysis using these data provide strong evidence for the importance of within-group inequality, and thus underscores the value of focusing on the capacity of groups to fight if one wishes to limit the destruction of civil conflicts. Keywords: Ethnicity, within-group inequality, civil conflict. JEL: D63, D74, J15, O15 1 This paper is a revised version of our previous work “Inequality, Ethnicity and Civil Conflict”. Huber: Depart- ment of Political Science, Columbia University, [email protected]; Mayoral: Institut d’Analisi` Economica,´ CSIC, Barcelona GSE, and University of Gothenburg; [email protected]. John Huber is grateful for financial support from the National Science Foundation (SES-0818381). Laura Mayoral gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Generalitat de Catalunya, and the Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness Grant number ECO2015-66883-P and from National Science Foundation Grant SES-1629370 (PI: Debraj Ray). We received helpful comments from Lars- Erik Cederman, Joan Esteban, Debraj Ray and seminar participants at various venues where this paper was presented. We also thank Sabine Flamand, Andrew Gianou and Tom Orgazalek for superb research assistance. 1. INTRODUCTION The tragic civil war in Syria, which broke out in 2011 and which pits a range of ethnic and sectarian groups against the government, has cost hundreds of thousands of lives and displaced millions. While it is a particularly depressing case, Syria joins a growing list of countries that have suffered from serious intrastate conflicts, which have replaced inter-state wars as the nexus for large scale violence in the world.2 Conflicts, however, vary a great deal in their intensity, with some conflicts leading to large numbers of fatalities and others to a small number. Over the period 1946-2009, for example, the total number of battle-related deaths in the 25% of least-deadly civil conflicts is less than 5,000 people in total (Lacina and Gleditsch, 2005). By contrast, the equivalent figure in the top 25% of most-deadly conflicts is close to 5 million people.3 Thus, if one wishes to limit the death and destruction of civil conflict, one must understand not simply what triggers conflict. It is perhaps even more important to focus on the factors that influence conflict severity. This paper examines empirically the relatioship between economic inequality and the severity of civil war. Previous research on economic inequality and civil war has focused on the link between inequality and grievance. This emphasis is found in long-standing arguments by Karl Marx, Dahrendorf (1959) and Gurr (1970, 1980), who argue that economic inequality breeds grievances which in turn lead to the onset of civil violence. More recent work has recognized that most civil conflict is rooted in ethnic, sectarian or other identity groups (Doyle and Sambanis 2006, Fearon and Laitin 2003), and group-level research with a focus on economic inequality has also emphasized grievances, arguing that economic inequality across groups triggers the start of civil wars (e.g., Cederman et al. 2011, Cederman et al. 2013, Cederman et al. 2015). We also focus on inequality and ethnically-based group conflict, but our analysis departs from this previous research in two substantively important respects. First, rather than focusing on in- equality across groups and its link to grievances, we emphasize inequality within groups, which 2Gleditsch et al. (2002), for example, find that since WWII, there were 46 interstate conflicts with more than 25 battle- related deaths per year, 22 of which have killed at least 1,000 over the entire history of the conflict. Over the same period, there were 181 civil conflicts with more than 25 battle-related deaths per year, and almost half of them had killed more than 1,000 people. 3These figures are based on the “best estimate” of the Battle Deaths dataset, version 3.1; see Lacina and Gleditsch (2005). 