Power Or Economic Law? Fresh Reflections on ECB Policy

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Power Or Economic Law? Fresh Reflections on ECB Policy A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Holtfrerich, Carl-Ludwig Article Power or Economic Law? Fresh Reflections on ECB Policy Intereconomics Suggested Citation: Holtfrerich, Carl-Ludwig (2018) : Power or Economic Law? Fresh Reflections on ECB Policy, Intereconomics, ISSN 1613-964X, Springer, Heidelberg, Vol. 53, Iss. 3, pp. 164-169, http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10272-018-0742-7 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/213171 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Monetary Policy DOI: 10.1007/s10272-018-0742-7 Carl-Ludwig Holtfrerich* Power or Economic Law? Fresh Refl ections on ECB Policy Conventional wisdom says that central banks determine interest rate levels. After all, monetary policy set by central banks directly infl uences money market conditions. But these conditions are also shaped by other actors such as government, manufacturing businesses, commercial banks and non-bank fi nancial institutions, as well as by monetary developments abroad. In this paper, it is argued that market forces, such as a global saving glut, play a more important role in setting interest rates than central banks. Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk’s classic 1914 article Macht oder especially in Germany. The German public, journalists ökonomisches Gesetz? presented a treatise which, using and mainstream economists in academia, think tanks and the wage level as an example, can be summarised as fol- the fi nancial sector have attacked ECB President Mario lows: The range of power of private associations such as Draghi for executing these policies. They argue that they trade unions and, one might add, public institutions like will erode private savings and old-age provisions and will central banks is quite considerable in the short run;1 in the lead to bubbles in the equity and real estate markets, to long run, however, it strongly shrinks “in favour of what is misdirected investments, to liquidity or solvency prob- subjected to economic laws or rather economic logic.”2 The lems in the fi nancial sector and to even looser fi scal poli- question today is whether it is the European Central Bank’s cies in those eurozone countries that already violate the power or rather market forces that determine the level of Maastricht criteria. Schnabl goes so far as to argue that interest rates, which since the 1990s have been falling and Draghi’s monetary policy is undermining the economic are nowadays very low. The conventional wisdom is that order of Germany, as devised by Walter Eucken.3 central banks alone control interest rates. I will present evi- dence that market forces play a more important role. It is well known that the German Bundesbank is opposed to Draghi’s monetary policy programme. Current Bundes- The ECB’s current monetary policy of setting low and even bank President Jens Weidmann and his predecessor Axel negative interest rates, along with its open-market policy Weber have been outvoted in the ECB Governing Coun- of quantitative easing (QE), have met with strong criticism, cil many times, as has the German member of the ECB Executive Board, Jürgen Stark. Indeed, both Weber and * This is a slightly revised version of the paper that I presented in the Stark resigned in protest in 2011.4 session on “The Future of the Eurozone” at the Annual Conference of the Institute for New Economic Thinking (INET) in Edinburgh, Scot- land, 21-23 October 2017. Even leading government members, such as former 1 E. von Böhm-Bawerk: Macht oder ökonomisches Gesetz?, in: fi nance minister Wolfgang Schäuble, have labelled Zeitschrift für Volkswirtschaft, Sozialpolitik und Verwaltung, Vol. 23, Draghi’s monetary policy as dangerous and have pushed 1914, pp. 205-271. For an early detailed review of Böhm-Bawerk’s ar- 5 ticle, see J. Bonar: Macht Oder Ökonomisches Gesetz? by Eugen v. for a tighter policy since at least spring of 2016. This is Böhm-Bawerk, in: The Economic Journal, Vol. 30, No. 118, 1920, pp. 214-219. Incidentally, Böhm-Bawerk is one of the fathers of mod- ern theories of capital and capital markets. 