Workingyforytheyeconomy

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Workingyforytheyeconomy Workingyforytheyeconomy The economic case for trade unions Looking at the relationship between two major economic trends since the 1970s – declining union membership and a shrinking share of wages and salaries in national income – it becomes clear that the UK has paid a heavy economic price for years of labour market deregulation and anti-union policies. yy Over the last four decades, the decline As shown in the graph, wage share in the UK of trade unions and weakened collective reached its peak in 1975 at 76.2% and had voice of the UK workforce have slowed the decreased by 8.9% in 2014, to 67.3%. motor of the economy - reducing national income by £27.2bn1. This can be explained Figure 1: Decline in the wage shareacross Europe in seven steps: 76 1. Ayloweryshareyofynationalyincomeyy hasybeenygoingytoywages 71 There has been a significant shift in the distribution of the national incomes of developed economies since the 1970s. National income is 66 the total amount produced by an economy in a single year, and is usually measured by Gross Domestic Product (GDP). 61 Regardless of their individual histories and institutions, European countries have seen a Wages as a share of national income (%) 56 pronounced decline in the share of national 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 income received by labour – the wage share – Key and an increase in the share going to capital in Denmark Sweden United Kingdom the form of profits for private business owners, France Germany EU15 shareholders and financial investors – the Source: AMECO. Retrieved from http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/ profit share. db_indicators/ameco/index_en.htm Note: ‘EU15’ shows an average of wage share decline in 15 European Union member states.2 2 Trade unions: working for the economy 2.yTheyreducedyabilityyofytheyworkforceytoy Figure 2: Fewer people in unions negotiateycollectivelyyonywageylevelsyisyay majorycauseyofythisydecline 90 Trade unions are the collective voice of the 80 UK labour force. They play a critical role in 70 determining what portion of national income goes to wages. This bargaining takes place 60 mostly at the level of individual workplaces, 50 where trade unions bring together the voices of employees to negotiate on wages and 40 conditions. Union density (%) 30 The aggregate effect of these individual 20 negotiations, only some of which are coordinated 10 across different workplaces in a sector, is a measurable impact on the share of national 0 income going to wages overall. 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Key Over the past three decades there has been a Denmark Sweden United Kingdom pronounced decline in membership of unions, in France Germany the level of industrial action and in the share of Source: OECD. Retrieved from https://stats.oecd.org/Index. the workforce covered by collective bargaining. aspx?DataSetCode=UN_DEN Note: Union density is calculated as union It is the decline in density – the percentage of membership as a proportion of wage and salary earners in employment. the workforce which is in a union – that gives the most accurate picture of the reduced powers of Figure 3: Decline in collective bargaining unions in many countries in Europe, but most 100 dramatically in the UK. 90 As shown in Figure 2, the UK has experienced one of the sharpest declines in union density in 80 Europe, behind only three countries – Portugal, 70 Ireland and Austria.3 60 Union density in the UK fell from a high of 49.9% in 1981 to a record low of 25.4% in 2013. This 50 decrease – union density has halved in 30 years 40 – significantly exceeds the rate of decline in Bargaining coverage (%) Germany (18.3%) and France (14.4%).4 30 While membership levels measure the potential 20 bargaining strength of unions, a fuller picture of 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 their effectiveness and reach can be seen by Key looking at bargaining coverage – the level of the Germany France United Kingdom national workforce which is covered by collective Denmark Sweden agreements on pay and conditions.5 Source: Visser, J. (2013), ICTWSS. Database on institutional characteristics of trade unions, wage setting, state intervention and social pacts. Retrieved As Figure 3 shows, following the decline in from http://www.uva-aias.net/208 membership, bargaining coverage in the UK has plummeted, from a peak of 80% in 1979 to 31.2% in 2011. Today, the vast majority of the British workforce has no say over their pay and conditions. 