3 we argue is a proxy for a group’s capacity to wage civil conflict. This requires us to measure income distributions within groups rather than economic differences across them.4 Second, we focus on the severity rather than the onset of conflict. Both of these departures from previous research are motivated by Esteban and Ray (2011), who argue that internally unequal groups – unlike groups with a large middle class composed of primarily rich or primarily poor individuals – have both the labor (poor people) and the capital (rich people) necessary to fight effectively. This focus on group capacity does not lead to clear inferences about how civil wars begin, but it does suggest that when civil conflicts occur, they will be most intense if they involve groups that have high levels of inequality among their members. Our paper makes two distinct contributions. First, we introduce a new data set that uses surveys to measure economic inequality within groups. Using survey data to this end presents important challenges which we describe below, as well as our strategies to address them. We also argue that using surveys to measure within-group inequality offers important advantages over the use of geo- coded spatial data, which have been employed in previous research. Second, we use the new data set to provide evidence of a robust association between within-group inequality and the severity of civil war (measured using battle deaths). To the best of our knowledge, this is the first paper that analyses this empirically.5 The estimated association – based on cross-national regressions which limit the possibility of making causal claims6 – is larger than the estimated effect of any other variable we examine, and it is robust. In addition, consistent with theoretical arguments emphasizing how group inequality affects the capacity rather than the incentive to fight, we find the association between within group-inequality and conflict onset to be quite weak. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the theoretical argument about the rela- tionship between intra-group inequality and conflict intensity. Section 3 introduces a new data 4 In a related study, Arbatli et al. (2018) find a positive relationship between conflict and within group genetic diver- sity,which they argue is a proxy for interpersonal diversity. We discuss how our findings and those of Arbatli et al. (2018) are related in Section 2. 5Previous studies have focused instead on conflict onset, which as noted above, is not clearly linked to the ER theory. Østby et al. (2009) find a positive association between within-region inequality and conflict onset in 22 countries in Sub-Saharan Africa, and Kuhn and Weidmann (2015), which we discuss below, find a positive association between within-group inequality and conflict onset using a global dataset that has the ethnic group – rather than the region– as unit of analysis. 6See Section 5, however, which is devoted to assessing issues of reverse causation and omitted variable bias. 4 30.46 30 26.44 22.41 20 Percent 10.34 10.34 10 0 0 <500 500-999 1,000-7,500 7,500-15,000 >15,000 Total war deaths Figure 1. Variation in the qualitative nature of civil wars set that uses individual-level surveys to measure within-group inequality. The empirical analysis is found in the three sections that follow. Section 4 focuses on conflict intensity and incidence as dependent variables, followed in Section 5 by a discussion of the possibility that results are due to omitted variable bias or reverse causality. Section 6 then turns to empirical analysis of within-group inequality and civil war onset. Section 7 concludes. Appendix A provides addi- tional analyses of the data, Appendix B provides definitions and summary statistics corresponding to the variables employed in the empirical analysis and (on-line) Appendix C contains materials regarding the data and its construction. 2. ETHNIC INEQUALITY AND CONFLICT Although empirical research on civil strife typically focuses on why conflicts break out, it is im- portant to recognize that the damage wrought by them varies a great deal (Lacina 2006). Figure 1 summarizes some of these differences for 174 civil conflicts with battle death information in the PRIO data (see Lacina and Gleditsch 2005). Around one third of these conflicts have less than 500 total casualties, and 40% have less than 1,000. But some conflicts lead to a great deal of death, with 26% of wars having more than 15,000 casualties. Thus, limiting the devastation from civil conflicts requires that we understand the factors that can lead conflicts to become particularly severe. 5 To this end, Esteban and Ray (2011) (henceforth “ER”) provide a simply theory linking one aspect of inequality – that which exists within groups – to a group’s ability to fight, and thus to variation in conflict intensity. They argue that for a group to fight effectively, it needs financial resources and labor (i.e, fighters). Sustaining violence therefore has at least two opportunity costs: the cost of contributing resources and the cost of contributing one’s labor to fight.