3 G. Schnabl: Folgen der Geldpolitik. Die EZB unterhöhlt die Grund- 2 My translation of E. Heuss: Macht oder ökonomisches Gesetz, in: pfeiler unserer Wirtschaftsordnung, FOCUS-MONEY online, 4 Sep- Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft / Journal of Institution- tember 2017, available at http://www.focus.de/fi nanzen/experten/ al and Theoretical Economics, Vol. 128, No. 2, 1972, pp. 185-195, here folgen-der-geldpolitik-die-ezb-unterhoehlt-die-grundpfeiler-unserer- p. 185. Heuss devotes his article to defi ning what power in Böhm- wirtschaftsordnung_id_7382123.html. Bawerk’s use of the word means in economic, political and social re- 4 P. Müller, C. Pauly, C. Reiermann: ECB Chief Economist Quits. lations. Jürgen Stark’s Resignation Is Setback for Merkel, Spiegel Online, 12 September 2011, available at http://www.spiegel.de/international/ europe/ecb-chief-economist-quits-juergen-stark-s-resignation-is- setback-for-merkel-a-785668.html. Carl-Ludwig Holtfrerich, Freie Universität Berlin, 5 H. Göbel: Schäuble will höhere Zinsen, Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung, 11 April 2014, available at http://www.faz.net/aktuell/ Germany. wirtschaft/wolfgang-schaeuble-kirtisiert-mario-draghis-ezb-geld- politik-14171118.html. Intereconomics 2018 | 3 164 Monetary Policy somewhat ironic, as it was the German government that lic opinion – governments, Germany has long maintained successfully insisted on the ECB’s independence from very high savings and very low net investment ratios. As government infl uence. a result, the country has been running current account surpluses since 2002, surpluses which began to rap- Millions of Germans live in fear of the consequences of idly increase in 2004, reaching a record 8.5% of GDP in Draghi’s monetary policy, while Draghi has spoken of the 2015. This has since tapered off slightly, falling to a still “perverse angst” among Germans regarding his policy high 8.1% in 2017. These surpluses are a strong impedi- decisions.6 The often stoked fear of infl ation, even hyper- ment to economic recovery processes in euro area defi - infl ation, as a consequence of the ECB’s fl ood of liquid- cit countries, and they are a threat to balanced economic ity into money and capital markets has not at all been development within the eurozone. Germany’s high current substantiated by price developments. Increases in the account surpluses constitute an incentive in defi cit coun- cost-of-living index have remained well below the price- tries to cut currency ties with the most competitive euro- stability target of under – but close to – two per cent p.a. zone member state and return to a national currency. The same is more or less true for Japan and the US. The expansion of the balance sheets of their respective cen- There is a strong belief in Germany, as well as in other eu- tral banks has been even more pronounced than that of rozone countries, in the UK and in the US, that the level of the ECB. interest rates is determined solely by the decisions made by central banks, as if the ECB or any other central bank The other side of the coin – cheap credit for investment could wield absolute power over the conditions in money purposes or real-estate fi nance – is not discussed, and and capital markets. Markus C. Kerber, a practicing at- certainly not complained about by those in Germany who torney at law and adjunct professor of public fi nance and make use of and benefi t from it. The fall of interest rates economic policy at the Technische Universität Berlin, ex- has redistributed income from creditors to debtors. Hy- plicitly called the ECB a “sovereign dictator” in his state- perinfl ation has the same effect, only much more quickly ment before the German Constitutional Court questioning and strongly. The common denominator is uncertainty, the constitutionality of the ECB corporate sector purchase presently with regards to future nominal interest rates and programme as an extension of the QE programme.9 in case of hyperinfl ation with regards to future real interest rates.7 It is textbook knowledge that the monetary policy set by central banks has direct infl uence on money market con- According to regular Eurobarometer polls carried out by ditions. But these conditions are also shaped by other ac- the European Commission, Germans are much more risk- tors within the domestic economy, such as government, and debt-averse than citizens of other EU member states private manufacturing businesses, non-bank fi nancial in- with a long tradition in international commerce and trade, stitutions and commercial banks, as well as by monetary namely Italy, Spain, Portugal, France, the Netherlands and developments abroad. Depending on its fi scal policy, a England.8 I consciously speak of England, not of the UK, government can, for example, demand short-term funds because Scotland, as part of the latter, is the proverbial from the money market in defi cit situations or add to the land of penny pinchers and savers, not of risk-takers and supply of these funds in surplus situations.
