Mortgage Convexity

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Mortgage Convexity Mortgage Convexity The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Hanson, Samuel Gregory. "Mortgage Convexity." Journal of Financial Economics (forthcoming). (Internet Appendix at http:// www.people.hbs.edu/shanson/MBS_IA_20140104.pdf) Citable link http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:12175237 Terms of Use This article was downloaded from Harvard University’s DASH repository, and is made available under the terms and conditions applicable to Open Access Policy Articles, as set forth at http:// nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:dash.current.terms-of- use#OAP Mortgage Convexity Samuel G. Hanson Harvard Business School [email protected] This draft: January 2014 First draft: July 2012 Abstract Most home mortgages in the United States are fixed-rate loans with an embedded pre- payment option. When long-term rates decline, the effective duration of mortgage-backed securities (MBS) falls due to heightened refinancing expectations. I show that these changes in MBS duration function as large-scale shocks to the quantity of interest rate risk that must be borne by professional bond investors. I develop a simple model in which the risk tolerance of bond investors is limited in the short run, so these fluctuations in MBS du- ration generate significant variation in bond risk premia. Specifically, bond risk premia are high when aggregate MBS duration is high. The model offers an explanation for why long-term rates may appear to be “excessively sensitive” to movements in short rates and explains how changes in MBS duration act as a positive-feedback mechanism that amplifies interest rate volatility. I find strong support for these predictions in the time series of US government bond returns. I thank seminar participants at the Boston University, Federal Reserve Board, the Copenhagen Business School FRIC’13Conference, as well as John Campbell, Anna Cieslak, Robin Greenwood, Arvind Krishnamurthy, Lasse Pedersen, Erik Stafford, Jeremy Stein, Larry Summers, Adi Sunderam, and Dimitri Vayanos for helpful comments. I am grateful to an anonymous referee for many helpful suggestions. I gratefully acknowledge funding from the Harvard Business School Division of Research. 1 Introduction A distinguishing feature of bond markets in the United States is the prominent role of fixed-rated home mortgages. Most fixed-rate mortgages issued in the US grant the borrower the right to prepay the loan at any time without penalty. When long-term interest rates decline, the option to prepay the mortgage and refinance at the current interest rate moves towards the money. Because lenders expect to be repaid sooner, the effective duration of outstanding mortgage- backed securities (MBS) falls– i.e., the sensitivity of MBS prices to changes in long-term yields declines. Conversely, as long-term interest rates rise, the prepayment option moves out of the money and the effective duration of MBS rises. To quote a Wall Street adage, this means that a mortgage-backed security “goes up like a 2 year bond”when rates fall and “goes down like a 6 year”when rates rise. More formally, the negative relationship between price and yield is convex for a noncallable bond. By contrast, the price-yield relation for callable bonds such as MBS is typically concave– a feature that bond investors call “negative convexity.” Aggregate mortgage refinancing activity varies significantly over time. Because refinancing entails large financial and nonfinancial costs, households typically follow a trigger rule, refinancing only when their option is suffi ciently far in the money. Thus, depending on the past path of mortgage rates, there are times when many households move from being far from refinancing to being close to refinancing and vice versa. I argue that the resulting changes in aggregate MBS duration act as massive supply shocks to the total quantity of interest rate risk that must be borne by investors in the broader bond market. Because these shifts in bond market duration are large relative to bond investors’risk tolerance, they have a significant impact on equilibrium term premium– i.e., on the expected return on long-term default-free bonds over short-term default- free bonds. In summary, time-variation in aggregate mortgage refinancing has a significant effect on the pricing of interest rate risk throughout the US fixed income market and, in particular, has a large impact on US Treasury yields. Why do shifts in expected household mortgage refinancing affect the aggregate amount of interest rate risk that bond market investors must bear? First, household borrowers only gradu- ally exercise their prepayment options following a decline in prevailing mortgage rates. Second, household borrowers do not alter their bond holdings to hedge their time-varying interest rate ex- posure. That is, households do not adjust their asset portfolios to offset the time-varying interest rate risk they are bearing on the liability side. The gradual response of mortgage prepayments to changes in mortgage rates and the lack of household hedging means that there are times when households are bearing more or less interest rate risk. Conversely, there are times when bond investors are bearing less or more risk. Thus, shifting refinancing expectations generate a form of aggregate market congestion: there are times when most households are effectively borrowing long term and other times when most are borrowing short term. If the risk-bearing capacity of professional bond investors is limited in the short run, then the term premium must adjust to induce investors to bear these risks. The sheer size of the MBS market within the US bond market plays a crucial role in this story. Bond markets have witnessed several MBS duration supply shocks that are larger than 1 the shift in duration induced by the Federal