3 Trade unions: working for the economy 3.yWhyytheyreachyandyinfluenceyofyy yy Changes to incentive regimes have seen pay unionsyhasydeclined being increasingly linked to performance, reducing commonality among workers. Several factors have contributed to the falling When wages and terms of employment are rate of union membership and reach in the UK. negotiated collectively, this takes place at The government-led reforms of the 1980s and the level of individual workplaces rather than 1990s introduced onerous regulations for union across sectors or nationally. activities and new laws were created imposing limits on employee protections.6 4.yEconomicygrowthyhasyslowedybutytheyy shareyofynationalyincomeygoingytoytheyy The labour market and workplace have also profitsyofyfirmsyhasyrisen changed in ways that mean employees are now less able to speak collectively, weakening the The decline in the wage share and increase in labour force’s negotiating position on wages and the profit share has happened at the same time conditions, even when collective bargaining and as a weaker growth performance over the last union activities take place. three decades in the UK and other European countries, the US, Japan, and several major These changes include: developing countries.8 yy Deregulation of the labour market carried out In the UK the seemingly higher growth rates of between the 1970s and 1990s – including 2000–07 appear, with hindsight, as something of changes to unemployment insurance benefits, an illusion: in the absence of strong productivity- employment protection policies and payroll oriented wage increases, it was rising household taxes. This reduced the bargaining power of debt that fuelled consumption.9 This proved to the work force significantly by increasing the be a fragile growth model that collapsed in the threat of dismissal.7 Great Recession. Average annual growth in the 2000s (2000–13) in the UK, including the years yy Cuts to welfare, high unemployment levels, of the recession, is considerably lower at 1.7%. and austerity measures reduce the options available to employees, meaning that people Company profits are accounting for an are more likely to take on jobs with poor pay increasingly large slice of the UK economic pie, and conditions. but the pie itself is growing more slowly. Why? yy Many jobs, particularly those associated with This general drop in growth levels poses a the rise of the service industry, have become significant puzzle for proponents of economic increasingly characterised by multi-skilling, policies that are intended to ensure profitability, flexible and casual employment contracts, and such as labour market deregulation, but that self-employed work. Individuals in this growing have failed to restore economic activity to portion of the labour force find themselves previous levels. more isolated and the transient nature of their positions provides less opportunity to Mainstream economic policy in recent years has coordinate with colleagues. been based on the belief that if wages are kept low relative to company returns, investment by yy The growing prominence of globalised firms firms, encouraged by greater profits, will pick has transformed the negotiation process; up. In addition, if labour costs are falling, exports firms increasingly coordinate their activities will become more competitive, stimulating more in complex and dispersed ways involving overseas sales. outsourcing and relocation. 4 Trade unions: working for the economy But it is evident that enacting economic policies Employees have a higher propensity to spend on the basis of these assumptions – for example than those who own the companies which limiting wages, curtailing trade union activities pay their wages and, therefore, less spending and reducing collective bargaining coverage happens in the economy if the wage share – has not had the desired effect of boosting is squeezed.10 national income. If spending power is reduced, firms, facing 5.yWagesyplayyayvitalyroleyinytheyeconomyyandy smaller markets, will choose to hold back on ifytheyyareyrestricted,yspendingycanyslow investment and production. Growth overall is then likely to fall, unless the spending squeeze In the economic theory and related policies is outweighed by increased activity elsewhere outlined above, which focus on the supply side in the economy, such as through increasing of economic relations, wages are treated first and income from net exports. foremost as costs to a business. As such, wages must be moderated to ensure the share of Measuring the interplay of these factors over income going to company profits remains high. time determines whether the economy of any particular country is driven more by wages, But there is another side to this coin: the or by profits. demand side. As shown in figure 4, wages are not merely a cost detracting from company 6.yTheyUKyisywage-ledy–ywhatythisymeansyy profits, but the source of demand in the andywhyyitymatters economy through spending, and as such play an essential role in generating company revenues. Findings show that, alongside Germany, France They are the means by which consumers buy and Italy, the UK economy is in fact wage-led.11 products and therefore drive the economy. This means that it is wages, not profits, that drive growth in the economy. Figure 4: The circular flow of income in Contrary to assumptions that have led to a the economy policy-driven reduction in the wage share, growth in the UK is driven by healthy wages – more so ome (mon Inc ey) than by increasing company profits. Labour In fact, if profit share goes up, as has been the case for the past four decades, demand actually decreases.
