Governance, Coordination and Distribution Along Commodity Value Chains

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Governance, Coordination and Distribution Along Commodity Value Chains FAO ISSN 1816-5303 COMMODITIES AND TRADE PROCEEDINGS 2 Governance, coordination and distribution along commodity value chains Rome, 4–5 April 2006 FAO COMMODITIES AND TRADE PROCEEDINGS 2 Governance, coordination and distribution along commodity value chains Rome, 4–5 April 2006 Trade and Markets Division FOOD AND AGRICULTURE ORGANIZATION OF THE UNITED NATIONS Rome, 2007 The designations employed and the presentation of material in this information product do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO) concerning the legal or development status of any country, territory, city or area or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers or boundaries. The mention of specific companies or products of manufacturers, whether or not these have been patented, does not imply that these have been endorsed or recommended by FAO in preference to others of a similar nature that are not mentioned. The papers contained in these proceedings have been reproduced as presented by the authors without further editing by FAO. ISBN 978-92-5-105748-3 All rights reserved. Reproduction and dissemination of material in this information product for educational or other non-commercial purposes are authorized without any prior written permission from the copyright holders provided the source is fully acknowledged. Reproduction of material in this information product for resale or other commercial purposes is prohibited without written permission of the copyright holders. Applications for such permission should be addressed to: Chief Electronic Publishing Policy and Support Branch Communication Division FAO Viale delle Terme di Caracalla, 00153 Rome, Italy or by e-mail to: [email protected] © FAO 2007 iii Table of contents Preface..................................................................................................................................................... v Introductory Note .................................................................................................................................... 1 Brian Moir PART 1.................................................................................................................................................... 7 CONCEPTUAL ISSUES OF MARKET STRUCTURE IN AGRICULTURAL COMMODITY VALUE CHAINS Market Control and Competition Ιssues along the Commodity Value Chain......................................... 9 Nikolaos Vettas Trade Liberalisation under Imperfect Competition in Commodity Markets......................................... 27 Steve McCorriston The Fall and Rise of Vertical Coordination in Commodity Chains in Developing and Transition Countries ............................................................................................................................................... 47 Miet Maertens and Johan F.M. Swinnen Contracting Issues at Various Levels of the Value Chain..................................................................... 69 Doyle Baker and Carlos Da Silva PART 2.................................................................................................................................................. 83 INSTITUTIONAL AND STRUCTURAL ISSUES IN COMMODITY MARKETS Standards and Supply-Chain Coordination - Impact on Small-Scale Producers................................... 85 Kees van der Meer Laura Ignacio Supermarkets, Horticultural Supply Chains, and Small Farmers in Central America .......................... 95 Thomas Reardon, Julio Berdegué,Luis Flores, Fernando Balsevich and Ricardo Hernández Transmission of Price Signals and the Distribution of Revenues along the Commodity Supply Chains: Review and Applications ....................................................................................................... 105 David Hallam and George Rapsomanikis Estimating the Pass-Through of Agricultural Policy Reforms: an Application to Brazilian Commodity Markets............................................................................................................................ 119 Jonathan Brook, Olga Melyukhina, Alastair Bailey and Kelvin Balcombe PART 3................................................................................................................................................ 139 FARMERS AND COMMODITY DEVELOPMENT The determinants of investments in coffee trees in Uganda................................................................ 141 Ruth Vargas Hill Market and other Constraints to Smallholder Coffee Development in Tanzania................................ 167 Alexander Sarris and Sara Savastano Assessing Small-holder Participation in Value Chains: the case of vegetables in Honduras and El Salvador .......................................................................................................................................... 209 Mark Lundy, Roberto Banegas, Lourdes Centeño, Iván Rodríguez, Manuel Alfaro, Santos Hernández and José Ángel Cruz iv PART 4................................................................................................................................................ 227 CHANGING MARKET STRUCTURES AND DISTRIBUTIONAL ISSUES Contracting, Competition and Rent Distribution in Commodity Value Chains.................................. 229 Johan F.M. Swinnen and Anneleen Vandeplas Domestic traders versus global retail chains: Evidence from Madagascar ......................................... 