Economics 11 Definitions

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Economics 11 Definitions Economics 11 Caltech Spring 2010 Problem Set 4 Homework Policy: Study You can study the homework on your own or with a group of fellow students. You should feel free to consult notes, text books and so forth. The quiz will be available Wednesday at 5pm. Following the Honor code, you should find 20 minutes and do the quiz, by yourself and without using any notes. Paper and pen should be all you need. Then turn it in by Thursday 5pm. (drop off in box in front of Baxter 133). It will include one question from each section The answers to the whole homework will be available Friday at 2pm. Definitions Please explain each term in three lines or less! • Shadow value The shadow value of capital refers to the value associated with a constraint, i.e. when capital cannot be adjusted in the short‐run it creates a constraint on the profit. • Marginal product The additional output that can be produced by one more unit of a particular input while holding all other inputs constant. It is usually assumed that an input’s marginal productivity diminishes as additional units of the input are put into use while holding other inputs fixed. If ,, • Marginal cost The cost of producing an additional unit of output. • Short‐run marginal cost The cost of producing an additional unit of output without changing anything you cannot change quickly (such as building new factories). In the short run, some inputs (e.g., capital) are fixed, i.e., cannot be adjusted to change output levels. In such case (e.g., assuming that capital is not adjustable in the short run), the marginal cost given the amount of capital used is the derivative of the total costs with respect to the quantity of output. In other words, | , , • Short‐run average cost of production The short‐run average cost is the short run total cost of production divided by quantity, where one factor of production is fixed. It is just the short‐run total cost of productions (i.e., holding K fixed) divided by the output, i.e., | the average of the total cost in the short run per unit of output: • Revealed preference The preference of consumers can be revealed by their purchasing habits. • Fixed costs Costs that do not change as the level of output changes in the short run. Fixed costs are in many respects irrelevant to the theory of short run price determination. • Total Factor Productivity A variable which accounts for effects in total output not caused by inputs. For example, a year with unusually good weather will tend to have higher output, because bad weather hinders agricultural product. A variable like weather does not directly relate to unit inputs, so weather is considered a total‐factor productivity variable (Wiki). Word problems Please explain each question in a few sentences. • Consider fixed capital, what are the implications of the first order condition of the profit maximization problem? What does the second order condition imply? Given a fixed level of capital K, the firm chooses L to maximize profit. From the firm’s (short‐run) profits , , we obtain the first order condition: , , 0 , where the left‐hand side of the last equality if the value of the marginal product of labor, and the right hand‐side is the wage rate. This implies that the firm will add workers to the production process up to the point where a worker just pays his salary, in the sense that the value of the marginal product for that worker equals the cost of hiring him. The second‐order condition, in turn, can be written as: , . This expression has to be negative (or non‐positive) since, at a maximum, the slope goes from positive (when the function is increasing up to the maximum) to zero (a the maximum) to a negative number (as the variable rises past the maximum). • Why do ships and taxis go at slower speeds as a short run adjustment to recessions? Given that capital equipment – and thus, the cost of capital – is fixed in the short run, taxis and ships adjust to recessions by lowering variable costs. By going at slower speeds, the cost of gas decrease, thus lowering variable costs. • Sketch the average total cost (ATC), average variable cost (AVC) and marginal cost (MC) of a firm (dollars vs. quantity). Why does the MC curve necessarily intersect at the minimum of the AVC and ATC curves? Maximize: 0 Multiply through by : So at the minimum of , , follow similar steps to get intersects at the minimum of . • Why does a profit‐maximizing firm produce the quantity , where price equals marginal cost, given price is as large as minimum average variable cost? Why does a profit‐maximizing firm shut down if the price falls below the minimum average variable cost of production? The profit maximizing firm maximizes profit (shaded blue) when it produces quantity where price equals marginal cost. The profit‐maximizing firm shuts down if price falls below the minimum AVC because the firm will start losing money. The firm’s (short‐run) profits are given by: |, and thus it maximizes profits by choosing the quantity satisfying a) 0 |. This is a good strategy only if producing a positive quantity is desirable, i.e. if | 0, , that is, if |, b) |, where is the average cost ignoring the investment in capital equipment (recall that the cost of capital is fixed in the short run, and thus 0, 0). Hence, the profit‐maximizing firm produces the quantity where price equals marginal cost, provided that p is as large as minimum average variable cost. If price falls below minimum average variable cost, the firm shuts down, since it is more convenient for the firm to face the fixed costs of producing 0 units than to produce a positive quantity (i.e., it loses less by producing 0). • What does 0 and 0, where , is the production function and and are capital and labor, imply about labor and capital? Provide an example of each case and draw the respective isoquants. 