Reserve’sQuantitative Easing policies from 2008 to 2012. For instance, there have been several occasions when the quarterly change in MBS duration was equivalent to a $1 trillion increase (in 2012 dollars) in the supply of 10-year Treasury notes, with a corresponding reduction in the supply of short-term T-bills. By way of comparison, the quarterly new-issue supply of 10-year Treasury notes in 2012 was roughly $65 billion. Thus, past shifts in MBS duration have arguably been very large relative to the risk tolerance of bond market arbitrageurs. I develop a simple model of this mortgage convexity mechanism. The model has the following key ingredients. First, expectations of future household mortgage refinancing vary over time, which induces shifts in the effective duration of household mortgage borrowing. Second, aggregate bond risks are priced by risk-averse, specialized bond investors as in Vayanos and Vila (2009). This ensures that demand curves for aggregate bond risks slope downward, so the term premium must adjust to induce investors to absorb the aggregate supply of bond duration. Specifically, the model predicts that measures of aggregate bond market duration, which derive most of their power from variation in MBS duration, should positively predict bond excess returns. Furthermore, since shocks to MBS duration are fairly transient, one would expect fluctuations in MBS duration to lead to high frequency variation in bond risk premia. The model shows how negative MBS convexity may contribute to the excess sensitivity of long-term yields to movements in short rates (Gurkaynak, Sack, and Swanson (2005)) and, more generally, to the excess volatility of long-term yields (Shiller (1979)). Excess sensitivity reflects what might be called a “MBS duration spiral.” An initial shock to the short rate directly raises long yields due to the expectations hypothesis. The rise in long yields raises the duration of MBS. The term premium must rise in order to induce risk-averse bond investors to bear the larger aggregate quantity of interest rate risk. The resulting rise in yields further raises MBS duration, which further raises the term premium, and so on. Thus, the fact that MBS duration is increasing in long yields gives rise to a positive-feedback channel that generates excess sensitivity and excess volatility. The model also suggests that this positive-feedback mechanism is strongest when the mortgage market is on a “refinancing cliff”–i.e., when a small movement in long rates will significantly impact refinancing behavior and, hence, MBS duration. The model therefore predicts that excess sensitivity and volatility should be most pronounced when the MBS market is more negatively convex. I also show that an MBS duration shock should have a larger effect on the expected excess returns of long-term bonds than on those of intermediate-term bonds. This is a natural conse- quence of the fact that an MBS duration shock raises the current duration risk premium in bond markets. However, since these shocks are transient, shocks to MBS duration have a humped- shaped effect on the yield curve and the forward rate curve. The effects of a supply shock on yields– which equals the effect on the bond’s average returns over its lifetime– will be greater for intermediate term bonds than for long-term bonds when the supply shock is expected to be short-lived. That is, a shock to MBS duration increases the curvature of the yield curve. This suggests that transient shocks to MBS duration may account for some of the predictive power of the Cochrane and Piazzesi (2005) factor which picks up time-variation in the curvature of the 2 yield curve and is useful for forecasting transitory variation in bond returns. I find strong support for these predictions in US interest rate data between 1989 and 2011. Measures of MBS duration are strong predictors of excess government bond returns. And they appear to contain information that is not reflected in traditional forecasting variables based on the current shape of the yield curve.
Recommended publications
  • Introduction to the Measurement of Interest Rate Risk
    The following is a review of the Analysis of Fixed Income Investments principles designed to address the learning outcome statements set forth by CFA Institute®. This topic is also covered in: INTRODUCTION TO THE MEASUREMENT O F INTEREST RATE RISK Study Session 16 EXAM FOCUS This topic review is about the relation of yield changes and bond price changes, primarily based on the concepts of duration and convexity. There is really nothing in this study session that can be safely ignored; the calculation of duration, the use of duration, and the limitations of duration as a measure of bond price risk are all important. You should work to understand what convexity is and its relation to the interest rate risk of fixed- income securities. There are two important formulas: the formula for effective duration and the formula for estimating the price effect of a yield change based on both duration and convexity. Finally, you should get comfortable with how and why the convexity of a bond is affected by the presence of embedded options. LOS 67.a: Distinguish between the full valuation approach (the scenario analysis approach) and the duration/convexity approach for measuring interest rate risk, and explain the advantage of using the full valuation approach. The full valuation or scenario analysis approach to measuring interest rate risk is based on applying the valuation techniques we have learned for a given change in the yield curve (i.e., for a given interest rate scenario). For a single option-free bond, this could be simply, “if the YTM increases by 50 bp or 100 bp, what is the impact on the value of the bond?” More complicated scenarios can be used as well, such as the effect on the bond value of a steepening of the yield curve (long-term rates increase more than short-term rates).