Recommended publications
  • Testing the Bhaduri-Marglin Model with OECD Panel Data
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Hartwig, Jochen Working Paper Testing the Bhaduri-Marglin model with OECD panel data KOF Working Papers, No. 349 Provided in Cooperation with: KOF Swiss Economic Institute, ETH Zurich Suggested Citation: Hartwig, Jochen (2014) : Testing the Bhaduri-Marglin model with OECD panel data, KOF Working Papers, No. 349, ETH Zurich, KOF Swiss Economic Institute, Zurich, http://dx.doi.org/10.3929/ethz-a-010061748 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/102976 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences),
    [Show full text]
  • The Economic Case for Trade Unions
    Working for the economy: The economic case for trade unions Özlem Onaran University of Greenwich Alexander Guschanski University of Greenwich James Meadway New Economics Foundation Alice Martin New Economics Foundation No. PB05-2015 1 Working for the economy: The economic case for trade unions1 Looking at the relationship between two major economic trends since the 1970s – declining union membership and a shrinking share of wages and salaries in national income – it becomes clear that the UK has paid a heavy economic price for years of labour market deregulation and anti-union policies. Over the last four decades, the decline of trade unions and weakened collective voice of the UK workforce have slowed the motor of the economy - reducing national income by £27.2bn.i This can be explained in seven steps: A lower share of national income has been going to wages There has been a significant shift in the distribution of the national incomes of developed economies since the 1970s. National income is the total amount produced by an economy in a single year, and is usually measured by Gross Domestic Product (GDP). Regardless of their individual histories and institutions, European countries have seen a pronounced decline in the share of national income received by labour – the wage share – and an increase in the share going to capital in the form of profits for private business owners, shareholders and financial investors – the profit share. As shown in the graph, wage share in the UK reached its peak in 1975 at 76.2% and had decreased by 8.9% in 2014, to 67.3%.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Case for Trade Unions New Economics Foundation (NEF) Is an Independent Think-And-Do Tank That Inspires and Demonstrates Real Economic Wellbeing
    Working for the economy The economic case for trade unions New Economics Foundation (NEF) is an independent think-and-do tank that inspires and demonstrates real economic wellbeing. We aim to improve quality of life by promoting innovative solutions that challenge mainstream thinking on economic, environmental and social issues. We work in partnership and put people and the planet first. Contents Summary 2 Introduction 4 1 The value of collective voice in the workplace 7 2 Declining union density has slowed economic development 24 3 Implications for policy 34 Conclusion 43 Appendices 44 List of figures, tables and explanation boxes 48 Endnotes 49 2 DiversityThe economic and Integration case for collective voice in the workplace Summary The UK has paid a heavy economic price for three decades of anti-union policy and law. If the recovery from the recession is to be placed on a secure footing, the status of trade unions as an essential part of sound economic policymaking must be restored. The share of wages in national income has declined across the developed world over the last thirty years. At the same time, and despite political rhetoric, growth in wage rates is significantly down on the levels achieved in the post-war period. For the UK, the boost provided by extraordinary levels of household debt created in the 2000s, and the consumption it fuelled, collapsed spectacularly during the financial crisis of 2008. These two facts are associated. Although wages are treated purely as a cost for businesses in conventional economics, where reductions in wages imply greater profits, and therefore more growth, this is only part of the story.