Recommended publications
  • Development Economics Courses at Cornell University
    Development Economics Courses At Cornell University 2010 2 Table of Contents Introduction…………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………….p.3 Courses Chart……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………….p.4‐9 Future Semester Offerings……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………..p.10 AEM 4420: Emerging Markets……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………p.12‐19 AEM 4450/NS 4450: Food Policy for Developing Countries………………………………………..................................p.20‐22 AEM 4540/ECON 4540: China’s and India’s Growth Miracles…………………………………………………………………….p.23‐29 AEM 4551/CRP 6490/SOC 4450: Comparative Perspectives in Poverty Reduction Policy……………………………p.30‐34 AEM 6420/NS 6420: Globalization, Food Safety, and Nutrition………………………………………………………………….p.35‐41 AEM 6600: Agroecosystems, Economic Development, and the Environment…………………………………………….p.42‐44 AEM 6670/ECON 7700: Topics in Development Economics………………………………………………………………………..p.45‐47 AEM 7350/ECON 7350: Topics in Public Economics……………………………………………………………………………………p.48‐49 AEM 7620: The Microeconomics of International Development………………………………………………………………..p.50‐57 AEM 7650: Development Microeconomics Graduate Research Seminar……………………………………………………p.58‐59 AEM 7670/ECON 7670: Topics in International Finance……………………………………………………………………………..p.60‐67 ECON 3710: Development Economics………………………………………………………………………………………………………..p.68‐75 ECON 7720/ILRLE 7490: Economics of Development………………………………………………………………………………….p.76‐79 ECON 7730: Economic Development…………………………………………………………………………………………………………p.80‐86 ILRIC
    [Show full text]
  • Dilip Mookherjee Debraj
    OCCUPATIONAL DIVERSITY AND ENDOGENOUS INEQUALITY Dilip Mookherjee Boston University Debraj Ray New York University and Instituto de Analisis´ Economico´ (CSIC) February 2006 ABSTRACT A traditional view of markets with intergenerational bequests within dynasties is that they equalize wealth across households. A more recent literature suggests that markets are inherently disequalizing. A third viewpoint argues that initial history is crucial in determining whether in- equalities persist or not. By constructing a theory of equilibrium investment allocation between human capital and financial assets in the presence of borrowing constraints, we address these views in a unified way. Two attributes of occupational diversity turn out to be central to our understanding: span, the range of training costs across occupations, and richness, the variety of different training costs contained within the span. The former is used to generate a necessary and sufficient condition for markets to be disequalizing, while the latter is shown to be directly connected to the question of history-dependence. Among the several implications of the analy- sis is a greater proneness for markets to be disequalizing in poorer countries. Mookherjee’s research was supported by the MacArthur Foundation and by National Science Foundation Grant No. 0418434, and Ray’s research by National Science Foundation Grant No. 0241070. Ray is also grateful to the London School of Economics for warm hospitality during a sabbatical year. We thank participants at several seminars for their helpful comments. The views expressed in this paper are the authors’ own and do not represent the views of the MacArthur Foundation or the National Science Foundation. Some results contained in the present paper were informally presented in an AER Papers and Proceedings volume; see Mookherjee and Ray (2002).
    [Show full text]
  • Aspirations and the Development Treadmill
    ASPIRATIONS AND THE DEVELOPMENT TREADMILL DEBRAJ RAY Journal of Human Development and Capabilities 17:3, 309–323 (2016) ABSTRACT. I describe a positive theory of socially determined aspirations, and some implications of that theory for the study of economic inequality and social conflict. The main contribution of the theory is that it attempts to describe, in the same explanatory arc, how a change in aspirations can be inspirational in some circumstances, or a source of frustration and resentment in others. These different reactions arise from the aspirational gap: the difference between socially generated aspirations and the current socio-economic standard that the individual enjoys. Ever-accelerating economic development can cut both ways in terms of inspiration and frustration. 1. INTRODUCTION This essay aims to describe how socially determined aspirations enter into the determination of individual goals, and in so doing can serve to both inspire and frustrate. Because aspirations are generated by the ambient society in which the individual is located, this gives rise to an inter- play between economic development as a whole, the speed and distributional consequences of that economic development, and individual behavior. Economic and social outcomes and individual conditions interact, of course, along a two-way street: the former influencing the latter via aspira- tions, and the latter giving rise to the former simply by virtue of aggregation over al individuals in society. This interplay has been highlighted, though from somewhat different perspectives, in the work of Ray (1998, 2006) and Appadurai (2004). There are several implications of this formulation. One could use this device to study poverty traps that are created by despair or frustration, as Appadurai (2004), Dalton, Ghosal and Mani (2015) and Ray (1998, 2006) have done.
