How Markets Work

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

How Markets Work HOW MARKETS WORK Why are airfares more expensive during the summer? Why are tickets to a National Basketball Association (NBA) playoff game more expensive than a regular season game? Why are gas prices higher when there is instability in the Middle East? The answer to these questions can be found through supply and demand analysis. Supply and demand are the forces that make market economies work. They determine the quantity of each good produced and the price at which it is sold. This chapter will introduce the theory of supply and demand, as well as the concept of elasticity, a measure of how much buyers and sellers respond to changes in market conditions. A market is a group of buyers and sellers of a particular good or service. With this definition in mind, let’s begin our study of markets by analyzing the behavior of both buyers and sellers. DEMAND (Principles of Economics 5th ed. pages 67–73/6th ed. pages 67–73) Buyers demand the goods and services produced and sold by sellers in various markets. What determines buyer demand? This section will provide you with the answer to this question. Let’s start with an example using the ice cream market. When the price of ice cream is high, the quantity of ice cream people are willing to buy is smaller. Conversely, when the price of ice cream is low, the quantity of ice cream people are willing to buy is greater. The economic concept here that captures this behavioral dynamic is the law of demand, which states that other things equal, the quantity demanded of a good falls when the price of the good rises. The quantity demanded is the amount of a good that buyers are willing and able to purchase. Suppose that ice cream cones cost $3.00. At that price, I am unwilling to buy an ice cream cone, but at the price of $2.50, I am willing to buy 2 ice cream cones, which means that the quantity demanded increases from 1 to 2 when the price of ice cream decreases from $3.00 to $2.50. The figure below shows my demand schedule for 79 80N❖NChapter 2 ice cream, a table that shows the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity demanded, for ice cream cones. Based on the above ice cream demand schedule, we can plot the market demand curve, a graph of the relationships between the price of a good and the quantity demanded, as in this figure below. The demand curve for ice cream slopes downward since a lower price increases both consumers’ willingness and ability to buy an ice cream cone. The demand curve in the figure above only represents my demand for ice cream. Since our goal is to analyze how markets work, we need to look at the market demand for ice cream, which is the sum of the demand curves of everyone who is willing and able to buy an ice cream cone. The market demand curve for ice cream follows the law of demand and, therefore, is also a downward sloping curve, as in this graph below. How Markets Work ❖N81 There are many variables that can shift the demand curve. Here are the most common variables that can shift the demand curve: INCOME–Holding other things constant, if your income increases, you will have more to spend. Assuming that ice cream is a normal good, a good for which, other things equal, an increase in income leads to an increase in demand, an increase in income will lead to an increase in the demand for ice cream. If ice cream is instead an inferior good, a good for which, other things equal, an increase in income leads to a decrease in demand, an increase in income will lead to a decrease in the demand for ice cream. PRICE OF RELATED GOODS–The price of goods related to ice cream may affect our decision to buy ice cream. For example, suppose the price of frozen yogurt falls. You will likely buy frozen yogurt instead of ice cream since frozen yogurt and ice cream are substitutes, two goods for which an increase in the price of one leads to an increase in the demand for the other. Alternatively, suppose that the price of ice cream cones fall. You will likely buy more ice cream because ice cream and ice cream cones are often consumed together and are therefore complements, two goods for which an increase in the price of one leads to a decrease in demand for the other. TASTES–Obviously, if you like ice cream, you will likely buy ice cream and vice versa. Market demand can change when tastes change. Applying this to our example, when more people decide that they now like ice cream, the demand for ice cream will increase. EXPECTATIONS–If you expect a pay raise, then you may be more likely to buy ice cream. Alternatively, if you expect the price of a good to change in the future, you may buy more or less of a good depending on the direction of the price change. For example, if you expect the price of ice cream to fall during the winter, you may choose to wait and buy your ice cream in the winter. 