    [Show full text]
  • Labour Share Developments Over the Past Two Decades: the Role of Public Policies
    Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development ECO/WKP(2019)10 Unclassified English - Or. English 14 February 2019 ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT LABOUR SHARE DEVELOPMENTS OVER THE PAST TWO DECADES: THE ROLE OF PUBLIC POLICIES ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT WORKING PAPERS No. 1541 By Mathilde Pak and Cyrille Schwellnus OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries. The opinions expressed and arguments employed are those of the author(s). Authorised for publication by Luiz de Mello, Director, Policy Studies Branch, Economics Department. All Economics Department Working Papers are available at www.oecd.org/eco/workingpapers. JT03443157 This document, as well as any data and map included herein, are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area. 2 │ ECO/WKP(2019)10 OECD Working Papers should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its member countries. The opinions expressed and arguments employed are those of the author(s). Working Papers describe preliminary results or research in progress by the author(s) and are published to stimulate discussion on a broad range of issues on which the OECD works. Comments on Working Papers are welcomed, and may be sent to OECD Economics Department, 2 rue André Pascal, 75775 Paris Cedex 16, France, or by e-mail to [email protected]. All Economics Department Working Papers are available at www.oecd.org/eco/workingpapers This document and any map included herein are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area.
    [Show full text]
  • Determinants of the Wage Share: a Cross-Country Comparison Using Sectoral Data
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Guschanski, Alexander; Onaran, Özlem Article Determinants of the Wage Share: A Cross-country Comparison Using Sectoral Data CESifo Forum Provided in Cooperation with: Ifo Institute – Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich Suggested Citation: Guschanski, Alexander; Onaran, Özlem (2018) : Determinants of the Wage Share: A Cross-country Comparison Using Sectoral Data, CESifo Forum, ISSN 2190-717X, ifo Institut - Leibniz-Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung an der Universität München, München, Vol. 19, Iss. 2, pp. 44-54 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/181209 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu FOCUS Alexander Guschanski and the EU and the United States.
    [Show full text]
  • Share of Labour Compensation and Aggregate Demand – Discussions Towards a Growth Strategy
    SHARE OF LABOUR COMPENSATION AND AGGREGATE DEMAND – DISCUSSIONS TOWARDS A GROWTH STRATEGY No. 203 September 2011 SHARE OF LABOUR COMPENSATION AND AGGREGATE DEMAND – DISCUSSIONS TOWARDS A GROWTH STRATEGY Javier Lindenboim, Damián Kennedy and Juan M. Graña No. 203 September 2011 Acknowledgement: We would like to thank Alfredo Calcagno, Agustín Arakaki, Pilar Piqué and Jimena Valdez for their comments to prior draft versions of this document and Ezequiel Monteforte for his assistance in data gathering. UNCTAD/OSG/DP/2011/3 ii The opinions expressed in this paper are those of the authors and are not to be taken as the official views of the UNCTAD Secretariat or its Member States. The designations and terminology employed are also those of the authors. UNCTAD Discussion Papers are read anonymously by at least one referee, whose comments are taken into account before publication. Comments on this paper are invited and may be addressed to the authors, c/o the Publications Assistant, Macroeconomic and Development Policies Branch (MDPB), Division on Globalization and Development Strategies (DGDS), United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD), Palais des Nations, CH-1211 Geneva 10, Switzerland (Telefax no: +41(0)22 917 0274/Telephone. no: +41(0)22 917 5896). Copies of Discussion Papers may also be obtained from this address. New Discussion Papers are available on the UNCTAD website at http://www.unctad.org. JEL classification: 011, 057, J24, J31 iii Contents Page Abstract ...................................................................................................................................................... 1 INTRODUCTION........................................................................................................................................ 1 I. THE SHARE OF LABOUR COMPENSATION IN INCOME FROM THE MIDDLE OF THE 20th CENTURY ............................................................................. 3 II. CAUSES OF THE EVOLUTION OF THE SHARE OF LABOUR COMPENSATION .............