243 Bart Minten Value Chain Analysis and Market Power in Commodity Processing with Application to the Cocoa and Coffee Sectors ................................................................................................................... 267 Christopher L. Gilbert v Preface The Commodities and Trade Division1 of FAO organized a two day workshop on 4 and 5 April 2006 in Rome, immediately after the meeting of the Common Fund for Commodities (CFC) with the various Intergovernmental Commodity Bodies (ICBs), thus benefiting from the presence in Rome of experts on various commodities from around the world. Additional analysts presented their work to the workshop. The workshop was held in the light of significant changes which are continuing to take place in the value chains for many agricultural commodities, particularly those fresh products destined for supermarket shelves. The changing pattern of these value chains has important, but not well understood, implications both for domestic policy in producing countries and for international trade. The objective of the workshop was to explore the issues arising from the changing structure of the various commodity chains, and to guide the future work of the Division in this area, in order to produce information and analysis of use to the FAO members. The workshop brought together the latest thinking on these issues to provide a stock-taking of the various problems, and more importantly, to identify the policy and technical issues on which there is consensus, and those where further analytical and empirical work is needed. Alexander Sarris Director Trade and Markets Division 1 Now the Trade and Markets Division Proceedings of the FAO Workshop on Governance, Coordination and Distribution along Commodity Value Chains 1 Introductory Note Brian Moir2 A two-day workshop was held by the Commodities and Trade Division3 at FAO in Rome, 4-5 April 2006. The objective was to explore the issues arising from the changing structure of the various commodity chains, and to guide the future work of the Division in this area. This set of proceedings of the workshop is published to assist in understanding the implications of the developments in agricultural value chains and in the analysis of value chains by economists, from a competitive market structure to one where market players are characterised by varying degrees of market power. This changing pattern and the development of market power affect resource allocation in agriculture and equity between producers, and have implications for domestic as well as international policies. THE CHANGING PATTERN OF AGRICULTURAL MARKETS The traditional pattern of agricultural production and markets as described by economists was (and to a large extent, still is) one of more-or-less perfect competition, typified by, inter alia, product homogeneity, a large number of buyers and sellers, and freedom of entry to the market. Under this model, each small farmer determines the volume and type of output to be produced and placed on the market. The relationships between seller and buyer (producer:wholesaler; wholesaler:retailer) are generally limited to simple spot transactions. The widely noted exception to the free market was the operation of various state trading enterprises. In countries such as the communist states of Eastern Europe, as well as China and Viet Nam, the supply chain was integrated and controlled by the state. Production, processing, marketing, and the provision of inputs and credit were all centrally planned. But in other countries also the state played a significant role in vertical coordination in food supply chains. In many African countries, parastatal organizations provided inputs and extension services to farmers and purchased their output and, despite the liberalization that has occurred in the past 20 years, this state controlled vertical coordination is still common in some African countries. Elsewhere, the state controlled the export of commodities from Canada and Australia, and controlled imports into Japan,
Recommended publications
  • Working Paper No. 222
    Money and Taxes: The Chartalist L. Randall Wray” Working Paper No. 222 January 1998 *Senior Scholar, The Jerome Levy Economics Institute L. Rnndull Wray Introductory Quotes “A requirement that certain taxes should be paid in particular paper money might give that paper a certain value even if it was irredeemable.” (Edwin Cannan, Marginal Summary to page 3 12 of Adam Smith’s The Wealth of Nations, in Smith 1937: 3 12) “[T]he money of a State is not what is of compulsory general acceptance, but what is accepted at the public pay offices...” (Knapp 1924: vii) “Money is the creation of the state; it is not true to say that gold is international currency, for international contracts are never made in terms of gold, but always in terms of some national monetary unit; there is no important distinction between notes and metallic money.... ” Keynes (Keynes 1983: 402) “In an economy where government debt is a major asset on the books of the deposit- issuing banks, the fact that taxes need to be paid gives value to the money of the economy. The virtue of a balanced budget and a surplus insofar as the commodity value (purchasing power) of money is concerned is that the need to pay taxes means that people work and produce in order to get that in which taxes can be paid.” (Minsky 1986: 23 1) *****k*************X*********************~***********~****** Introduction In conventional analysis, money is used to facilitate exchange; its value was long determined by the value of the precious metal it represented, although under a fiat money system, its value is determined by the quantity of commodities it can purchase.