    [Show full text]
  • 02/2019 Dilip Mookherjee Office
    02/2019 DILIP MOOKHERJEE OFFICE: Department of Economics 270 Bay State Road Boston, MA 02215. Tel: (617) 3534392 FAX: (617) 3534143, 3534449 EMAIL: [email protected] RESEARCH INTERESTS: Development, Inequality, Contract Theory TEACHING INTERESTS: Development, Microeconomics. EDUCATION: Ph.D. (Economics), London School of Economics, 1982. M.Sc.(Econometrics and Mathematical Economics), London School of Economics, 1980. M.A . (Economics), Delhi School of Economics, 1978. B.A. (Economics), Presidency College, Calcutta, 1975. EMPLOYMENT: 1995-present Professor of Economics, Boston University. 1989-1996 Professor, Planning Unit, Indian Statistical Institute, New Delhi. 1982-89 Associate Professor (1986-89), Assistant Professor (1982-86) of Economics, Graduate School of Business, Stanford University. OTHER APPOINTMENTS: 2019-2022 Member, Executive Committee of the Econometric Society 2018-2021 Member, Council of the Econometric Society 2017 Fall Visiting Professor, Department of Economics, New York University 2016- Member, Asia Regional Standing Committee (ARSC), Econometric Society 2015- Co-Editor, Theoretical Economics 2012- Honorary Adjunct Professor, Indian Statistical Institute; Research Associate, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. 2011-2012 Visiting Mitchell Professor, Department of Economics, Columbia University 2011- Research Fellow, Center for Economic Policy Research, London 2010-2018 Lead Academic, India Central Program, International Growth Centre, London School of Economics 2003-2008 Co-Editor, Journal of Development
    [Show full text]
  • Aspirations and the Development Treadmill
    Journal of Human Development and Capabilities, 2016 Vol. 17, No. 3, 309–323, http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/19452829.2016.1211597 Aspirations and the Development Treadmill DEBRAJ RAY Department of Economics, New York University, New York, USA ABSTRACT I describe a positive theory of socially determined aspirations, and some implications of that theory for the study of economic inequality and social conflict. The main contribution of the theory is that it attempts to describe, in the same explanatory arc, how a change in aspirations can be inspirational in some circumstances, or a source of frustration and resentment in others. These different reactions arise from the aspirational gap: the difference between socially generated aspirations and the current socio-economic standard that the individual enjoys. Ever-accelerating economic development can cut both ways in terms of inspiration and frustration. KEYWORDS Aspirations, Inequality development, Economic growth, Conflict 1. Introduction This essay aims to describe how socially determined aspirations enter into the determination of individual goals, and in so doing can serve to both inspire and frustrate. Because aspira- tions are generated by the ambient society in which the individual is located, this gives rise to an interplay between economic development as a whole, the speed and distributional consequences of that economic development, and individual behavior. Economic and social outcomes and individual conditions interact, of course, along a two-way street: the former influencing the latter via aspirations, and the latter giving rise to the former simply by virtue of aggregation over all individuals in society. This interplay has been high- lighted, though from somewhat different perspectives, in the work of Ray (1998, 2006) and Appadurai (2004).