82N❖NChapter 2 NUMBER OF BUYERS–If the number of ice cream buyers increase, the demand for ice cream also increases. Similarly, if the number of ice cream buyers decline, the demand for ice cream also declines. The baby-boomer generation is an interesting example of this—as baby boomers have aged through time, the demand for the goods that they buy increases. AP Tip A helpful pneumonic to remember these demand determinants is S-E-P-T-I-C: Substitutes, Expectations, Population, Tastes, Income, Complements. Any change in market demand due to changes in any of the above mentioned variables leads to a shift in the demand curve. Refer to the following demand curves below for a better understanding of how to show a demand shift. Note that, when the price of ice cream changes, the demand curve does not shift. When the price of ice cream changes, there is a movement along the existing demand curve, meaning that there is a change in the quantity demanded (represented by a movement along the curve), not a change in demand (represented by a shift of the curve). The table below provides a good summary of the effects of the variables that influence buyers and market demand. How Markets Work ❖N83 AP Tip The AP will test whether you know the difference between a change in the quantity demanded versus a change in demand. A change in the quantity demanded is represented by a movement along the demand curve whereas a change in demand is represented by a shift of the demand curve. The graphs here illustrate this difference graphically. SUPPLY (Principles of Economics 5th ed. pages 73–76/6th ed. pages 73–76) We now look at the behavior of sellers in the market for ice cream. When the price of ice cream is high, producers are willing to sell more ice cream because the revenue potential is higher. Conversely, when the price of ice cream is low, ice cream producers are willing to sell less ice cream. This tells us that, as prices rise, the quantity supplied of ice cream will increase. The economic concept here that captures this behavioral dynamic is the law of supply, which states that other things equal, the quantity supplied of a good rises when the price of the good rises. The quantity supplied is the amount of a good that sellers are willing and able to sell. The law of supply is true because suppliers face increasing opportunity costs, just as in the PPF model discussed in Chapter 1. The following table and graph show the supply schedule and supply curve. 84N❖NChapter 2 As in our demand analysis, the market supply curve consists of the sum of all individual supply curves of everyone who is willing and able to sell ice cream cones. Contrary to the demand curve, however, the market supply curve is upward sloping. The suppliers who were willing to sell at $1 are also happy to take $2 and may even provide additional units, which is one of the reasons why the quantity supplied increases as the market price increases. The following graph shows the market supply curve. There are many variables that can shift the market supply curve. Here are the most common variables that can affect supply: INPUT PRICES–Sellers use factors of production, or inputs, to produce goods and services. To produce ice cream, sellers may use inputs such as sugar, cream, machines, and workers. If the price of any of these inputs rises, it becomes less profitable for a seller to produce ice cream. TECHNOLOGY–The use of technology in the production process may help to increase the overall productivity of the supplier. In our example, if the ice cream producing firm uses machinery to make ice cream, ice cream producing firms can produce and supply more ice cream to the market. EXPECTATIONS–The amount of ice cream supplied today may depend on suppliers’ expectations about the future. For example, if there is an expectation that ice cream prices will increase, ice cream producers may choose to put ice cream into storage to sell at a later date. NUMBER OF SELLERS–Market supply depends on the number of sellers. If the number of ice cream sellers increase, the supply of ice cream also increases.
Recommended publications
  • 1 Unit 4. Consumer Choice Learning Objectives to Gain an Understanding of the Basic Postulates Underlying Consumer Choice: U
    Unit 4. Consumer choice Learning objectives to gain an understanding of the basic postulates underlying consumer choice: utility, the law of diminishing marginal utility and utility- maximizing conditions, and their application in consumer decision- making and in explaining the law of demand; by examining the demand side of the product market, to learn how incomes, prices and tastes affect consumer purchases; to understand how to derive an individual’s demand curve; to understand how individual and market demand curves are related; to understand how the income and substitution effects explain the shape of the demand curve. Questions for revision: Opportunity cost; Marginal analysis; Demand schedule, own and cross-price elasticities of demand; Law of demand and Giffen good; Factors of demand: tastes and incomes; Normal and inferior goods. 4.1. Total and marginal utility. Preferences: main assumptions. Indifference curves. Marginal rate of substitution Tastes (preferences) of a consumer reveal, which of the bundles X=(x1, x2) and Y=(y1, y2) is better, or gives higher utility. Utility is a correspondence between the quantities of goods consumed and the level of satisfaction of a person: U(x1,x2). Marginal utility of a good shows an increase in total utility due to infinitesimal increase in consumption of the good, provided that consumption of other goods is kept unchanged. and are marginal utilities of the first and the second good correspondingly. Marginal utility shows the slope of a utility curve (see the figure below). The law of diminishing marginal utility (the first Gossen law) states that each extra unit of a good consumed, holding constant consumption of other goods, adds successively less to utility.