0 implies that and are substitutes—increase in makes an increase in boost production less. 0 implies that and are complements—increase in makes an increase in boost production more. • Suppose we have a profit‐maximizing firm and is the fixed optimum price required. What does a decline in output price imply about cost of production? What does an increase in wages imply about labor productivity? At the optimum, the profit‐maximizing firm produces the quantity where the price equals the marginal cost. Ceteris paribus, a decline in price thus will require a corresponding decrease in the marginal cost of productions – and hence a decline in the cost of production. Ceteris paribus, an increase in wages has to be matched by an increase in labor productivity, since profit , maximization requires that . Technical problems • Suppose a company has total cost given by where capital is fixed in the short‐run. o What is the short‐run average total cost and marginal cost? Plot these curves. 2 o For a given quantity , what level of capital minimizes total cost? What is the minimum average total cost of ? Minimize total cost wrt : 0 2 2 √2 Minimize average total cost wrt : 0 2 2 √2 o Suppose capital can be adjusted in the long‐run. Does this company have an increasing return to scale, decreasing returns to scale or constant returns to scale? So we optimize the total cost with respect to and plug in: √2 2√2 1 √2 2√2 So the average total cost is constant independent of so constant return to scale. • Professor Smith and Professor Jones are going to write a textbook together. Their production function for the book is //, where is the number of pages in the finished book, is the number of working hours spent by Smith, and is the number of hours spent working by Jones. Smith values his labor as $3 per working hour. He has spent 900 hours preparing for the first draft. Jones, whose labor is valued at $12 per working hour, will revise Smith’s draft to complete the book. o How many hours will Jones have to spend to produce a finished book of 150 pages? Of 300 pages? Of 450 pages? 3 12 Plug in 12 3 Minimize total cost with respect to : 12 3 0 2 2 But we also need to stipulate that 900. If 150, then Smith has already worked more than the equilibrium amount so we just need the smallest TC even though it won’t be a minimum. For 900, 12 3 312/360 So 900 150 25 900 Similarly, if 300, and 900 12 3 312/90 So 900 300 100 900 And if 450 and 900, then 12 12 3 3 0 4 So 900 450 225 900 o What is the marginal cost of the 150th pages of the finished book? Of the 300th page? Of the 450th page? In the previous part we showed that Smith doesn’t put in any more hours for 450 so 30 900 12 12 2700 2700 900 24 900 If 150, 4. If 300, 8. If 450, then 12. • A lawn mowing company uses two sizes of mowers to cut lawns. The smaller mowers have a 24‐ inch blade and are used on lawns with many trees and obstacles. The larger mowers are exactly twice as big as the smaller mowers and are used on open lawns where maneuverability is not so difficult. The two production functions available to the company are1: Output Capital input Labor input (square feet) (# of 24’’ mowers) Larger mowers 8000 2 1 Small mowers 5000 1 1 o Graph the 40000 square feet isoquant for the first production function.
Recommended publications
  • Managerial Economics Unit 6: Oligopoly
    Managerial Economics Unit 6: Oligopoly Rudolf Winter-Ebmer Johannes Kepler University Linz Summer Term 2019 Managerial Economics: Unit 6 - Oligopoly1 / 45 OBJECTIVES Explain how managers of firms that operate in an oligopoly market can use strategic decision-making to maintain relatively high profits Understand how the reactions of market rivals influence the effectiveness of decisions in an oligopoly market Managerial Economics: Unit 6 - Oligopoly2 / 45 Oligopoly A market with a small number of firms (usually big) Oligopolists \know" each other Characterized by interdependence and the need for managers to explicitly consider the reactions of rivals Protected by barriers to entry that result from government, economies of scale, or control of strategically important resources Managerial Economics: Unit 6 - Oligopoly3 / 45 Strategic interaction Actions of one firm will trigger re-actions of others Oligopolist must take these possible re-actions into account before deciding on an action Therefore, no single, unified model of oligopoly exists I Cartel I Price leadership I Bertrand competition I Cournot competition Managerial Economics: Unit 6 - Oligopoly4 / 45 COOPERATIVE BEHAVIOR: Cartel Cartel: A collusive arrangement made openly and formally I Cartels, and collusion in general, are illegal in the US and EU. I Cartels maximize profit by restricting the output of member firms to a level that the marginal cost of production of every firm in the cartel is equal to the market's marginal revenue and then charging the market-clearing price. F Behave like a monopoly I The need to allocate output among member firms results in an incentive for the firms to cheat by overproducing and thereby increase profit.