    [Show full text]
  • Commodity Dependence and International Commodity Prices
    commoDity DEpEndencE anD intErnational 2 commoDity pricEs Since low-income coutries depend mostly on just a few commodities for the bulk share of their export earnings, commodity price fluctuations directly affect the incidence of poverty, as the vast majority of the poor depend on primary commodities for their livelihoods. Photo: Martine Perret/UN Timor-Leste MartinePhoto: Perret/UN Commodity Dependence and International Commodity Prices Introduction The types of commodities exported by a country are another important determinant of a country’s vulnerability to exogenous economic shocks. The majority of developing countries are dependent on primary commodities1 for export revenues and, of the 141 developing countries, 95 depend on primary commodities for at least 50 percent of their export earnings (Brown 2008). However, international commodity prices are notoriously volatile in the short to medium term, sometimes varying by as much as 50 percent in a single year (South Centre 2005). Moreover, price volatility is increasing over time and across a broad range of commodities. “In the past 30 years, there have been as many price shocks across the range of commodities as there were in the preceding 75 years” (Brown 2008). From the perspective of developing countries, especially those whose principal means of foreign exchange earnings come from Over the longer term, dependence the exports of primary commodities, unstable commodity prices on primary commodities heightens create macro-economic instabilities and complicate macro- a country’s vulnerability because economic management. Erratic price movements generate erratic movements in export revenue, cause instability in foreign exchange (non-oil) primary commodity prices reserves and are strongly associated with growth volatility.
    [Show full text]
  • Money As 'Universal Equivalent' and Its Origins in Commodity Exchange
    MONEY AS ‘UNIVERSAL EQUIVALENT’ AND ITS ORIGIN IN COMMODITY EXCHANGE COSTAS LAPAVITSAS DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS SCHOOL OF ORIENTAL AND AFRICAN STUDIES UNIVERSITY OF LONDON [email protected] MAY 2003 1 1.Introduction The debate between Zelizer (2000) and Fine and Lapavitsas (2000) in the pages of Economy and Society refers to the conceptualisation of money. Zelizer rejects the theorising of money by neoclassical economics (and some sociology), and claims that the concept of ‘money in general’ is invalid. Fine and Lapavitsas also criticise the neoclassical treatment of money but argue, from a Marxist perspective, that ‘money in general’ remains essential for social science. Intervening, Ingham (2001) finds both sides confused and in need of ‘untangling’. It is worth stressing that, despite appearing to be equally critical of both sides, Ingham (2001: 305) ‘strongly agrees’ with Fine and Lapavitsas on the main issue in contention, and defends the importance of a theory of ‘money in general’. However, he sharply criticises Fine and Lapavitsas for drawing on Marx’s work, which he considers incapable of supporting a theory of ‘money in general’. Complicating things further, Ingham (2001: 305) also declares himself ‘at odds with Fine and Lapavitsas’s interpretation of Marx’s conception of money’. For Ingham, in short, Fine and Lapavitsas are right to stress the importance of ‘money in general’ but wrong to rely on Marx, whom they misinterpret to boot. Responding to these charges is awkward since, on the one hand, Ingham concurs with the main thrust of Fine and Lapavitsas and, on the other, there is little to be gained from contesting what Marx ‘really said’ on the issue of money.
    [Show full text]
  • MLP & Infrastructure
    Monthly Investment Commentary April 2021 Midstream: Last month, we discussed how midstream has historically provided inflation- resistant income in a way that REITs, utilities, and TIPS have not. Q1 earnings provided a strong case-in-point for this relationship, as midstream profited from commodity bottlenecks, while other sectors absorbed higher costs. This week’s Colonial Pipeline outage is another example of how underinvestment has created less infrastructure redundancy. The fundamental arguments for midstream – benefitting operationally from inflation, while reducing capital employed at a time of rising rates – continue to strengthen, especially compared to capital-intensive sectors like utilities and Cleantech. Natural Resources: As current inflationary pressures mount, the topic of 1970s inflation has grown in prominence. Our analysis of the 1970s highlights the stronger role commodities played in the early 1970s inflationary period, compared to the broader based inflation of the late 1970s. With commodity inflation increasing today in the relative absence of broad-based inflation, at this point, the early 1970s appears to be a more appropriate comparison than the late 1970s and could foreshadow an extended period of inflation. MLP & Infrastructure Performance review During the month of April 2021, the Recurrent MLP & Infrastructure Strategy generated net returns of +5.62%, underperforming the +7.15% return of the Alerian MLP Index (AMZ) by (1.53%). Since the strategy’s July 2017 inception, Recurrent’s MLP & Infrastructure Strategy has outperformed the AMZ by +3.74% (annualized, net of fees). Please see the performance section at bottom for more detail. One year since WTI oil prices went negative, commodity bottlenecks are increasingly frequent From oil and gas, to lumber, copper, steel and aluminum – commodity tightness is making itself felt across the global economy.
