Export-Oriented Industrialisation and Dependent Development: the Experience of Singapore

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Export-Oriented Industrialisation and Dependent Development: the Experience of Singapore Export-Oriented Industrialisation and Dependent Development: the Experience of Singapore Cheah Hock Beng Introduction metropolitan multinational companies (MNCs) whIch Development which relies in varying degrees upon the have generally established processing and assembly export of manufactured goods is not a new phenomenon. plants, utilising cheap local labour for largely unskilled It was in many ways significant in the early development and labour-intensive parts of the production process. experiences of a number of the advanced industrial Such production is generally based upon the import of countries. Indeed, stressing the role of exports and the most or all of the key manufacturing inputs (with high importance of the foreign trade multiplier, Kaldor value added operations and R and D activities confined ¡1977! has argued that the growth of all rapidly to the metropoles), in operations which are externally industrialising countries has been export-led. vertically integrated. The general consequence is that minimal benefit (in terms of local linkages, local The most recent school to advocate export-oriented learning and local control of the production process) industrialisation (EOI) as the appropriate strategy for accrues to the developing country involved, while the developing countries has sought its justification maximum advantage accrues to the MNCs (in terms of not so much in the historical experience of the earlier control over production, pricing, profits and general industrialisers as in the reputed failures of import- economic leverage over the local labour force and the substituting industrialisation (ISI). In general, this local state) ¡ see Sutcliffe 1971, pp 270-80; Helleiner school has a theoretical and policy perspective associated 1973; Trajtenberg 1976; AMPO 1977; Nayyar 1978; with the orthodox growth .and-modernisation approach and Fröbel, Heinrichs and Kreye 19801. to development, and it sees EOI as the strategy through which a Rostow-type development process could be This paper seeks to draw out the implications of the initiated and sustained in the developing countries, experience of the EOI strategy in Singapore for these where ¡SI failed see Keesing 1967; Little, Scitovsky opposing views and in particular, to assess the extent and Scott 1970; Balassa 1971; Myint 1972; Johnson to which it challenges the dependency approach. 1973; ¡LO 1974; and Little 1979!. The proponents of the EOI strategy argue that it Development Strategy: the Context and the would promote a form of industrialisation which would Policies Adopted be more efficient and internationally competitive, and Development efforts in Singapore should be viewed in more in tune with the employment needs of developing the context of a relatively new and very vulnerable countries, because it would be concerned with political entity, attempting to establish a place for developing production in lines in which these countries itself in an unstable and changing world a small have an obvious comparative advantage, namely, labour- island city-state which has sought to overcome the intensive manufactures. Starting on these lower rungs immense domestic and external pressures impinging of manufacturing, these countries could, over time, upon it through undertaking the most rapid form of progress towards more sophisticated manufacturing development open to it. With a population of only activities. All this would go along with the opening up about two million, a land area of only 616 sq km, of the economy, greater reliance on the free-market resulting in high population density and strong pressures price mechanism, the elimination of impediments on on employment opportunities, it has traditionally been trade, investments and other financial flows, and dependent on trading and other service activities and generally increased integration with the international on imports of energy resources, raw materials and economy. food for its population and production activities. Despite the rapid growth of industry, the tertiary sector as a However, the critics of this strategy allege it has high whole continues to be the dominant economic sector. economic and social costs, such as the increasing dependence of the economies concerned and the Following the break from Malaysia in 1965 the city- growing exploitation of their labour-forces, and argue state was left with only its small domestic market. The against both the desirability and the likelihood of the economic strategy (up to this point largely ¡SI) was long-term success of the strategy. The main force of consequently modified to emphasise export-oriented their arguments is that the EOI strategy has served to industries that would cater for the general world promote an influx of foreign investment, mostly by market. The MNC then seemed to be an ideal ally in Bulletin, 1980, vol 12 no 1, Institute of Development Studies, Sussex 35 this regard, because it had the technical expertise competition between major US European and Japanese which could help to raise local skills,its labour- firms, and increasing US direct foreign investment. intensive operations would create substantial employ- These investments were directed largely towards Europe, ment, and it had established access to foreign markets. to take advantage of the relatively more rapid growth Moreover, the entrenchment of foreign capital, expertise rates, lower wages and higher productivity, to expand and other supporting institutions in the country would the total world market share of US firms and also to ensure external interest in the survival and continued hedge against decline in