    [Show full text]
  • Demand Demand and Supply Are the Two Words Most Used in Economics and for Good Reason. Supply and Demand Are the Forces That Make Market Economies Work
    LC Economics www.thebusinessguys.ie© Demand Demand and Supply are the two words most used in economics and for good reason. Supply and Demand are the forces that make market economies work. They determine the quan@ty of each good produced and the price that it is sold. If you want to know how an event or policy will affect the economy, you must think first about how it will affect supply and demand. This note introduces the theory of demand. Later we will see that when demand is joined with Supply they form what is known as Market Equilibrium. Market Equilibrium decides the quan@ty and price of each good sold and in turn we see how prices allocate the economy’s scarce resources. The quan@ty demanded of any good is the amount of that good that buyers are willing and able to purchase. The word able is very important. In economics we say that you only demand something at a certain price if you buy the good at that price. If you are willing to pay the price being asked but cannot afford to pay that price, then you don’t demand it. Therefore, when we are trying to measure the level of demand at each price, all we do is add up the total amount that is bought at each price. Effec0ve Demand: refers to the desire for goods and services supported by the necessary purchasing power. So when we are speaking of demand in economics we are referring to effec@ve demand. Before we look further into demand we make ourselves aware of certain economic laws that help explain consumer’s behaviour when buying goods.
    [Show full text]
  • Value and Pricing of Moocs
    education sciences Article Value and Pricing of MOOCs Rose M. Baker 1 and David L. Passmore 2,* 1 College of Information, Department of Learning Technologies, Discovery Park G150, 3940 North Elm Street, University of North Texas, Denton, TX 76207, USA; [email protected] 2 College of Education, Department of Learning and Performance Systems, Workforce Education and Development Program, 305D J. Orvis Keller Building, The Pennsylvania State University, University Park, PA 16802-1303, USA * Correspondence: [email protected]; Tel.: +1-814-863-2583 Academic Editor: Ebba Ossiannilsson Received: 27 February 2016; Accepted: 24 May 2016; Published: 27 May 2016 Abstract: Reviewed in this article is the potential for Massive Open Online Courses (MOOCs) to transform higher education delivery, accessibility, and costs. Next, five major value propositions for MOOCs are considered (headhunting, certification, face-to-face learning, personalized learning, integration with services external to the MOOC, marketing). Then, four pricing strategies for MOOCs are examined (cross-subsidy, third-party, “freemium”, nonmonetary). Although the MOOC movement has experienced growing pains similar to most innovations, we assert that the unyielding pace of improvements in network technologies combined with the need to tame the costs of higher education will create continuing demand for MOOC offerings. Keywords: educational technology; policy in education; assessment; financing higher education; MOOCs; online learning 1. Introduction 1.1. The MOOC Movement A Massive Open Online Course (MOOC) is a type of online course characterized by large-scale student participation and open access via the Internet. The “Open” part of the MOOC acronym signifies “free” to many people—as in “free to students”.
    [Show full text]
  • Tpriv ATE STRATEGIES, PUBLIC POLICIES & FOOD SYSTEM PERFORMANC-S
    tPRIV ATE STRATEGIES, PUBLIC POLICIES & FOOD SYSTEM PERFORMANC-S Alternative Measures of Benefit for Nonmarket Goods Which are Substitutes or Complements for Market Goods Edna Loehman Associate Professor Agricultural Economics and Economics Purdue University ---WORKING ,PAPER SERIES ICS A Joint USDA Land Grant University Research Project April 1991 Alternative Measures of Benefit for Nonmarket Goods Which are Substitutes or Complements for Market Goods Edna Loehman Associate Professor Agricultural Economics and Economics Purdue University ABSTRACT Nonmarket goods include quality aspects of market goods and public goods which may be substitutes or complements for private goods. Traditional methods of measuring benefits of exogenous changes in nonmarket goods are based on Marshallian demand: change in spending on market goods or change in consumer surplus. More recently, willingness to pay and accept have been used as welfare measures . This paper defines the relationships among alternative measures of welfare for perfect substitutes, imperfect substitutes, and complements. Examples are given to demonstrate how to obtain exact measures from systems of market good demand equations . Thanks to Professor Deb Brown, Purdue University, for her encouragement and help over the period in which this paper was written. Thanks also to the very helpful anonymous reviewers for Social Choice and Welfare. -1- Alternative Measures of Benefit for Nonmarket Goods Which are Substitutes or Complements for Market Goods Edna Loehman Department of Agricultural Economics Purdue University Introduction This paper concerns the measurement of benefits for nonmarket goods. Nonmarket goods are not priced directly in a market . They include public goods and quality aspects of market goods. The need for benefit measurement arises from the need to evaluate government programs or policies when nonmarket goods are provided or are regulated by a government .