    [Show full text]
  • CURRICULUM VITAE B. Douglas Bernheim
    January 2017 CURRICULUM VITAE B. Douglas Bernheim Department of Economics 650-725-8732 (Voice) Stanford University 650-725-5702 (Fax) Stanford, CA 94305-6072 [email protected] Education Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1979-1982, Ph.D. Harvard University, 1975-1979, A.B. Academic Positions Stanford University, Department of Economics, 1994-present. Edward Ames Edmonds Professor of Economics (2005-present), Lewis and Virginia Eaton Professor of Economics (1994-2005). Department Chair (2014-2017). Princeton University, Department of Economics, 2007-2008, Professor of Economics. Princeton University, Department of Economics, 1990-1994. John L. Weinberg Professor of Economics and Business Policy. Northwestern University, J.L. Kellogg Graduate School of Management, Department of Finance, 1988- 1990. Harold J. Hines Jr. Distinguished Professor of Risk Management. Stanford University, Department of Economics, 1987-1988. Associate Professor with tenure. Stanford University, Department of Economics, 1982-1987. Assistant Professor. Honors and Awards Distinguished Visitor, UCSD, Department of Economics, May 2013. Martha and Jonathan Cohen Distinguished Visitor at PIER, University of Pennsylvania, Department of Economics, October 2011. 2009 Best Article Award, Economic Inquiry, for “The Effects of Financial Education in the Workplace: Evidence from a Survey of Employers” John Simon Guggenheim Memorial Foundation Fellowship, 2001-02. Fellow, Center for Advanced Study in the Behavioral Sciences, 2001-02. 1 Fellow of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences, elected 1997. Fellow of the Econometric Society, elected 1991. ACCF Center for Policy Research Fellowship, 1994. Alfred P. Sloan Foundation Research Fellow, 1987-1989. NBER-Olin Research Fellow, 1985-1986. Awarded Hoover National Fellowship, 1985-1986 (declined to accept NBER-Olin). National Science Foundation Graduate Fellowship, 1979-1982.
    [Show full text]
  • Aspirations and Inequality
    http://www.econometricsociety.org/ Econometrica, Vol. 85, No. 2 (March, 2017), 489–519 ASPIRATIONS AND INEQUALITY GARANCE GENICOT Georgetown University, Washington, DC 20057, U.S.A. DEBRAJ RAY New York University, New York, NY 10012, U.S.A. and University of Warwick, Coventry, CV4 7AL, U.K. The copyright to this Article is held by the Econometric Society. It may be downloaded, printed and re- produced only for educational or research purposes, including use in course packs. No downloading or copying may be done for any commercial purpose without the explicit permission of the Econometric So- ciety. For such commercial purposes contact the Office of the Econometric Society (contact information may be found at the website http://www.econometricsociety.org or in the back cover of Econometrica). This statement must be included on all copies of this Article that are made available electronically or in any other format. Econometrica, Vol. 85, No. 2 (March, 2017), 489–519 ASPIRATIONS AND INEQUALITY BY GARANCE GENICOT AND DEBRAJ RAY 1 This paper develops a theory of socially determined aspirations, and the interac- tion of those aspirations with growth and inequality. The interaction is bidirectional: economy-wide outcomes determine individual aspirations, which in turn determine in- vestment incentives and social outcomes. Thus aspirations, income, and the distribution of income evolve jointly. When capital stocks lie in some compact set, steady state dis- tributions must exhibit inequality and are typically clustered around local poles. When sustained growth is possible, initial histories matter. Either there is convergence to an equal distribution (with growth) or there is perennial relative divergence across clus- ters, with within-cluster convergence.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics News
    Economics News NEWSLETTER FOR THE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS SPRING 2018 A letter from the Chair Dear Students, Parents, Alumni, Colleagues, and Friends, 2017-18 was notable for us in many ways, among them the fact that we crossed what once seemed to be an impossible mark: BU now has over 1000 undergradu- ate majors in economics. With about 200 masters students and 120 PhD students, we are one of the largest Departments in the University. And, of course, we are also the most entertaining! To meet that high demand, we have been hard at work to bring exciting new facul- ty members to the Department. This year, we were fortunate to hire Jean-Jacques Forneron, an econometrician getting his PhD at Columbia, and Yuhei Miyauchi, a trade economist graduating from MIT. We will have to wait for Yuhei to arrive as he will do a post doc at Stanford University next year, joining us in 2019-20. Speaking of coming to BU, we were delighted to have our former colleague Debraj Ray give the 16th Annual Rosenthal Lecture this year. Debraj, now at New York University (also known as BU South), gave a fascinating talk which is summarized in the newsletter. He also showed some photographs of Bob Rosenthal with other HQTOGTCPFEWTTGPVEQNNGCIWGU1PCUCFPQVGVJKUYCUVJGƂTUVNGEVWTGUKPEGVJG passing of Bob’s mother, Ruth Rosenthal. Ruth and Bob’s sister, Janet Stradley, have been instrumental in keeping the lecture series going. We plan an intensive push to build up the Rosenthal Lecture fund so that it becomes an endowment that will fund the series in perpetuity.