the value of the US dollar. growth of the city-state. Consequently, the main thrust However, many subsidiaries were also established in a of the economic strategy was to integrate the domestic number of developing countries, to benefit from the economy more closely with the international economy, cheaper cost of labour, employed in processing and with the associated aim of maximising the rate of assembly activities vertically integrated into the broader economic growth. international operations of US MNCs, so as to acquire a competitive edge over European and Japanese The policies associated with this strategy involved firms. offering fiscal incentives, providing an extensive and modern infra-structure, redefinition of the contractual The response of European and Japanese firms to this relationship between employers and employees, challenge from US companies has been varied, but it imposition of restraints upon the local labour movement, also includes more direct foreign investment on their the import of foreign labour, and a general policy of part and the transfer of certain production activities to wage restraint. There was an acceptance of the fact a number of developing countriesnot so much to that foreign investors are primarily profit-seeking. expand market shares in those areas themselves (as The concessions provided were justified by reference previously) but rather to follow US MNCs into externally to the employment opportunities and the access to vertically integrated production processes capitalising developed country markets provided, in particular by upon cheaper labour sources. These, then, were the the MNCs. conditions under which the introduction and rapid growth of export-oriented manufacturing occurred in Less attention and support was provided to the generally Singapore and, with some variations, in a number of smaller local firms and industries, because they were other Asian countries. mainly engaged in processing and repairing activities not oriented towards export. Insofar as these local industries harboured a significant proportion of the Structural Change In Manufacturing and labour force while the new industries encountered Associated Developments increasing labour shortages, justifications were found In 1965, direct exports of manufactures from Singapore to eliminate, directly or indirectly, many of the local constituted only 32 per cent of total sales value in the establishments and to rationalise the rest to be more in manufacturing sector. If the criterion for an export- tune with the overall industrialisation strategy. oriented industry is taken as direct exports accounting for 50 per cent or more of total sales, only four An important aspect of the problem was that the city- industry groups qualified as such. They were textiles state had not traditionally had as strong an involvement (including wearing apparel) and footwear (SSIC 23+24), in manufacturing as, for instance, Hong Kong. This leather products (SSIC 29), rubber products (SSIC posed serious difficulties for any indigenous efforts to 30), and electrical machinery (SSIC 37). Together, develop a significant and internationally competitive these four industry groups contributed only about 17 manufacturing sector in the short or. medium term. per cent of all direct manufactured exports. The Instead, it was thought that an open-door' policy greater part of direct manufactured exports was would be more successfuldespite its costs. And, contributed by other industries which were primarily based upon a realistic assessment of the difficulties catering for the local market. The relative insignificance involved in acquiring and developing sophisticated of the export industries at this time is further evidenced technology, an equally pragmatic approach was by the fact that they accounted for only about 14 per formulated for the longer-term development of domestic cent of all manufacturing establishments,
Recommended publications
  • Chapter 2 New Challenges to the Export Oriented Growth Model
    Chapter 2 New Challenges to the Export Oriented Growth Model Song Hong Institute of World Economics and Politics (IWEP), Chinese Academy of Social Sciences (CASS) December 2012 This chapter should be cited as Song, H. (2012), ‘New Challenges to the Export Oriented Growth Model’, in Zhang, Y., F. Kimura and S. Oum (eds.), Moving Toward a New Development Model for East Asia- The Role of Domestic Policy and Regional Cooperation . ERIA Research Project Report 2011-10, Jakarta: ERIA. pp.27-54. CHAPTER 2 New Challenges to the Export Oriented Growth Model SONG HONG Institute of World Economics and Politics (IWEP), Chinese Academy of Social Sciences (CASS) The export-oriented strategy played a crucial role for the successful development of East Asian economies after the World War II. They first exported low-technology manufactured goods, then gradually upgraded and transformed their export goods packages and finally caught up with the developed countries. Export oriented strategy in East Asia has been based on a series of internal and external conditions. Those conditions includes an open international environment, the existence of a certain size of external market, a stable supply of raw materials, as well as good and convenient navigation, and some internal conditions. Global financial crisis badly changed some of these conditions. For example, the external market was very unstable and was growing very slow; after the financial crisis, international raw material and energy prices experienced sharp volatility, which caused great challenges to the countries and enterprises seeking to implement an export oriented strategy. However, after the financial crisis the changes in international and domestic environments did not change the nature and trends of globalization, only temporarily slowed the pace of this process.