Recommended publications
  • Chapter 3 Corporate Saving and Investment: Recent Trends
    OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK 82 PRELIMINARY EDITION CHAPTER 3 CORPORATE SAVING AND INVESTMENT: RECENT TRENDS AND PROSPECTS Introduction and summary of the main results Since 2001, OECD For the aggregate OECD corporate sector, the excess of gross saving corporate net lending has over fixed investment (i.e. net lending) has been unusually large since risen sharply 2002, even allowing for the recent fall (Figure 3.1). Indeed, while attention has increasingly focussed on the emergence of global financial imbalances and a possible global “saving glut”,1 aggregate OECD corporate net lending rose slightly more over 2001-05 than the aggregate external surplus of the Figure 3.1. OECD corporate net lending1 As a percentage of GDP, in current dollars Corporate gross fixed capital formation (right scale) 3 Corporate gross saving (right scale) 14 2 2 Corporate net lending (left scale) 13 1 12 0 11 -1 10 -2 9 -3 8 -4 7 1991 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 2000 01 02 03 04 05 06 1. Aggregates include Australia, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Netherlands, United Kingdom and United States. For Japan and Denmark in 2006, estimates based on Economic Outlook 82 database. 2. Net lending is not equal to the difference between gross saving and gross fixed capital formation. It is also affected by changes in inventories and capital transfers. These can be important, as for Germany in 1995 and Japan in 1998. Source: OECD Annual National Accounts, national sources and OECD calculations. 1 . See Bernanke (2005). 1 OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK 82 PRELIMINARY EDITION emerging market economies (2% of OECD GDP against 1½ per cent of OECD GDP) (Figure 3.2).2 To the extent the household sector does not fully “pierce the corporate veil”, the rise in corporate saving that has driven the run-up in net lending will have contributed to low global interest rates.3 Figure 3.2.
    [Show full text]
  • Interest-Rate-Growth Differentials and Government Debt Dynamics
    From: OECD Journal: Economic Studies Access the journal at: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/19952856 Interest-rate-growth differentials and government debt dynamics David Turner, Francesca Spinelli Please cite this article as: Turner, David and Francesca Spinelli (2012), “Interest-rate-growth differentials and government debt dynamics”, OECD Journal: Economic Studies, Vol. 2012/1. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2012-5k912k0zkhf8 This document and any map included herein are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area. OECD Journal: Economic Studies Volume 2012 © OECD 2013 Interest-rate-growth differentials and government debt dynamics by David Turner and Francesca Spinelli* The differential between the interest rate paid to service government debt and the growth rate of the economy is a key concept in assessing fiscal sustainability. Among OECD economies, this differential was unusually low for much of the last decade compared with the 1980s and the first half of the 1990s. This article investigates the reasons behind this profile using panel estimation on selected OECD economies as means of providing some guidance as to its future development. The results suggest that the fall is partly explained by lower inflation volatility associated with the adoption of monetary policy regimes credibly targeting low inflation, which might be expected to continue. However, the low differential is also partly explained by factors which are likely to be reversed in the future, including very low policy rates, the “global savings glut” and the effect which the European Monetary Union had in reducing long-term interest differentials in the pre-crisis period.
    [Show full text]
  • Global Saving Glut Or Domestic Saving Drought?
    On the Source of U.S. Trade Deficits: Global Saving Glut or Domestic Saving Drought? Joseph B. Steinberg University of Toronto, Department of Economics, 150 St. George Street, Toronto, M5S 3G7, Canada Abstract Are U.S. trade deficits caused by high foreign saving—a global saving glut—or low domestic saving—a domestic saving drought? To answer this question, I conduct a wedge accounting analy- sis of U.S. trade balance dynamics during 1995–2011 using a dynamic general equilibrium model. I find that a global saving glut explains 96 percent of U.S. trade deficits in excess of those that would have occurred naturally as a result of productivity growth and demographic change. Con- trary to widespread belief, however, investment distortions, not a global saving glut, account for much of the decline in real interest rates that has accompanied U.S. trade deficits. Keywords: Trade deficit, global saving glut, wedge accounting, real exchange rate JEL: F21, F32, F41 1. Introduction The United States has run trade deficits for more than two decades. In a well-known speech, Bernanke(2005) argued that a high supply of saving in the rest of the world—a global saving glut—is responsible for U.S. trade deficits. More recently, however, Chinn and Ito(2007, 2008), Laibson and Mollerstrom(2010), and other researchers have argued that a low domestic supply of saving—a domestic saving drought—is the culprit. In this paper I use a dynamic general equi- librium model to quantify the contributions of domestic and foreign forces to U.S. trade balance dynamics between 1995–2011.