    [Show full text]
  • What's New in Development Economics?
    What’s New in Development Economics? Debraj Ray New York University January 2000 I am greatly indebted to Dilip Mookherjee for several conversations on this subject, and in particular, for allowing me to borrow freely from our joint introduction to A Reader in Development Economics, London:Blackwell (forthcoming), for the purpose of writing this essay. 1 Introduction This essay is meant to describe the current frontiers of development economics, as I see them. I might as well throw my hands up at the beginning and say there are too many frontiers. In recent years, the subject has made excellent use of economic theory, econometric methods, sociology, anthropology, political science and demography and has burgeoned into one of the liveliest areas of research in all the social sciences. And about time too:the study of economic development is probably the most challenging in all of economics, and provided we are patient about getting to “the bottom line” and the “policy implications”, it can have enormous payoffs. Fortunately, considerations of space allow me to use brevity as an excuse for selec- tivity. So rather than attempt an exhaustive review of several areas, I would like to concentrate on a few methodological points around which recent literature appears to have clustered. More than anything else, I want to bring out for you a certain way of thinking about development that has become increasingly influential over the last couple of decades, one that is changing and will continue to change the face of research in this discipline. The main trend I would like to try and document is a move — welcome, in my opinion — away from a traditional preoccupation with the notion of convergence.
    [Show full text]
  • Aspirations, Inequality, Investment and Mobility
    Aspirations, Inequality, Investment and Mobility Garance Genicot Georgetown University Debraj Ray New York University July 2009 1. Introduction What individuals want for themselves, or what parents want for their children, is conditioned by society in fundamental ways. One such pathway is via the creation of individual aspirations (for their own future, or for their children's future). To some extent, such aspirations are drawn from past individual experience (as in the literature on habit formation or reference points), but at the same time they are profoundly affected by one's social environment. We look at others \around" us, and their experiences and achievements shape our desires and goals. This is a view of individual preferences that isn't standard in economic theory. But it should be. Individual goals don't exist in social isolation as consumer preferences are so often assumed to do. Thus society-wide aggregates (say in intergenerational investment, which is our main interest here) may depend fundamentally on the ambient distribution of income and wealth. In short, aspirations affect income mobility and income distribution, but in turn, these latter ingredients shape aspi- rations. Thus aspirations, income (and its distribution), investment and economic mobility evolve jointly, and in many situations in a self-reinforcing way. A detailed examination of this proposition is the subject of our paper. The relationship between macroeconomic outcomes (such as growth and mobility) and individual aspirations turns on three things. First, there is the question of how individuals react to the aspirations that they do have. Second, there is the issue of how aspirations are formed: how they vary with the current economic circumstances of the individual concerned as well as the world around her.