    [Show full text]
  • (Output) Import Tariff Reduction Increase Home Exports? Evidence from Korean Manufacturing Plant–Product Data
    ERIA-DP-2019-29 ERIA Discussion Paper Series No. 315 Does Home (Output) Import Tariff Reduction Increase Home Exports? Evidence from Korean Manufacturing Plant–Product Data Chin Hee HAHN Gachon University, Republic of Korea Ju Hyun PYUN§ Korea University Business School, Republic of Korea February 2020 Abstract: This study examines the effects of domestic output import tariff reduction on domestic plant export dynamics and clarifies the underlying mechanism, using rich plant–product data from the Republic of Korea for 1991–2002. We find that home import liberalisation increases domestic plants’ export market participation (extensive margins), particularly for industry where markup growth is more negative during tariff reductions. However, we do not find evidence that cutting import tariffs significantly affects incumbent home exporters’ export volume (intensive margins). This study unveils a new mechanism – ‘escape competition’ to foreign markets – by showing that reducing import tariffs leads domestic firms under heightened industry competition to look for an opportunity in foreign markets via export inauguration. Keywords: Plant-product level data; output tariff; Lerner symmetry; extensive margin; intensive margin; product scope JEL Classification: F15; F23 Corresponding author: Ju Hyun Pyun, Business School, Korea University, 145 Anam-Ro, Seongbuk- Gu, Seoul 02841, Republic of Korea, Tel: 82-2-3290-2610, E-mail: [email protected] § This research was conducted as part of the 2018 Microdata project of the Economic Research Institute for ASEAN and East Asia (ERIA). The authors are deeply indebted to the members of this project for their invaluable suggestions. The opinions expressed in this paper are the sole responsibility of the authors and do not reflect the views of ERIA.
    [Show full text]
  • What Is Really in the Economic Partnership Agreements for the Southern African Region? a Perspective from Botswana's Beef Expo
    Agrekon, Vol 47, No 4 (December 2008) Mbatha & Charalambides What is really in the economic partnership agreements for the Southern African region? A perspective from Botswana’s beef export markets CN Mbatha1 & N Charalambides2 Abstract The signing of the Economic Partnership Agreements (EPAs) between the European Union (EU) and the African Caribbean Pacific (ACP) nations dominated the multilateral trade agenda in late 2007 and early 2008. While the Caribbean nations signed the full EPAs, some of the African countries only singed interim agreements with the EU and a number of West African countries chose not to sign any EPA. Using the case of Botswana’s export markets, especially in agriculture, it is argued that the interim Southern African Development Community (SADC) EPA, which was signed by Botswana and her neighbours, with the exception of South Africa, may have been economically sensible in protecting Botswana’s rural poor, at least in the short run. By tracing trade flows from the border to specifically poor sectors of the country, the importance of the beef exports sector to the poor and rural communities was found. The potential effects on the most significant exports of tariff bands associated with preferential agreements with the EU were found to be most beneficial in comparison to the Most Favoured Nation (MFN) and the South Africa-EU Trade Development and Cooperation Agreement (TDCA) tariff bands. But it is also argued that the EPA will most likely have far reaching long run costs on regional economic development and institutional integration, within the SADC and Southern African Customs Union (SACU).
    [Show full text]
  • How Do Exports and Imports Affect the Use of Free Trade Agreements? Firm-Level Survey Evidence from Southeast Asia
    ERIA-DP-2016-01 ERIA Discussion Paper Series How Do Exports and Imports Affect the Use of Free Trade Agreements? Firm-level Survey Evidence from Southeast Asia Lili Yan ING* Economic Research Institute for ASEAN and East Asia (ERIA) and University of Indonesia Shujiro URATA ERIA and Waseda University Yoshifumi FUKUNAGA Economic Research Institute for ASEAN and East Asia (ERIA) January 2016 Abstract: Based on profit estimations, findings from a firm-level survey of 630 manufacturing firms across Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) countries conducted in 2013 showed that a 1 percent increase in the share of exports in total sales will increase the probability of use of free trade agreements (FTAs) by 0.2 percent, whereas a 1 percent increase in the share of imports in total inputs will reduce the probability of use of FTAs by 0.4 percent. Results from locally weighted scatterplot smoothing (LOESS) show that the use of FTAs is tilde-shaped and negative-shaped as a function of exports and imports, respectively. Keywords: Free Trade Agreement, ASEAN, Regional integration, FTA Utilisation JEL: F14, F15, F16, F23, F6 * The authors thank national teams for their work on leading surveys in Southeast Asia – MOFAT for Brunei Darussalam, CICP for Cambodia, LPEM–FEUI for Indonesia, NERI for Lao PDR, MIER Malaysia, YIE for Myanmar, PIDS for the Philippines, SIIA for Singapore, University of Chulalongkorn for Thailand, and CIEM for Viet Nam. The authors thank Ikumo Isono and Archanun Koophaiboon, and participants at the 14th East Asian Economic Association Conference for their comments on an earlier draft, and Robert Herdiyanto for his assistance in data cleaning at an early stage of the survey, and Rully Prassetya and Muhammad Rizqy for checking the use of GSP.