    [Show full text]
  • Total Cost and Profit
    4/22/2016 Total Cost and Profit Gina Rablau Gina Rablau - Total Cost and Profit A Mini Project for Module 1 Project Description This project demonstrates the following concepts in integral calculus: Indefinite integrals. Project Description Use integration to find total cost functions from information involving marginal cost (that is, the rate of change of cost) for a commodity. Use integration to derive profit functions from the marginal revenue functions. Optimize profit, given information regarding marginal cost and marginal revenue functions. The marginal cost for a commodity is MC = C′(x), where C(x) is the total cost function. Thus if we have the marginal cost function, we can integrate to find the total cost. That is, C(x) = Ȅ ͇̽ ͬ͘ . The marginal revenue for a commodity is MR = R′(x), where R(x) is the total revenue function. If, for example, the marginal cost is MC = 1.01(x + 190) 0.01 and MR = ( /1 2x +1)+ 2 , where x is the number of thousands of units and both revenue and cost are in thousands of dollars. Suppose further that fixed costs are $100,236 and that production is limited to at most 180 thousand units. C(x) = ∫ MC dx = ∫1.01(x + 190) 0.01 dx = (x + 190 ) 01.1 + K 1 Gina Rablau Now, we know that the total revenue is 0 if no items are produced, but the total cost may not be 0 if nothing is produced. The fixed costs accrue whether goods are produced or not. Thus the value for the constant of integration depends on the fixed costs FC of production.
    [Show full text]
  • Externalities and Public Goods Introduction 17
    17 Externalities and Public Goods Introduction 17 Chapter Outline 17.1 Externalities 17.2 Correcting Externalities 17.3 The Coase Theorem: Free Markets Addressing Externalities on Their Own 17.4 Public Goods 17.5 Conclusion Introduction 17 Pollution is a major fact of life around the world. • The United States has areas (notably urban) struggling with air quality; the health costs are estimated at more than $100 billion per year. • Much pollution is due to coal-fired power plants operating both domestically and abroad. Other forms of pollution are also common. • The noise of your neighbor’s party • The person smoking next to you • The mess in someone’s lawn Introduction 17 These outcomes are evidence of a market failure. • Markets are efficient when all transactions that positively benefit society take place. • An efficient market takes all costs and benefits, both private and social, into account. • Similarly, the smoker in the park is concerned only with his enjoyment, not the costs imposed on other people in the park. • An efficient market takes these additional costs into account. Asymmetric information is a source of market failure that we considered in the last chapter. Here, we discuss two further sources. 1. Externalities 2. Public goods Externalities 17.1 Externalities: A cost or benefit that affects a party not directly involved in a transaction. • Negative externality: A cost imposed on a party not directly involved in a transaction ‒ Example: Air pollution from coal-fired power plants • Positive externality: A benefit conferred on a party not directly involved in a transaction ‒ Example: A beekeeper’s bees not only produce honey but can help neighboring farmers by pollinating crops.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Evaluation Glossary of Terms
    Economic Evaluation Glossary of Terms A Attributable fraction: indirect health expenditures associated with a given diagnosis through other diseases or conditions (Prevented fraction: indicates the proportion of an outcome averted by the presence of an exposure that decreases the likelihood of the outcome; indicates the number or proportion of an outcome prevented by the “exposure”) Average cost: total resource cost, including all support and overhead costs, divided by the total units of output B Benefit-cost analysis (BCA): (or cost-benefit analysis) a type of economic analysis in which all costs and benefits are converted into monetary (dollar) values and results are expressed as either the net present value or the dollars of benefits per dollars expended Benefit-cost ratio: a mathematical comparison of the benefits divided by the costs