    [Show full text]
  • Research Review 2010
    RESEA R CH REVIEW Contents Spring 2010 Recent Discussion Papers Page #191 Lumpy Investment and Corporate Tax Policy 2 Jianjun Miao and Pengfei Wang #192 Transitional Dynamics of Dividend Tax Reform 2 Francois Gourio and Jianjun Miao #193 Input Sourcing and Multinational Production 3 Stefania Garetto #194 On Measuring Vulnerability to Poverty 4 Indranil Dutta, James Foster and Ajit Mishra #195 Poverty and Disequalization 4 Dilip Mookherjee and Debraj Ray #196 Impact of Political Reservations in West Bengal Local Governments on Anti-Poverty Targeting 5 Pranab K. Bardhan, Dilip Mookherjee and Monica Parra Torrado #197 Social Interactions and Segregation in Skill Accumulation 6 Dilip Mookherjee, Stefan Napel and Debraj Ray #198 Loopholes: Social Learning and the Evolution of Contract Form 7 Philippe Jehiel and Andrew F. Newman #199 Trade Policy and Firm Boundaries 8 Laura Alfaro, Paola Conconi, Harald Fadinger and Andrew F. Newman #200 Prohibitions on Punishments in Private Contracts 8 Philip Bond and Andrew F. Newman #201 Risk Adjustment, Innovation and Prevention 9 Karen Eggleston, Randall P. Ellis and Mingshan Lu #202 Cross-Validation Methods for Risk Adjustment Models 10 Randall P. Ellis and Pooja G. Mookim #203 Infertility Treatment, ART and IUI Procedures and Delivery Outcomes: How Important is Selection? 10 Pooja G. Mookim, Randall P. Ellis and Ariella Kahn-Lang #204 The Impact of Access to Rail Transportation on Agricultural Improvement: The American Midwest as a Test Case, 1850-1860 11 Jeremy Atack and Robert A. Margo #205 Correcting the Bias in the Estimation of a Dynamic Ordered Probit with Fixed Effects of Self-assessed Health Status 12 Jesus M.
    [Show full text]
  • Garance Genicot
    GARANCE GENICOT Georgetown University • Department of Economics • ICC 570 • Washington DC 20057-1036 Tel: 202-687-7144 •Fax: (202) 687-6102 •http://faculty.georgetown.edu/gg58/ •Email:[email protected] EDUCATION Ph.D. in Economics, Cornell University, 1995-1999 B.A. in Economics, Université de Liège, Belgium, 1991-1995. EMPLOYMENT Current Position: Professor, Department of Economics, Georgetown University, August 2018-Present Past Employment: Associate Professor, Department of Economics, Georgetown University, 2007-2018 Visiting Faculty, Department of Economics, University of Aix-Marseille, May-July 2018 Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, Georgetown University, 2003-2007 Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, University of California at Irvine, 1999-2003 Visiting Faculty, Department of Economics, University of Aix-Marseille, May-July 2016 Visiting Faculty, Development Research Group of the World Bank, Spring 2011 Visiting Assistant Professor in Economics, M.I.T., Spring 2007 Visiting Assistant Professor in Economics, London School of Economics, Fall 2004 Visiting Assistant Professor in Economics, University College London, Spring 2003 Visiting Assistant Professor in Economics and International Affairs, Princeton University, 2001-2002. Visiting Assistant Professor, New York University, Summers 2000 and 2002. PROFESSIONAL MEMBERSHIPS AND ACTIVITIES Theoretical Research in Development Economics (ThReD), Board Member. Bureau for Research and Economic Analysis of Development (BREAD), fellow. Economic Development and Institutions research network, member of the Thematic Group Family Gender and Conflict, 2016- Program Committee Member for the Bread Conference held at Maryland University May 2019. Program Committee Member for the ThReD Conference held at Notre Dame University May 2019. Member of the Jury for the Infosys Prize in Social Sciences 2016 Associate Editor for the Journal of Development Economics 2010- Associate Editor for the Berkeley Electronic Journal for Theoretical Economics 2006-2011.
    [Show full text]