    [Show full text]
  • Trade Facilitation and the EU-ACP Economic Partnership Agreements
    Journal of Economic Integration 23(3), September 2008; 518-546 Trade Facilitation and the EU-ACP Economic Partnership Agreements Maria Persson Lund University Abstract This paper assesses the potential effects from trade facilitation in terms of increased trade flows both on average and specifically for the six regional groups of ACP countries negotiating Economic Partnership Agreements (EPAs) with the EU. Data from the World Bank’s Doing Business Database on the time required to export or import are used as indicators of cross-border transaction costs, and a gravity model on two-way bilateral trade between 22 EU countries and 100 developing countries is estimated using a sample selection approach. The results suggest that time delays on the part of the exporter and the importer generally significantly decrease trade flows, but also that this effect is not constant, in the sense that the elasticity of trade with respect to border delays declines at higher levels of time requirements. On average, lowering border delays in the exporting country by one day from the sample mean would yield an export-increasing effect of about 1 percent, while the same reduction in the importing country would increase imports by about 0.5 percent. Significant negative effects are also found of both export and import transaction costs for most EPA groups, and the effects tend to be at least as large as the average or larger. The results are generally robust for a number of alternative estimation methods such as Poisson estimation, IV estimation taking sample selection into account and the sample selection approach suggested by Helpman et al.
    [Show full text]
  • Research Paper 57 GLOBALIZATION, EXPORT-LED GROWTH and INEQUALITY: the EAST ASIAN STORY
    Research Paper 57 November 2014 GLOBALIZATION, EXPORT-LED GROWTH AND INEQUALITY: THE EAST ASIAN STORY Mah-Hui Lim RESEARCH PAPERS 57 GLOBALIZATION, EXPORT-LED GROWTH AND INEQUALITY: THE EAST ASIAN STORY Mah-Hui Lim* SOUTH CENTRE NOVEMBER 2014 * The author gratefully acknowledges valuable inputs and comments from the following persons: Yılmaz Akyüz, Jayati Ghosh, Michael Heng, Hoe-Ee Khor, Kang-Kook Lee, Soo-Aun Lee, Manuel Montes, Pasuk Phongpaichit, Raj Kumar, Rajamoorthy, Ikmal Said and most of all the able research assistance of Xuan Zhang. The usual disclaimer prevails. THE SOUTH CENTRE In August 1995 the South Centre was established as a permanent inter- governmental organization of developing countries. In pursuing its objectives of promoting South solidarity, South-South cooperation, and coordinated participation by developing countries in international forums, the South Centre has full intellectual independence. It prepares, publishes and distributes information, strategic analyses and recommendations on international economic, social and political matters of concern to the South. The South Centre enjoys support and cooperation from the governments of the countries of the South and is in regular working contact with the Non-Aligned Movement and the Group of 77 and China. The Centre’s studies and position papers are prepared by drawing on the technical and intellectual capacities existing within South governments and institutions and among individuals of the South. Through working group sessions and wide consultations, which involve experts from different parts of the South, and sometimes from the North, common problems of the South are studied and experience and knowledge are shared. NOTE Readers are encouraged to quote or reproduce the contents of this Research Paper for their own use, but are requested to grant due acknowledgement to the South Centre and to send a copy of the publication in which such quote or reproduction appears to the South Centre.