    [Show full text]
  • Consumer Response to Versioning: How Brands Production Methods Affect Perceptions of Unfairness
    Consumer Response to Versioning: How Brands’ Production Methods Affect Perceptions of Unfairness ANDREW D. GERSHOFF RAN KIVETZ ANAT KEINAN Marketers often extend product lines by offering limited-capability models that are created by removing or degrading features in existing models. This production method, called versioning, has been lauded because of its ability to increase both consumer and firm welfare. According to rational utility models, consumers weigh benefits relative to their costs in evaluating a product. So the production method should not be relevant. Anecdotal evidence suggests otherwise. Six studies show how the production method of versioning may be perceived as unfair and unethical and lead to decreased purchase intentions for the brand. Building on prior work in fairness, the studies show that this effect is driven by violations of norms and the perceived similarity between the inferior, degraded version of a product and the full-featured model offered by the brand. The idea of Apple gratuitously removing fea- been recommended by economists as a production method tures that would have been actually easier to that benefits both firms and consumers (Deneckere and leave in is downright perplexing. McAfee 1996; Hahn 2006; Varian 2000). Firms benefit by reducing design and production costs and by increasing profits The intentional software crippling stance they have taken with the iPod Touch is disturbing through price discrimination when multiple configurations of at best. (Readers’ responses to iPod Touch re- a product are offered. Consumers benefit because versioning view on www.engadget.com) results in lower prices and makes it possible for many to gain access to products that they might otherwise not be able to afford (Shapiro and Varian 1998; Varian 2000).
    [Show full text]
  • Private Provision of a Complementary Public Good∗
    Private Provision of a Complementary Public Good∗ Richard Schmidtke † University of Munich Preliminary Version Abstract For several years, an increasing number of firms are investing in Open Source Software (OSS). While improvements in such a non- excludable public good are not appropriable, companies can benefit indirectly in a complementary proprietary segment. We study this incentive for investment in OSS. In particular we ask how (1) market entry and (2) public investments in the public good affects the firms’ behaviour and profits. Surprisingly, we find that there exist cases where incumbents benefit from market entry. Moreover, we show the counter-intuitive result that public spending does not necessarily lead to a decreasing voluntary private contribution. JEL-classification numbers: C72, L13, L86 Keywords: Open Source Software, Private Provision of Public Goods, Cournot- Nash Equilibrium, Complements, Market Entry ∗I would like to thank Monika Schnitzer, Karolina Leib, Thomas M¨uller, Sougata Poddar and Patrick Waelbroeck and participants at the EDGE Jamboree in Marseille, at the International Industrial Organiza- tion Conference in Chicago, at the Society for Economic Research on Copyright Issues Annual Conference in Torino, at the Kiel-Munich Workshop 2005 in Kloster Seeon at the E.A.R.I.E. in Berlin and at the Annual Meeting of the Verein fuer Socialpolitik in Dresden for helpful comments and suggestions. †Department of Economics, University of Munich, Akademiestr. 1/III, 80799 Munich, Germany, Tel.: +49-89-2180 3232, Fax.: +49-89-2180 2767, e-mail: [email protected] 1 1 Introduction For several years, an increasing number of firms like IBM and Hewlett-Packard or Suse and Red Hat have begun to invest in Open Source Software.
    [Show full text]
  • Understand How Various Factors Shift Supply Or Demand and Understand the Consequences for Equilibrium Price and Quantity.”