    [Show full text]
  • Commodity Value Measurement and Connotative Value Currency
    Theoretical Economics Letters, 2020, 10, 535-544 https://www.scirp.org/journal/tel ISSN Online: 2162-2086 ISSN Print: 2162-2078 Commodity Value Measurement and Connotative Value Currency Jinjun Cheng1, Dian Cheng2 1Anhui Development and Reform Commission, Hefei, China 2Pudong Development Bank Hefei Branch, Hefei, China How to cite this paper: Cheng, J. J., & Abstract Cheng, D. (2020). Commodity Value Mea- surement and Connotative Value Currency. Goods of utility, in the final analysis, contain two parts of natural value and Theoretical Economics Letters, 10, 535-544. labor value: the natural value is created by god and given to us for free, the https://doi.org/10.4236/tel.2020.103034 labor value is the human labor which is condensed in the commodity without Received: April 26, 2020 any difference, and the commodity value is reflected by the labor value. The Accepted: May 24, 2020 essence of human labor is the process of consuming the energy and life time Published: May 27, 2020 of the body and doing physical work to the object of labor. The value of labor, W, is the square root of the product of the energy consumed by the worker, E, Copyright © 2020 by author(s) and Scientific Research Publishing Inc. and the time spent on labor, T (W = ET ). By discovering the formula of This work is licensed under the Creative commodity labor value, we can design a new currency that conforms to the Commons Attribution International principles of freedom and fairness—the Talent (symbol: Ω|| ), whose value License (CC BY 4.0). || http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ corresponds to its value: 1 Ω = 1 JS⋅ , J is joules, S is seconds.
    [Show full text]
  • Abstract Labor: Substance Or Form
    ABSTRACT LABOR: SUBSTANCE OR FORM ABSTRACT LABOR: SUBSTANCE OR FORM? A CRITIQUE OF THE VALUE-FORM INTERPRETATION OF MARX’S THEORY by Fred Moseley Universidad Autonoma Metropolitana (Mexico City) Mount Holyoke College (Massachusetts) May 1997 Our analysis has shown that the form of value, that is the expression of the value of a commodity, arises from the nature of commodity value, as opposed to value and its magnitude arising from their mode of expression as exchange-value. Marx (C. I. 152) It is not money that renders commodities commensurable. Quite the contrary. Because all commodities, as values, are objective human labor and therefore themselves commensurable, their values can be communally measured in one and the same commodity. Mon ey is the necessary form of appearance of the measure of value immanent in commodities - labor-time. Marx (C.I. 188) ABSTRACT LABOR: SUBSTANCE OR FORM? A CRITIQUE OF THE VALUE-FORM INTERPRETATION OF MARX’S THEORY In the Introduction to our first book, I wrote: All the authors agree that Marx attempted in Section 1 of Chapter 1 of Capital to derive abstract labor as the "substance of value," which exists prior to exchange - although it is not observable - and which determines the exchange values of com modities. But there is significant disagreement over the validity file:///C|/Documents%20and%20Settings/mhcuserxp/Desktop/VALUEFRM.htm (1 of 15)10/15/2005 2:29:42 PM ABSTRACT LABOR: SUBSTANCE OR FORM and necessity of Marx’s derivation. Indeed this disagreement is probably the most significant one amount the authors. This controversy has a long history beginning with Boehm-Bawerk.
    [Show full text]
  • The Preeminence of Gold and Silver As Shariah Money
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Preeminence of Gold and Silver as Shariah Money Krichene, Noureddine and Ghassan, Hassan B. Umm Al-Qura University, IMF 2017 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/95445/ MPRA Paper No. 95445, posted 07 Aug 2019 03:57 UTC The Preeminence of Gold and Silver as Shariah Money Noureddine Krichene1 and Hassan Ghassan2 Published in Thunderbird International Business Review volume 61:821-835, 2019 Abstract Shariah money is gold and silver, supplied by the market on profit criterion. Everywhere, government inconvertible paper money arose from bankruptcy. A government with balanced budgets would never need it. Imposed by force, inconvertible paper is a taxation mean, highly inflationary, and causes impoverishment. Unjust and bankrupt governments will continue to force this despotic money. Islamic Monetary Economics refutes the idea of money as a policy tool. Fully convertible paper is Shariah compliant. Shariah requires a just government to balance its budgets and restore fully gold and silver as lawful money. Key words. Shariah, money, gold-silver, inconvertible paper, inflation, bankruptcy. JEL Classification. E42, E5, F33 1 Professor Noureddine Krichene is an economist, previously affiliated to the International Monetary Fund, and former advisor at the Islamic Development Bank, Jeddah: [email protected] 2 Professor Hassan Ghassan (Corresponding author) is an economist at the University of Umm Al-Qura, Department of economics, Makkah: [email protected] 1 1. Introduction Money is defined as the cash in circulation; it is perfectly liquid, unanimously accepted in all transactions. Previously, it included gold and silver coins. Presently, it is government currency. Money substitutes may be less liquid.