    [Show full text]
  • Farewell to Cheap Capital? the Implications of Long‑Term Shifts in Global Investment and Saving
    McKinsey Global Institute McKinsey Global Institute Farewell to cheapFarewell to capital? The implications long‑term of shifts in global investment and saving December 2010 Farewell to cheap capital? The implications of long‑term shifts in global investment and saving The McKinsey Global Institute The McKinsey Global Institute (MGI), established in 1990, is McKinsey & Company’s business and economics research arm. MGI’s mission is to help leaders in the commercial, public, and social sectors develop a deeper understanding of the evolution of the global economy and to provide a fact base that contributes to decision making on critical management and policy issues. MGI research combines two disciplines: economics and management. Economists often have limited access to the practical problems facing senior managers, while senior managers often lack the time and incentive to look beyond their own industry to the larger issues of the global economy. By integrating these perspectives, MGI is able to gain insights into the microeconomic underpinnings of the long‑term macroeconomic trends impacting business strategy and policy making. For nearly two decades, MGI has utilized this “micro‑to‑macro” approach in research covering more than 20 countries and 30 industry sectors. MGI’s current research agenda focuses on three broad areas: productivity, competitiveness, and growth; the evolution of global financial markets; and the economic impact of technology. Recent research has examined a program of reform to bolster growth in Europe; Africa’s economic potential; debt and deleveraging; the impact of multinational companies on the US economy; technology‑enabled business trends; urbanization in India and China; and the competitiveness of sectors and industrial policy.
    [Show full text]
  • 'Chimerica' and the Global Asset Market Boom
    International Finance 10:3, 2007: pp. 215–239 DOI: 10.1111/j.1468-2362.2007.00210.x ‘Chimerica’ and the Global Asset Market Boomà w Niall Ferguson and Moritz Schularickz w Harvard Business School and zFree University of Berlin. Abstract Over the past five years the world has witnessed a spectacular boom in asset prices. This paper reviews different explanations for this phenom- enon, and argues that future financial historians will point to the divergence between high returns on capital and the low cost of capital, not to excess liquidity or asset shortage, as the driving force in global asset markets. The integration of the massive Asian labour force into the world economy has significantly increased global returns on capital while the cost of capital as measured by long-term real interest rates has not increased, but has actually fallen. We label this two-sided phenomenon ‘Chimerica’ because it is in large measure consequence of the symbiotic economic relationship that has developed between the People’s Republic of China and the United States of America. Not only has plentiful Chinese and Asian labour increased global returns to capital; Chinese excess savings have also depressed US and global interest rates. We show that the Chinese ‘savings glut’ was not primarily a function of precautionary household behaviour, but of surging corporate profits in China due to increasing exchange rate undervaluation. ÃMany thanks to Thomas Steger (University of Leipzig) and Roland Beck (European Central Bank) for helpful comments. We gratefully acknowledge the support we received from various financial market participants: Helen Qiao, Jan Hatzius, Ed McKelvey and Dominic Wilson at Goldman Sachs; Stephen Jen, Charles St-Arnaud, and Manoj Pradhan at Morgan Stanley; Jonathan Anderson, Will Darwin, George Magnus, Terence Keeley, and Sheryl Shah at UBS as well as Ian Mukherjee (Amiya Capital).
    [Show full text]
  • Global Imbalances and the Global Saving Glut – a Panel Data Assessment
    2007-11 Reserve Bank of Australia RESEARCH DISCUSSION PAPER Global Imbalances and the Global Saving Glut – A Panel Data Assessment Anthony Legg, Nalini Prasad and Tim Robinson RDP 2007-11 Reserve Bank of Australia Economic Research Department GLOBAL IMBALANCES AND THE GLOBAL SAVING GLUT – A PANEL DATA ASSESSMENT Anthony Legg, Nalini Prasad and Tim Robinson Research Discussion Paper 2007-11 November 2007 Economic Research Department Reserve Bank of Australia We would like to thank Andrew Stone who contributed to the original ideas and early work for this paper. We would also like to thank Christopher Kent, David Orsmond, Adam Cagliarini, Malcolm Edey and David Vines for helpful comments, and Tim Callen and Mahnaz Hemmati at the International Monetary Fund for providing data. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Reserve Bank of Australia. Authors: prasadn or robinsont at domain rba.gov.au Economic Publications: [email protected] Abstract Since the late 1990s there have been substantial changes in the current account balances of a number of economies, most notably a marked widening in the current account deficit of the United States and increased net lending by many developing nations to developed economies. This paper uses panel data to examine what may have contributed to changes in the current account positions of a wide sample of developing and developed economies. In particular, we aim to assess the ‘global saving glut’ hypothesis that financial crises have contributed to the current account surpluses in developing economies. Overall, we find some support for this argument; there is a significant role for financial crises as well as institutional factors in determining current account balances.