    Microeconomics Topic 3: “Understand how various factors shift supply or demand and understand the consequences for equilibrium price and quantity.” Reference: Gregory Mankiw’s Principles of Microeconomics, 2nd edition, Chapter 4. The Supply and Demand Model Supply and demand is a model for understanding the how prices and quantities are determined in a market system. The explanation works by looking at two different groups -- buyers and sellers -- and asking how they interact. The supply and demand model relies on a high degree of competition, meaning that there are enough buyers and sellers in the market for bidding to take place. Buyers bid against each other and thereby raise the price, while sellers bid against each other and thereby lower the price. The equilibrium is a point at which all the bidding has been done; nobody has an incentive to offer higher prices or accept lower prices. Perfect competition exists when there are so many buyers and sellers that no single buyer or seller can affect the price on the market. Imperfect competition exists when a single buyer or seller has the power to influence the price on the market. For more discussion of perfect and imperfect competition, see the notes on Microeconomics topic 7. The supply and demand model applies most accurately when there is perfect competition. In reality, few markets are perfectly competitive. However, the supply and demand framework still provides a good approximation for what is happening much of the time. The Consumer Side of the Market Demand is the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity of the good that consumers are willing and able to buy.
    [Show full text]
  • Comparative Statics and the Gross Substitutes Property of Consumer Demand
    Comparative Statics and the Gross Substitutes Property of Consumer Demand Anne-Christine Barthel1 and Tarun Sabarwal Abstract. The gross substitutes property of demand is very useful in trying to understand stability of the standard Arrow-Debreu competitive equilibrium. Most attempts to derive this property rely on aspects of the demand curve, and it has been hard to derive this property using assumptions on the primitive utility function. Using new results on the comparative statics of demand in Quah (Econometrica, 2007), we provide simple and easy conditions on utility functions that yield the gross substitutes property. Quah provides conditions on utility functions that yield normal demand. We add an assumption on elasticity of marginal rate of substitution, which combined with Quah's assumptions yields gross substitutes. We apply this assumption to the family of constant elasticity of substitution preferences. Our approach is grounded in the standard comparative statics decomposition of a change in demand due to a change in price into a substitution eect and an income eect. Quah's assumptions are helpful to sign the income eect. Combined with our elasticity assumption, we can sign the overall eect. As a by-product, we also present conditions which yield the gross complements property. PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE 1 Department of Economics, University of Kansas, Lawrence, KS 66045 Email: [email protected] 1 2 1. Introduction In the standard Arrow-Debreu model, the gross substitutes property of demand provides insight into the question of a competitive equilibrium's stability. Its usefulness in this matter entails the question what assumptions will guarantee this property.
    [Show full text]
  • Fundamentals of Economics
    FUNDAMENTALS OF ECONOMICS 1 1 NATURE AND SCOPE OF ECONOMICS Basically man is involved in at least four identifiable relationships: a) man with himself, the general topic of psychology b) man with the universe, the study of the biological and physical sciences; c) man with unknown, covered in part by theology and philosophy d) man in relation to other men, the general realm of the social sciences, of which economics is a part. It is hazardous to delineate these areas of inquiry explicitly. However, the social sciences are generally defined to include economics, sociology, political science, anthropology and portions of history and psychology, Economists use history, sociology and other fields such as statistics and mathematics as valuable adjuncts to their study. As a body of knowledge, economics is a relatively new subject, having been around formally a scant two centuries, but subsistence, wealth and the ordinary business of life are, as we all know, as old as mankind. Economics deals with many socioeconomic issues, most of which are of immediate concern to us. Although it is tempting to continue to discuss important economic problems, such a discussion would be premature. To form a reasoned opinion, it is necessary to analyse the issues carefully, a process which requires a meaningful, sequential exposure to economics. Nature has blessed the humans with abundant natural wealth to live on this earth. Humans would have been contended with what nature provided, had they been able to peg their wants (requirements) at a given level. But it is not so, man being born in this world is influenced by biological, physical and social needs, which keep him always busy in searching out the means to keep him satisfied.