of a project or intervention. When the benefit-cost ratio is greater than 1, benefits exceed costs C Comorbidity: presence of one or more serious conditions in addition to the primary disease or disorder Cost analysis: the process of estimating the cost of prevention activities; also called cost identification, programmatic cost analysis, cost outcome analysis, cost minimization analysis, or cost consequence analysis Cost effectiveness analysis (CEA): an economic analysis in which all costs are related to a single, common effect. Results are usually stated as additional cost expended per additional health outcome achieved. Results can be categorized as average cost-effectiveness, marginal cost-effectiveness,
    [Show full text]
  • Principles of Microeconomics
    PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS A. Competition The basic motivation to produce in a market economy is the expectation of income, which will generate profits. • The returns to the efforts of a business - the difference between its total revenues and its total costs - are profits. Thus, questions of revenues and costs are key in an analysis of the profit motive. • Other motivations include nonprofit incentives such as social status, the need to feel important, the desire for recognition, and the retaining of one's job. Economists' calculations of profits are different from those used by businesses in their accounting systems. Economic profit = total revenue - total economic cost • Total economic cost includes the value of all inputs used in production. • Normal profit is an economic cost since it occurs when economic profit is zero. It represents the opportunity cost of labor and capital contributed to the production process by the producer. • Accounting profits are computed only on the basis of explicit costs, including labor and capital. Since they do not take "normal profits" into consideration, they overstate true profits. Economic profits reward entrepreneurship. They are a payment to discovering new and better methods of production, taking above-average risks, and producing something that society desires. The ability of each firm to generate profits is limited by the structure of the industry in which the firm is engaged. The firms in a competitive market are price takers. • None has any market power - the ability to control the market price of the product it sells. • A firm's individual supply curve is a very small - and inconsequential - part of market supply.
    [Show full text]
  • PRINCIPLES of MICROECONOMICS 2E
    PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS 2e Chapter 8 Perfect Competition PowerPoint Image Slideshow Competition in Farming Depending upon the competition and prices offered, a wheat farmer may choose to grow a different crop. (Credit: modification of work by Daniel X. O'Neil/Flickr Creative Commons) 8.1 Perfect Competition and Why It Matters ● Market structure - the conditions in an industry, such as number of sellers, how easy or difficult it is for a new firm to enter, and the type of products that are sold. ● Perfect competition - each firm faces many competitors that sell identical products. • 4 criteria: • many firms produce identical products, • many buyers and many sellers are available, • sellers and buyers have all relevant information to make rational decisions, • firms can enter and leave the market without any restrictions. ● Price taker - a firm in a perfectly competitive market that must take the prevailing market price as given. 8.2 How Perfectly Competitive Firms Make Output Decisions ● A perfectly competitive firm has only one major decision to make - what quantity to produce? ● A perfectly competitive firm must accept the price for its output as determined by the product’s market demand and supply. ● The maximum profit will occur at the quantity where the difference between total revenue and total cost is largest. Total Cost and Total Revenue at a Raspberry Farm ● Total revenue for a perfectly competitive firm is a straight line sloping up; the slope is equal to the price of the good. ● Total cost also slopes up, but with some curvature. ● At higher levels of output, total cost begins to slope upward more steeply because of diminishing marginal returns.