    [Show full text]
  • Industrialisation: Import Substitution to Export Promotion
    University of Wollongong Research Online Faculty of Business - Economics Working Papers Faculty of Business and Law January 2000 Industrialisation: Import Substitution to Export Promotion Kankesu Jayanthakumaran University of Wollongong, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://ro.uow.edu.au/commwkpapers Recommended Citation Jayanthakumaran, Kankesu, Industrialisation: Import Substitution to Export Promotion, Department of Economics, University of Wollongong, 2000. https://ro.uow.edu.au/commwkpapers/30 Research Online is the open access institutional repository for the University of Wollongong. For further information contact the UOW Library: [email protected] University of Wollongong Department of Economics Working Paper Series 2000 Industrialisation: Import Substitution to Export Promotion Kankesu Jayanthakumaran WP 00-09 INDUSTRIALISATION: IMPORT SUBSTITUTION TO EXPORT PROMOTION Kankesu Jayanthakumaran* ABSTRACT Import-substitution policy creates biases in the incentive structure and lowers the growth of potential exports in the long run. Trade reforms in this respect are likely to reduce the gap between domestic and border prices. The expectation is to bring better industrial performance on the lines of comparative advantages. This paper examines the import-substitution policy and the effect and impact of trade liberalisation. INTRODUCTION Neoclassical economic theory focuses on the market or exchange with the assumption that the price mechanism works well and allocates resources efficiently. A focus on the effectiveness of the market mechanism in allocating resources is a core theme of this approach. Promoting foreign trade to access the potential static and dynamic gains and removing the widespread inefficiencies in developing countries due to higher level of protection are some of the issues that the supporters of the market mechanism focus on.
    [Show full text]
  • Globalization, Export-Oriented Industrialization, Female Employment and Equity in East Asia
    United Nations Research Institute for Social Development (UNRISD) GLOBALIZATION, EXPORT-ORIENTED INDUSTRIALIZATION, FEMALE EMPLOYMENT AND EQUITY IN EAST ASIA Paper prepared for the UNRISD Project on Globalization, Export-Oriented Employment for Women and Social Policy ***DRAFT NOT FOR CITATION*** ***SUGGESTIONS AND CRITICAL FEEDBACK APPRECIATED*** Jomo K.S. University of Malaya, Malaysia E-mail: [email protected] October 2001 The United Nations Research Institute for Social Development (UNRISD) is an autonomous agency engaging in multidisciplinary research on the social dimensions of contemporary problems affecting development. Its work is guided by the conviction that, for effective development policies to be formulated, an understanding of the social and political context is crucial. The Institute attempts to provide governments, development agencies, grassroots organizations and scholars with a better understanding of how development policies and processes of economic, social and environmental change affect different social groups. Working through an extensive network of national research centres, UNRISD aims to promote original research and strengthen research capacity in developing countries. Current research programmes include: Civil Society and Social Movements; Democracy, Governance and Human Rights; Identities, Conflict and Cohesion; Social Policy and Development; and Technology, Business and Society. A list of the Institute’s free and priced publications can be obtained by contacting the Reference Centre. UNRISD, Palais des Nations 1211 Geneva 10, Switzerland Tel: (41 22) 9173020 Fax: (41 22) 9170650 E-mail: [email protected] Web: http://www.unrisd.org Copyright © United Nations Research Institute for Social Development. This is not a formal UNRISD publication. The responsibility for opinions expressed in signed studies rests solely with their author(s), and availability on the UNRISD Web site (http://www.unrisd.org) does not constitute an endorsement by UNRISD of the opinions expressed in them.
    [Show full text]
  • Why Has Globalisation Brought Such Large
    by Stephen Redding and Anthony Venables Why has globalisation brought such large increases in exports to some countries and not to others? Stephen Redding and Anthony Venables look at the way internal geography and domestic institutions seem to be a large part of the answer. Yawning gaps here have been wide variations in countries’ which we call its “foreign market access”. The other is export performance over the last quarter century. linked to changes within the country, which we call its South-East Asian countries have seen their real “supply capacity”. We find that a substantial part of the exports increase by more than 800% since the differential export growth of various countries and regions early 1970s, while those of sub-Saharan Africa since 1970 can be attributed to variations in the rate at Thave increased by just 70%. which their foreign market access has grown. This has raised concerns that, while some countries are Changes in one country’s foreign market access arise from benefiting from globalisation, others are at best passed by. changes in aggregate import demand from other countries We have investigated some of the determinants of these – particularly those that are geographically close. There may divergent export performances, looking in particular at the also be particular effects arising, for example, from regional roles of external and internal geography. integration agreements. We, therefore, refined our model to allow the ease of trading within regions to differ from that Geography might be expected to affect export performance between regions. Such intra-regional effects are positive for in several ways.