    [Show full text]
  • Value and the Valuation of Art in Economic And
    ( 170 M_ Huller 1111d 1<. Shu_\.tl--'mwrl Clwptl.'r6 Abstract VALUE AND THE VALUATION OF ART IN ECONOMIC Artistic value played a minor role in classkal philosophy, bul ~~loved to center stage in 18th century ae._<;theric theory and also played a role in moral philosophy. The value AND AESTHETIC THEORY of Art and the process of its valuation has remained an indispensable subject of mod­ ern aesthetics, while economists have excluded these topics from consideration. Recent MICHAEL HUTTER attention to "external effect;;" has opened new ways of interpreting artistic value in a manner consistent with economic theory. Sections 1-5 narrate historical positions in both disciplines, many of which have left their imprint on current analysis. Sec­ RICHARD SHUSTERMAN tions 6-8 focus on the contemporary discussion of artistic values and their logic of Florida AtlallfiC Uuiversity. Boca Raton. F"!orida. USA evaluation in economics and in aesthetics. Contents Abstract 170 Keywords Keywords 170 l . Premodern theories 171 artistic valuation, consumption skills, tastes, use value 2. Art in early subjectivist theories 174 3. Art in 19th century economics and aesthetics 183 JEL c!ass{fication: Zll 4. Art in economic theory until the 1970s 187 5. Art in aesthetics until the 1990s 189 6. Varieties of artistic external effects in contemporary economics 193 7. Varieties of artistic value in contemporary aesthetics, and their economic val- uation 197 8. The logic of aesthetic and economic evaluation 201 References 205 Handbook of the Economics of Arr and Culture. Volume Edited 1>.1' Victor k Ginslno:~h and Dm·id Thms!J_r Copyright© 2.006 Elsel'ier B.
    [Show full text]
  • Marx's Commodity and Labour As the Substance of Value*
    Marx's Commodity and Labour as the Substance of Value* Pablo Ahumada La Trobe University School of Economics Bundoora, 3086 Victoria, AUSTRALIA Email: [email protected] * I am grateful to Professor John King and Professor Pablo Levín for helpful feedback on this paper. Any errors in it, however, are the sole responsibility of the author. Marx's Commodity and Labour as the Substance of Value Abstract This paper reinterprets Marx’s theory of value in the context of his theory of the commodity. The labour theory of value is derived from the analysis of the immediate form of appearance of the commodity as an exchangeable good. The subject matter of neoclassical economics is thereby critically appropriated and used to motivate the transition to the concept of labour value. The neoclassical theory of the commodity, in turn, is transcended and subsumed under the theoretical framework of Classical Political Economy. This shows that production is the organisation of the labour of society for its own material reproduction, or the unity-in- difference of a labour process and a social relation. This breaks the false immediate identification of supply with production and of means of labour with capital. It thus becomes evident that the labour theory of value considers all inputs to production and that it can accommodate neoclassical economics’ marginal principle. JEL Classification: B14, D51, P10 Keywords: Labour Theory of Value, Commodity, Marx ii Marx's Commodity and Labour as the Substance of Value I. Introduction The labour theory of value, in particular Marx’s (1867, 1885, 1894) rendering of it, has caused heated controversy in economics over the years.1 The discussion has focussed almost entirely on Marx’s (1894) transformation of labour values into prices of production and thus overlooked the fact that the concept of value refers to one of the most generic aspects of the commodity, and hence of capitalist production.