    [Show full text]
  • Section 3-7 Marginal Analysis in Business and Economics ➤ Marginal Cost, Revenue, and Profit ➤ Application ➤ Marginal Average Cost, Revenue, and Profit
    202 Chapter 3 The Derivative Section 3-7 Marginal Analysis in Business and Economics ➤ Marginal Cost, Revenue, and Profit ➤ Application ➤ Marginal Average Cost, Revenue, and Profit ➤ Marginal Cost, Revenue, and Profit One important use of calculus in business and economics is in marginal analy- sis. In economics, the word marginal refers to a rate of change, that is, to a de- rivative. Thus, if C(x) is the total cost of producing x items, then C¿(x) is called the marginal cost and represents the instantaneous rate of change of total cost with respect to the number of items produced. Similarly, the marginal revenue is the derivative of the total revenue function and the marginal profit is the de- rivative of the total profit function. Copyright 2005 Pearson Education, Inc., publishing as Pearson Prentice Hall Section 3-7 Marginal Analysis in Business and Economics 203 DEFINITION Marginal Cost, Revenue, and Profit If x is the number of units of a product produced in some time interval, then total cost = C(x) marginal cost = C¿(x) total revenue = R(x) marginal revenue = R¿(x) total profit = P(x) = R(x) - C(x) marginal profit = P¿(x) = R¿(x) - C¿(x) = (marginal revenue) - (marginal cost) Marginal cost (or revenue or profit) is the instantaneous rate of change of cost (or revenue or profit) relative to production at a given production level. To begin our discussion, we consider a cost function C(x). It is important to remember that C(x) represents the total cost of producing x items, not the cost of producing a single item.
    [Show full text]
  • An Externality Is an Unintended Consequence of a Choice That Falls on Someone Other Than the Decision-Maker
    © 2010 Pearson Education Canada An externality is an unintended consequence of a choice that falls on someone other than the decision-maker. Externalities may be positive or negative Externalities may arise in consumption or production © 2010 Pearson Education Canada Production Externalities Production externalities drive a wedge between the marginal private cost (MC) that is borne by the producer, and the marginal social cost (MSC) that is the total cost to society. MSC = MC + marginal external cost The marginal external cost is the cost of producing one more unit of a good or service that falls on people other than the producer. © 2010 Pearson Education Canada Negative Production Externalities © 2010 Pearson Education Canada Negative Production Externalities: Pollution Production and Pollution: How Much? In the market for a good with an externality that is unregulated, the amount of pollution created depends on the equilibrium quantity of the good produced. © 2010 Pearson Education Canada Negative Externalities: Pollution Figure 16.2 shows the equilibrium in an unregulated market with an external cost. The quantity produced is where marginal private cost equals marginal social benefit. © 2010 Pearson Education Canada Negative Externalities: Pollution At the market equilibrium, MSB is less than MSC, so the market produces an inefficient quantity. At the efficient quantity, marginal social cost equals marginal social benefit. With no regulation, the market overproduces and creates a deadweight loss. © 2010 Pearson Education Canada Consumption Externalities Consumption externalities drive a wedge between the marginal private benefit (MB) that is borne by the producer, and the marginal social benefit (MSB) that is the total cost to society.
    [Show full text]
  • Externalities
    Externalities I don’ t care about you F*** you! - Guns N’ Roses Externalities An externality is an uncompensated cost or benefit that the decision-maker imposes on others. An external benefit or positive externality is a benefit that comes to individuals other than the decision- maker, for which the decision-maker is not compensated. Example: fixinggp up house exterior; bees An external cost or negative externality is a cost imposed on individuals other than the decision-maker, for which they are not compensated. Example: pollution; traffic congestion 1 Negative externalities An external cost or negative externality is a P cost imposed on MSC individuals other than the $500 decision-maker, for which they are not compensated. $200 The marginal social cost , MSC, (the cost to MB = MSB everybody) is greater than the marginal cost to the MC decision-maker. Q Socially optimal Market-determined Example: pollution quantity quantity Externalities and efficiency The market -determined quantity is inefficient. P MSC The marginal social cost $500 is greater than the marginal social benefit. Reducing the quantity of pollution would decrease the social cost more than $200 it would decrease the social benefit. MB = MSB But the decision-maker MC has no incentive to take Q the external cost into Socially optimal Market-determined account. quantity quantity 2 Externalities and market failure What’s the problem? Market failure - there is no market for pollution: If there were a price for pollution (that the polluter has to pay to those who bear the cost of pollution), the polluter would take the external cost into account.