    [Show full text]
  • Redalyc.The Rise and Fall of Export-Led Growth
    Investigación Económica ISSN: 0185-1667 [email protected] Facultad de Economía México Palley, Thomas I. The Rise and Fall of Export-led Growth Investigación Económica, vol. LXXI, núm. 280, abril-junio, 2012, pp. 141-161 Facultad de Economía Distrito Federal, México Available in: http://www.redalyc.org/articulo.oa?id=60123314007 How to cite Complete issue Scientific Information System More information about this article Network of Scientific Journals from Latin America, the Caribbean, Spain and Portugal Journal's homepage in redalyc.org Non-profit academic project, developed under the open access initiative investigación económica, vol. LXXI, 280, abril-junio de 2012, pp. 141-161 The Rise and Fall of Export-led Growth T����� I. P�����* I����������� For the past thirty years development policy has been dominated by the paradigm of export-led growth. That paradigm is part of a consensus among economists about the benefits of economic openness which has been used to promote and justify globalization. The Great Recession has surfaced contradictions that were always inherent in export-led growth and globalization and the global economy now confronts a troubling outlook of significant demand shortage. In developed economies the shortage is explicit in high rates of unemployment and large output gaps. In emerging market (EM) economies it is implicit in their reliance on export markets. Received November 2011; accepted March 2012. * New America Foundation, <[email protected]>. This paper was presented at a conference on the Mexican Economy organized by the Economics Department of the University of Puebla, Puebla, Mexico, November 17-19, 2010 and at a conference on Brazil-China-United States.
    [Show full text]
  • Globalization and Distribution of Exports
    CESIS Electronic Working Paper Series Paper No. 93 GLOBALIZATION AND DISTRIBUTION OF EXPORTS Börje Johansson and Desirée Nilsson (JIBS and CESIS) August 2007 Globalisation and Distribution of Exports Börje Johansson* and Désirée Nilsson** Abstract During the 1980s many economists started to use the term globalisation as a catchword for an increased interaction between countries in world trade. The literature does not provide a clear definition of globalisation. We set up a number of criteria and formulate hypotheses about globalisation that we explore for Swedish export flows during the years 1965-2000. Globalisation, in this study, is referred to as increases in country diversity, extended transport radii, less effect of distance on trade flows, and the ratio of exports to the importing countries’ incomes. The results from the empirical analysis do not support the hypotheses of increasing trade globalisation It is rather the case that export flows are becoming more internationally regionalised. Keywords: Globalisation, Country Diversity, Transaction Distance, Proportional Distribution JEL classification: F01, F10 _____________________ * Affiliation: Jönköping International Business School, Jönköping University, P.O. Box 1026, SE-55111 Jönköping, E-mail: [email protected] ** Affiliation: Jönköping International Business School, Jönköping University, P.O. Box 1026, SE-55111 Jönköping, E-mail: [email protected] 2 1 Introduction What is economic globalisation? The literature does not offer a clear definition of the concept. However, in this connection one often refers to integration, openness and the mobility of production factors. The extent of openness (export and import as a ratio to GDP) is continuously increasing since many countries in the world are opening up to international trade.
    [Show full text]
  • A Note on Free Trade Agreements and Their Costs*
    A NOTE ON FREE TRADE AGREEMENTS AND THEIR COSTS* Dr. V.K. Saraswat1, Prachi Priya2 and Aniruddha Ghosh3 * Disclaimer: Opinions and recommendations in this article are exclusively of the authors and not of any other individual or institution. 1 Dr. V.K. Saraswat is the former DRDO Chief & Secretary Defence R&D, recipient of Padma Shri & Padma Bhushan and is currently Member, NITI Aayog 2 Ms. Prachi Priya is a Mumbai based economist 3 Mr. Aniruddha Ghosh works in the Office of Dr. VK. Saraswat Introduction Trade theory has consistently been a strong proponent of free trade of goods, services, capital and labour. However, a growing wave of protectionism and trade wars have dominated global trade recently. To underscore the prevailing sentiments regarding protectionism, it is instructive to look at what a free-trade champion and Nobel Laureate Paul Krugman had to say on the issue of seamless trade: “It’s also true that much of the elite defense of globalization is basically dishonest: false claims of inevitability, scare tactics (protectionism causes depressions!), vastly exaggerated claims for the benefits of trade liberalization and the costs of protection, hand-waving away the large distributional effects that are what standard models actually predict.” New York Times, 9th March, 2016 While it is difficult to assess whether the trade war will lead to a significant shift in the global trade paradigm, in the current scenario India should carefully review existing Free Trade Agreements (FTAs) before negotiating new ones. Evidences from recent FTAs suggest unfavorable gains to our trade partners. Worsening of our trade balances with our FTA partner countries merits attention.
    [Show full text]