    [Show full text]
  • Working Paper No. 597
    Working Paper No. 597 Bretton Woods 2 Is Dead, Long Live Bretton Woods 3? by Jörg Bibow Skidmore College and Levy Economics Institute May 2010 Address for correspondence: Skidmore College, Economics Department, 815 N. Broadway, Saratoga Springs, NY 12866. The author gratefully acknowledges comments on an earlier draft by Ann Davis, Charles Goodhart, Andrea Terzi, Gennaro Zezza, and session participants at the 4th Bi-Annual Cross-Border Post Keynesian Conference in Buffalo, NY, in October 2009, and the ASSA meetings in Atlanta, GA., in January 2010. The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute scholars and conference participants. The purpose of the series is to disseminate ideas to and elicit comments from academics and professionals. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, founded in 1986, is a nonprofit, nonpartisan, independently funded research organization devoted to public service. Through scholarship and economic research it generates viable, effective public policy responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in the United States and abroad. Levy Economics Institute P.O. Box 5000 Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000 http://www.levyinstitute.org Copyright © Levy Economics Institute 2010 All rights reserved ABSTRACT This paper sets out to investigate the forces and conditions that led to the emergence of global imbalances preceding the worldwide crisis of 2007–09, and both the likelihood and the potential sustainability of reemerging global imbalances as the world economy recovers from that crisis. The “Bretton Woods 2” hypothesis of sustainable global imbalances featuring a quasi-permanent U.S. current account deficit overlooked that the domestic counterpart to the United States’ external deficit—soaring household indebtedness—was based not on safe debts but rather toxic ones.
    [Show full text]
  • Is the U.S. Trade Deficit Caused by a Global Saving Glut?
    Order Code RL33140 CRS Report for Congress Received through the CRS Web Is the U.S. Trade Deficit Caused by a Global Saving Glut? November 4, 2005 Marc Labonte Specialist in Macroeconomics Government and Finance Division Congressional Research Service ˜ The Library of Congress Is the U.S. Trade Deficit Caused by a Global Saving Glut? Summary The U.S. trade deficit is equal to net foreign capital inflows. Because U.S. investment rates exceed U.S. saving rates, the gap must be financed by foreign borrowing. The trade deficit has grown over recent years to a record 5.8% of gross domestic product (GDP) in 2004. Economists have long argued that the low U.S. saving rate, which is much lower than most foreign countries, is the underlying cause of the trade deficit and that policies aimed at reducing the trade deficit should focus on boosting national saving. The most straightforward policy would be to reduce the budget deficit, which directly increases national saving. In an often-cited speech in early 2005, Ben Bernanke, recently nominated to be the chairman of the Federal Reserve, argued that the underlying cause of the trade deficit was not insufficient domestic saving, but rather a “global saving glut.” He argued that there was too much saving worldwide, not enough investment demand, and that the United States was the natural destination for this excess saving. In response to the global saving glut, the trade deficit increased, interest rates were kept low, demand for capital and residential investment rose, and the incentive to save decreased in the United States.
    [Show full text]
  • Tracing the Origins of the Financial Crisis
    OECD Journal: Financial Market Trends Volume 2014/2 © OECD 2015 Tracing the origins of the financial crisis by Paul Ramskogler* More than half a decade has passed since the most significant economic crisis of our lifetimes and a plethora of different interpretations has been offered about its origins. This paper consolidates the stylised facts put forward so far into a concise and coherent meta-narrative. The paper connects the dots between the arguments developed in the literature on macroeconomics and those laid out in the literature on financial economics. It focuses, in particular, on the interaction of monetary policy, international capital flows and the decisive impact of the rise of the shadow banking industry. JEL classification: A10, F30, G01 Keywords: Financial crisis, international capital flows, shadow banking * Paul Ramskogler is an economist at the Austrian central bank, OeNB. This article is based on a more thoroughly documented report (Ramskogler, 2014). It intends to make the major findings of the report more accessible without providing its fuller details and more rigid analysis. The report was prepared while the author was seconded to the OECD New Approaches to Economic Challenges (NAEC) project. Its findings were presented and discussed at a dedicated NAEC seminar at the OECD in Paris on 22 September 2014. Input and comments by OECD staff on an earlier version of the report and by participants of the seminar are gratefully acknowledged. The author is solely responsible for any remaining errors. This work is published on the responsibility of the Secretary-General of the OECD. The opinions expressed and arguments employed herein do not necessarily reflect the official views of OECD member countries.