    [Show full text]
  • Understanding and Maximizing America's Evolutionary Economy
    UNDERSTANDING AND MAXIMIZING AMERICA’S EVOLUTIONARY ECONOMY ITIF The Information Technology & Innovation Foundation DR. ROBERT D. ATKINSON i UNDERSTANDING AND MAXIMIZING AMERICA’S EVOLUTIONARY ECONOMY DR. ROBERT D. ATKINSON OCTOBER 2014 DR. ROBERT D. ATKINSON ITIF The Information Technology & Innovation Foundation In the conventional view, the U.S. economy is a static entity, changing principally only in size (growing in normal times and contracting during recessions). But in reality, our economy is a constantly evolving complex ecosystem. The U.S. economy of 2014 is different, not just larger, than the economy of 2013. Understanding that we are dealing with an evolutionary rather than static economy has significant implications for the conceptu- alization of both economics and economic policy. Unfortunately, the two major economic doctrines that guide U.S. policymakers’ thinking—neoclassical economics and neo-Keynesian economics—are rooted in overly simplistic models of how the economy works and therefore generate flawed policy solutions. Because these doctrines emphasize the “economy as machine” model, policymakers have developed a mechanical view of policy; if they pull a lever (e.g., implement a regulation, program, or tax policy), they will get an expected result. In actuality, economies are complex evolutionary systems, which means en- abling and ensuring robust rates of evolution requires much more than the standard menu of favored options blessed by the prevailing doctrines: limiting government (for conservatives), protecting worker and “consumer” welfare (for liberals), and smoothing business cycles (for both). As economies evolve, so too do doctrines Any new economic and governing systems. After WWII when the framework for America’s United States was shifting from what Michael “fourth republic” needs Lind calls the second republic (the post-Civil War governance system) to the third republic to be grounded in an (the post-New-Deal, Great Society governance evolutionary understanding.
    [Show full text]
  • Intermediate Microeconomics
    Intermediate Microeconomics COSTS BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD PURDUE UNIVERSITY No free lunch Previously we have examined the result of a firm using inputs in a production process . that output is produced. We saw the concept of the isoquant map, which indicated that there are many different input combinations that will result in the same quantity of output. If the inputs were free, there would be no point in choosing which combination to use. ◦ But employing inputs is not free for the firm. Since it has to pay its workers and its suppliers of capital, the firm is interested in the combination of inputs that will minimize its costs. “Prices” of labor and capital Suppliers of labor (workers) are paid a wage rate per unit of time they devote to working for the firm. ◦ Denote the wage rate as (w). Suppliers of capital are paid a rental rate for each unit of capital they let the firm use. ◦ Denote the rental rate as (v). The wage rate times the number of labor hours used and the rental rate times the number of “machine hours” used by the firm represent its costs. The firm’s costs When a firm uses two inputs (capital and labor), its costs are: ( ) = + . This is the firm’s cost function .∗ ∗ The firm will choose L and K in such a way as to minimize TC for any given level of output. w and v as opportunity costs The wage rate is the amount per hour that the worker could get in his next-best employment opportunity. ◦ The firm has to pay him at least this much to prevent him from taking the other job.
    [Show full text]
  • Marginal Analysis Math165: Business Calculus
    Marginal Analysis Math165: Business Calculus Roy M. Lowman Spring 2010 Roy M. Lowman Marginal Analysis Marginal Analysis Marginal Cost - two definitions Marginal cost: From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia In economics and finance, marginal cost is the change in total cost that arises when the quantity produced changes by one unit. That is, it is the cost of producing one more unit of a good. Mathematically, the marginal cost (MC) function is expressed as the first derivative of the total cost (TC) function with respect to quantity (Q). Note that there are two definitions: Practical Definition: marginal cost is the change in total cost that arises when the quantity produced changes by one unit Formal definition used in calculus: marginal cost (MC) function is expressed as the first derivative of the total cost (TC) function with respect to quantity (q). Roy M. Lowman Marginal Analysis Marginal Analysis Marginal Cost - two definitions Marginal cost: From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia In economics and finance, marginal cost is the change in total cost that arises when the quantity produced changes by one unit. That is, it is the cost of producing one more unit of a good. Mathematically, the marginal cost (MC) function is expressed as the first derivative of the total cost (TC) function with respect to quantity (Q). Note that there are two definitions: Practical Definition: marginal cost is the change in total cost that arises when the quantity produced changes by one unit Formal definition used in calculus: marginal cost (MC) function is expressed as the first derivative of the total cost (TC) function with respect to quantity (q).
    [Show full text]