    [Show full text]
  • Productivity Dispersion and Sectoral Labour Shares in Europe
    Working Paper No. 659 May 2020 Productivity dispersion and sectoral labour shares in Europe Martina Lawless*a,b and Luke Rehillc Abstract: The stability of the labour share of income is a fundamental feature of macroeconomic models, with broad implications for the shape of the production function, inequality, and macroeconomic dynamics. However, empirically, this share has been slowly declining in many countries for several decades, though its causes are subject of much debate. This paper analyses the drivers of labour share developments in Europe at a sectoral level. We begin with a simple shift-share analysis which demonstrates that the decline across countries has been primarily driven by changes within industries. We then use aggregated microdata from CompNet to analyse drivers of sector-level labour shares and to decompose their effects into shifts in the sector average or reallocation of resources between firms. Our main findings are that the advance of globalisation and the widening productivity gap between “the best and the rest” have negative implications for the labour share. We also find that most of the changes are due to reallocation within sectors providing support for the “superstar firms” hypothesis. The finding that globalisation has had a negative impact on the labour share is of relevance for policy in the context of the current backlash against globalisation and reinforces the need to ensure benefits of globalisation and productivity are passed on to workers. *Corresponding Author: [email protected] Acknowledgements: This research is part of the joint research programme of the ESRI, Department of Finance and Revenue Commissioners on the Macro-economy, Taxation and Banking.
    [Show full text]
  • Payroll Share, Real Wage and Labor Productivity Across US States Ivan Mendieta-Muñoz , Codrina Rada†, Ansel Schiavone‡
    Payroll Share, Real Wage and Labor Productivity across US States Ivan Mendieta-Muñoz*, Codrina Rada†, Ansel Schiavone‡ and Rudi von Arnim§ Working Paper No. 121 April 15th, 2020 ABSTRACT This paper analyzes regional contributions to the US payroll share from 1977 to 2017 and the four major business cycles throughout this period. We implement two empirical exercises. First, we decompose the US payroll share across states. Utilizing a Divisia index decomposition technique yields exact contributions of real wages, employment structure, labor productivity and relative prices across the states to the aggregate change in the payroll share. Key findings are that the decline in the aggregate (i) is driven by decoupling between real wage and labor productivity; and * Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, University of Utah †Corresponding author: [email protected]; Associate Professor, Department of Economics, University of Utah. ‡ PhD Candidate, Department of Economics, University of Utah § Associate Professor, Department of Economics, University of Utah The authors gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Institute for New Economic Thinking (INET). We thank Peter Skott, Thomas Michl and participants to the Eastern Economic Association Conference, Boston, 2020, for their comments and suggestions. (ii) is initially driven by the rust belt states, but subsequently dominated by relatively large states. Second, we employ mixture models on real wages and labor productivity across US states to discern whether distinct mechanisms appear to generate these distributions. Univariate models (iii) indicate the possibility that two distinct mechanisms generate state labor productivities, raising the question of whether regional dualism has taken hold. Lastly, we use bivariate mixture models to investigate whether such dualism and decoupling manifest in the joint distributions of payroll shares and labor productivity, too.
    [Show full text]
  • Capital Shares and Income Inequality: Evidence from the Long Run
    IZA DP No. 9581 Capital Shares and Income inequality: Evidence from the Long Run Erik Bengtsson Daniel Waldenström December 2015 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor Capital Shares and Income inequality: Evidence from the Long Run Erik Bengtsson Lund University Daniel Waldenström Uppsala University, CEPR, IZA and IFN Discussion Paper No. 9581 December 2015 IZA P.O. Box 7240 53072 Bonn Germany Phone: +49-228-3894-0 Fax: +49-228-3894-180 E-mail: [email protected] Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published in this series may include views on policy, but the institute itself takes no institutional policy positions. The IZA research network is committed to the IZA Guiding Principles of Research Integrity. The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Bonn is a local and virtual international research center and a place of communication between science, politics and business. IZA is an independent nonprofit organization supported by Deutsche Post Foundation. The center is associated with the University of Bonn and offers a stimulating research environment through its international network, workshops and conferences, data service, project support, research visits and doctoral program. IZA engages in (i) original and internationally competitive research in all fields of labor economics, (ii) development of policy concepts, and (iii) dissemination of research results and concepts to the interested public. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised version may be available directly from the author.