    [Show full text]
  • Q1- Fill in the Blanks
    Govt. of Bihar MUZAFFARPUR INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY MUZAFFARPUR – 842003 (Under the Department of Science & Technology Govt. of Bihar, Patna) INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS AND ACCOUNTANCY B.Tech 3rd Sem, EC + CE SOLUTION Q1- Fill in the blanks 1- X axis (Demand/ quantity) 2- Y axis (Price) 3- Perfect competition 4- Monopolistic competition 5- Negative 6- Positive 7- Rent/ Machinery/tools/insurance 8- Labour/material/electricity 9- Fixed 10- Variable Q2- Total variable cost= 7000 Rs Contribution= Selling Price- Cost= 4-0.5= 3.5 Rs BEP (no. of units) = Total variable cost/Contribution= 7000/3.5= 2000 units Percentage of maximum capacity = (10000/2000)*100= 20% Q3-All factors of production are traditionally classified in the following four groups: (i) Land: It refers to all natural resources which are free gifts of nature. Land, therefore, includes all gifts of nature available to mankind—both on the surface and under the surface, e.g., soil, rivers, waters, forests, mountains, mines, deserts, seas, climate, rains, air, sun, etc. (ii) Labour: Human efforts done mentally or physically with the aim of earning income is known as labour. Thus, labour is a physical or mental effort of human being in the process of production. The compensation given to labourers in return for their productive work is called wages (or compensation of employees). Land is a passive factor whereas labour is an active factor of production. Actually, it is labour which in cooperation with land makes production possible. Land and labour are also known as primary factors of production as their supplies are determined more or less outside the economic system itself.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Supply and Demand 1.1 Lecture 2: Supply and Demand 1.1.1 Supply and Demand Diagrams: • Demand Curve Measures Willingness of Consumers to Buy the Good
    1 Supply and demand 1.1 Lecture 2: Supply and Demand 1.1.1 Supply and demand diagrams: • Demand Curve measures willingness of consumers to buy the good • Supply Curve measures willingness of producers to sell • Intersection of supply and demand curve is market equilibrium. • Supply and demand curves can shift when there are – shocks to the ability of producers to supply – shocks in consumer tastes – shocks to the price of complement/substitute goods. A rise in the price of a substitute good for good X raises the demand for the X. • Interventions in market can lead to disequilibrium: – for example, imposing a minimum wage means that more people will want to work than employers want to hire at the minimum wage. This creates unemployment. • The cost of these interventions is found in reduced eÿciency (trades that are not made); there may be benefts in greater equity. 1.1.2 TO KNOW- Conceptual Understanding • Explain the di˙erence between a movement along the demand (supply) curve and a shift of the demand (supply) curve • Describe factors that shift supply and demand curves • Know “what’s wrong” with excess supply or excess demand 1.1.3 TO KNOW- Graphical and Math Understanding • Find a market equilibrium given a demand and supply curve- (a) graphi- cally and (b) using algebraic expressions • Analyze the e˙ect of a price ceiling in a graph • Analyze the e˙ect of a price foor in a graph 1 1.2 Lecture 3: Applying supply and demand 1.2.1 Elasticity • Price elasticity of demand is defned @Q Q = @P P • Perfectly inelastic demand is = 0 and perfectly elastic demand is = −∞: • The elasticity a˙ects consumers’ response to a shift in price: if the elas- ticity is between 0 and -1, then frms can raise revenues by raising the price (since consumers will still buy the good in signifcant quantities); if < −1, then raising the price results in a decline in frm revenue.
    [Show full text]
  • Volume 31, Issue 2
    Volume 31, Issue 2 Competing impure public goods and the sustainability of the theater arts Tyler Pugliese Jeffrey Wagner Economics Dept., Rochester Institute of Technology Economics Dept., Rochester Institute of Technology Abstract The general purpose of this paper is to extend the literature regarding public good provision when consumers may contribute via consumption of an impure public good and/or by donating directly to the public good. Standard models pose consumer utility as a function of one impure public good and one or more private goods. Our model features two competing impure public goods and two private goods: one that is a conventional substitute good and one that is a numeraire. We build most directly upon Kotchen's (2005) model of “green” consumption of impure public goods. We propose national and local live theater arts as an example of competing impure public goods. Our model shows that if local and national live theater are substitutes, and the national live theater (such as the Met) is strengthened via technological change (for instance, via simulcasts into local venues), the overall sustainability of the live theater arts may be diminished. We are grateful to Editor John Conley; an anonymous referee; session participants at the 2010 New York State Economics Association annual meeting (and particularly our discussant, Bill Kolberg); and session participants at the 2011 Midwest Economics Association annual meeting (and particularly our discussant, Carly Urban) for several helpful and encouraging comments. Citation: Tyler Pugliese and Jeffrey Wagner, (2011) ''Competing impure public goods and the sustainability of the theater arts'', Economics Bulletin, Vol. 31 no.2 pp.
    [Show full text]