    [Show full text]
  • 127. Commodity Versus Gift As Metaphor for Market Versus Non
    SOAS Department of Economics Working Paper 127 COMMODITY VERSUS GIFT AS METAPHOR FOR MARKET VERSUS NON- MARKET RELATIONS COSTAS LAPAVITSAS DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS SCHOOL OF ORIENTAL AND AFRICAN STUDIES UNIVERSITY OF LONDON THORNHAUGH ST, RUSSELL SQ LONDON WC1 0XG UK [email protected] ABSTRACT In social science gifts are frequently contrasted with commodities. Commodities are assumed to stand for rationality and commercial gain, in short the economic realm. Gifts are presumed to be bearers of moral obligation and social concerns, that is, to represent the non-economic realm. However, it is shown in this article that commodities also rest on, and give rise to, a wealth of non-market relations. Thus, the use of commodity vs. gift as metaphor for market vs. non-market relations in a capitalist society is misleading. This article demonstrates that for the analysis of the interaction between market and non- market relations what is instead required is understanding of capital as a set of social relations, along lines provided by Marxist political economy. 1 1.Introduction: Commodities and gifts as tokens of market and non-market exchange. i Reciprocity and the moral aspects of gift transactions have long attracted theoretical interest in anthropology, and social science more generally. Mauss’ (1925) essay on the gift has continually attracted commentary of the highest calibre (Levi- Strauss 1950, Sahlins 1972). Polanyi and his school made reciprocity one of the pillars of their analysis of non-market-based societies (Polanyi, et. al., 1957). Gouldner (1960) found in reciprocity a universal ‘moral norm’ for all human societies. There have been entire theories of ‘social exchange’ resting on reciprocity (Homans 1958, Blau 1964).
    [Show full text]
  • Agricultural Commodity Value Chains: the Effects of Market Concentration on Farmers and Producing Countries – the Case of Cocoa
    United Nations TD/B/63/2 United Nations Conference Distr.: General 14 October 2016 on Trade and Development Original: English Trade and Development Board Sixty-third session Geneva, 5–9 December 2016 Item 2 of the provisional agenda Evolution of the international trading system and its trends from a development perspective Agricultural commodity value chains: The effects of market concentration on farmers and producing countries – the case of cocoa Note by the UNCTAD secretariat Executive summary This note discusses market concentration and the distribution of value among stakeholders in agricultural commodity global value chains. Specifically, the note examines the structure of the cocoa industry, in which the already weak position of dispersed, smallholding farmers in global value chains continues to be undermined by other well-integrated stakeholders, including traders, processors and manufacturers of cocoa and chocolate products. This structure, which prevails across most agricultural commodity value chains worldwide, leaves limited room for farmers to increase revenues to cover production costs and provide them with a margin for a decent livelihood, and this may undermine the sustainability of farming businesses unless concerted actions are taken to address the situation. This note highlights some policy options for supporting small-scale stakeholders in agricultural commodity global value chains, especially farmers, in the face of increasing concentration in all segments of such chains. GE.16-17838(E) TD/B/63/2 I. Introduction 1. Concentration at all stages along agricultural commodity value chains – including horizontal concentration and vertical integration – has become a topical issue in recent years.1 A limited number of large companies control a large part of the markets, from trading to the processing and retailing of agricultural products.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Marx's Explanation of Money's Functions: Overturning the Quantity
    1 Marx’s Explanation of Money’s Functions: Overturning the Quantity Theory Martha Campbell At the beginning of the Chapter on Money in the Grundrisse, Marx discusses the operation and effects of ‘modern credit institutions’, touching on several of the questions he will later consider in Capital, Vol. III. An argument he will later present in Capital, Vol. II is implicit in his rhetorical question: would ‘large scale modern industry’ be possible ‘without the concentration of credit …created’ by “our present banks’? Referring to the great variety of financial instruments generated by the credit system, he states that ‘the thousand forms of circulating paper…are as much the preconditions as the product of modern commerce and modern industry’.1 It is clear from this that Marx knows that capitalist money is not gold and, moreover, that capitalism could not have developed as it did without the credit system. The obvious question, then, is, if he knows it is unrealistic to assume that money is gold, why does he do this throughout Capital? There is the obvious ‘expositional’ advantage that gold money gives Marx a way of presenting money and value so that he can proceed to the concept of capital, which presupposes both; banking, by contrast, presupposes not only capital but the division into different kinds of capital.2 Another expositional convenience is that Marx uses gold money throughout Capital, Vol. I as the measure, or expression of value, in order to explain, for example, the origin of surplus value and the factors that influence its quantity. By treating gold 1 All quotations from Marx 1939: 122.
    [Show full text]