    [Show full text]
  • Recent Declines in Labor's Share in Us Income: a Preliminary Neoclassical Account
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES RECENT DECLINES IN LABOR'S SHARE IN US INCOME: A PRELIMINARY NEOCLASSICAL ACCOUNT Robert Z. Lawrence Working Paper 21296 http://www.nber.org/papers/w21296 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 June 2015 This paper received funding from the Peterson Institute for International Economics and the MasterCard Center for Inclusive Growth The views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2015 by Robert Z. Lawrence. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Recent Declines in Labor's Share in US Income: A Preliminary Neoclassical Account Robert Z. Lawrence NBER Working Paper No. 21296 June 2015 JEL No. D3,D33 ABSTRACT As shown in the 1930s by Hicks and Robinson the elasticity of substitution (σ) is a key parameter that captures whether capital and labor are gross complements or substitutes. Establishing the magnitude of σ is vital, not only for explaining changes in the distribution of income between factors but also for undertaking policy measures to influence it. Several papers have explained the recent decline in labor’s share in income by claiming that σ is greater than one and that there has been capital deepening.
    [Show full text]
  • The Labor Share of Income Around the World: Evidence from a Panel Dataset
    ADBI Working Paper Series THE LABOR SHARE OF INCOME AROUND THE WORLD: EVIDENCE FROM A PANEL DATASET Marta Guerriero No. 920 February 2019 Asian Development Bank Institute Marta Guerriero is a senior teaching fellow and deputy head of the School for Cross-Faculty Studies (Global Sustainable Development) at the University of Warwick, United Kingdom. The views expressed in this paper are the views of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of ADBI, ADB, its Board of Directors, or the governments they represent. ADBI does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this paper and accepts no responsibility for any consequences of their use. Terminology used may not necessarily be consistent with ADB official terms. Working papers are subject to formal revision and correction before they are finalized and considered published. The Working Paper series is a continuation of the formerly named Discussion Paper series; the numbering of the papers continued without interruption or change. ADBI’s working papers reflect initial ideas on a topic and are posted online for discussion. Some working papers may develop into other forms of publication. Suggested citation: Guerriero, M. 2019. The Labor Share of Income Around the World: Evidence from a Panel Dataset. ADBI Working Paper 920. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute. Available: https://www.adb.org/publications/labor-share-income-around-world-evidence-panel-dataset Please contact the authors for information about this paper. Email: [email protected] Asian Development Bank Institute Kasumigaseki Building, 8th Floor 3-2-5 Kasumigaseki, Chiyoda-ku Tokyo 100-6008, Japan Tel: +81-3-3593-5500 Fax: +81-3-3593-5571 URL: www.adbi.org E-mail: [email protected] © 2019 Asian Development Bank Institute ADBI Working Paper 920 M.
    [Show full text]
  • Unpacking the U.S. Labor Share
    Heintz. Labor Share. Weisskopf Conference. Unpacking the U.S. Labor Share James Heintz Political Economy Research Institute University of Massachusetts, Amherst Preliminary Draft September 2011 In his classic paper, 'Marxian Crisis Theory and the Rate of Profit in the Postwar U.S. Economy,' which appeared in the Cambridge Journal of Economics in 1979, Thomas Weisskopf presented a detailed empirical decomposition of the factors behind the declining rate of profit observed at that time ‐ specifically, from the mid 1960s to the mid 1970s. A decline in the rate of profit is central to Marxian crisis theory and to radical analysis of U.S. economic history, specifically the collapse of the 'Golden Age' of U.S. capitalism. Weisskopf found that the rising strength of labor, as captured by the distribution of income between capital and labor, was a critical determinant of the falling rate of profit in the U.S. However, Weisskopf also found that labor's strength at this time was 'defensive' as opposed to 'offensive', in that labor was able to preserve its income in the face of adverse terms of trade movements. Put another way, labor did not aggressively raise its real wage, but rather prevented a loss of income when price changes began to threaten the profitability of U.S. producers. In the spirit of Weisskopf's detailed analysis, this paper examines trends in the U.S. labor share in recent decades. In so doing, it extends the empirical analysis into the era of neoliberal dominance, deregulation, and concerted attacks on the bargaining strength of labor. However, it also takes seriously Weisskopf's insistence in his earlier paper that aggregate trends need to be unpacked to really get at the distributive dynamics behind macroeconomic variables such as the profit rate or labor's share of income.
    [Show full text]