    [Show full text]
  • Stanley Fischer
    Stanley Fischer: The low level of global real interest rates Speech by Mr Stanley Fischer, Vice Chair of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, at the Conference to Celebrate Arminio Fraga's 60 Years, Rio de Janeiro, 31 July 2017. * * * I am grateful to Joseph W. Gruber of the Federal Reserve Board for his assistance. Views expressed in this presentation are my own and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Board or the Federal Open Market Committee. I am very happy to be participating in this conference celebrating Arminio. My tenure at the International Monetary Fund overlapped with the first two and a half years of Arminio’s time as president of the Central Bank of Brazil, and in our capacities at the time, we had frequent opportunities to interact and converse. Of course, I watched with admiration the remarkable management of the economy by the Malan-Fraga team in the run-up to the election that brought Lula to power. In particular, Arminio and his Central Bank team’s management of the exchange rate—which at one point reached 3.95 reais per dollar—was masterly and put in place a sound foundation for that essential part of Brazil’s economic machinery in the years that followed. Subsequently, as I was on the brink of transitioning to the world of central banking early in 2005— that is, prior to taking up my position as governor of the Bank of Israel—Arminio was able to turn the tables and offered me some hard-edged advice on how to be a central banker.
    [Show full text]
  • A Forensic Analysis of Global Imbalances
    R obert M . La Follette School of Public Affairs University of Wisconsin–M adison Working Paper Series L a Follette School Working Paper N o. 2019-002 ht t p:/ / www.lafollett e.wisc.edu/ research-public-service/publications A Requiem for “Blame It on Beijing” Interpreting Rotating Global Current Account Surpluses Menzie D. Chinn Professor, L a Follette School of Public A ffairs and Department of Economics, University of Wisconsin–M adison; and N ational Bureau of Economic R esearch [email protected] Hiro Ito Portland State University March 2019 A Requiem for “Blame It on Beijing” Interpreting Rotating Global Current Account Surpluses Menzie D. Chinn* University of Wisconsin, Madison and NBER Hiro Ito** Portland State University March 28, 2019 Abstract Global current account imbalances have reappeared, although the extent and distribution of these imbalances are noticeably different from those experienced in the middle of the last decade. What does that recurrence mean for our understanding of the origin and nature of such imbalances? Will imbalances persist over time? Informed by empirical estimates of the determinants of current account imbalances encompassing the period after the global recession, we find that – as before – the observable manifestations of the factors driving the global saving glut have limited explanatory power for the time series variation in imbalances. Fiscal factors determine imbalances, and have accounted for a noticeable share of the recent variation in imbalances, including in the U.S. and Germany. For advanced economies, the financial component of the current account has been playing an increasing role to determine the movements of the account.
    [Show full text]
  • The Saving Glut of the Rich ∗
    The Saving Glut of the Rich ∗ Atif Mian Ludwig Straub Amir Sufi Princeton & NBER Harvard & NBER Chicago Booth & NBER February 2021 Abstract There has been a large rise in savings by Americans in the top 1% of the income or wealth distribu- tion over the past 40 years, which we call the saving glut of the rich. Instead of financing investment, this saving glut has been associated with dissaving by the non-rich and dissaving by the govern- ment. An unveiling of the financial sector reveals that rich households have accumulated substantial financial assets that are direct claims on U.S. government and household debt. State-level analysis shows that the rise in top income shares has been important in generating the rise in savings by the rich. ∗A previously circulated version of this study was entitled “The Saving Glut of the Rich and the Rise in Household Debt.” We thank Ian Sapollnik for extraordinary research assistance throughout this project. Pranav Garg, Sebastian Hanson, and Bianca He also provided excellent research assistance at various stages. We are grateful to the follow- ing scholars who patiently answered questions on various conceptual and data issues: Jesse Bricker, Joseph Briggs, Jonathan Fisher, Fatih Guvenen, Jonathan Heathcote, David Johnson, Ralph Koijen, Eric Nielsen, Fabrizio Perri, Lukasz Rachel, Kamila Sommer, Alice Volz, Owen Zidar, and Gabriel Zucman. We also thank Heather Boushey, Benjamin Hebert,´ Greg Kaplan, Gianni La Cava, Lukasz Rachel, Moritz Schularick, Richard Thaler, Harald Uhlig, Stijn van Nieuwerburgh, Rob Vishny, and seminar participants at the Bank of England, the Bank of International Set- tlements, UC Berkeley, Brown, Chicago Booth, Columbia, Dartmouth, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, the Federal Reserve Board of Governors, the IMF, the NBER Corporate Finance meeting, Princeton University, and the Reserve Bank of Australia.
    [Show full text]