    [Show full text]
  • VALUATION of CALLABLE BONDS: the SALOMON BROTHERS APPROACH Fernando Daniel Rubio Fernández
    VALUATION OF CALLABLE BONDS: THE SALOMON BROTHERS APPROACH Fernando Daniel Rubio Fernández VALUATION OF CALLABLE BONDS: THE SALOMON BROTHERS APPROACH FERNANDO RUBIO1 Director FERNCAPITAL S.A. and Invited Professor at the Graduated Business School Universidad de Valparaíso, Chile. Pasaje La Paz 1302, Viña del Mar, Chile. Phone (56) (32) 507507 EXTRACT This paper explain, analyze and apply in an example the original paper developed by Kopprasch, Boyce, Koenigsberg, Tatevossian, and Yampol (1987) from The Salomon Brothers Inc. Bond Portfolio Analysis Group. Please, be aware. This paper is for educational issues only. There is a Spanish version in EconWPA. JEL Classification: G10, G15, G21, G32. Keywords: Salomon Brothers, bond portfolio, duration and convexity, effective duration, valuation, callable and non callable bond. Originally developed January, 1999 Originally published October, 2004 This update July, 2005 1 This paper was made while I was assisting to the Doctoral Programme in Financial Economics, Universidad Autónoma de Madrid, Spain. Comments and suggestions will be appreciated. Please, send them by e-mail to [email protected] [email protected] 1 VALUATION OF CALLABLE BONDS: THE SALOMON BROTHERS APPROACH Fernando Daniel Rubio Fernández VALUATION OF CALLABLE BONDS: THE SALOMON BROTHERS APPROACH By Professor Dr. © Fernando Rubio 1 DURATION AND CONVEXITY FOR NORMAL (NO CALLABLE) BONDS Bonds are fixed income investments that have a fixed interest rate or coupon, payable on the principal amount. All fixed income investments are evidence of indebtedness which represent a loan or debt between the issuer and the owner or holder of the security. The value of any bond is the present value of its expected cash flows.
    [Show full text]
  • SESSION 7: VALUING a CONTRACTUAL CLAIM (BONDS) the Nature of Contractual Claims
    SESSION 7: VALUING A CONTRACTUAL CLAIM (BONDS) The nature of contractual claims ¨ A contractual claim cash flow is set at the time a contract or transaction is initiated, with the promisor committing to deliver that cash flow at the specified time. ¨ The cash flow that is contracted can be a constant cash flow or it can be tied to an observable and specific index or value. ¤ An example of the first would be a conventional fixed rate coupon bond ¤ An example of the second would be a floating rate bond. 2 The Effect of Default ¨ Even though a claim is contractually set, there is the possibility that the promisor may default. ¨ If the promisor has no default risk, the claim is said to be a risk free claim. ¤ The only entities that can conceivable by default free are governments that control the printing of currency. ¤ Not all governments are default free. ¨ If there is default risk, you have to adjust for the likelihood of default, when valuing the claim. 3 A fixed rate, risk free bond ¨ To value a fixed rate, risk free bond (issued by a government that is default free), you will discount the coupons (which are annuity) and the face value of the bond at the risk free rate. ¨ Thus, if you view the US government as default free, the value of 3% coupon rate, US treasury bond with ten years to maturity, if the US$ risk free rate today for a 10-year bond is 2% can be written as follows: Price of the Bond = 30* PV(A,10,2%) + 1000/1.0210 =$1089.83 ¨ This bond is trading at above par (with the face value of $1000 defined as par) because the market interest rate is lower than the coupon rate.
    [Show full text]
  • Bond Duration and Convexity
    Bond Duration and Convexity Gary Schurman, MBE, CFA October 15, 2009 Bond duration and convexity are measures of the sensitivity of bond price to interest rate (i.e. yield) changes. Bond price is a function of time (t) and discount rate (k). The equation for bond price at time zero is the discounted value of expected future cash flow. The bond price equation in mathematical terms is... T X −t P0 = [Ct × (1 + k) ] (1) t=1 Provided that estimated future cash flow does not change, bond price will change with the passage of time (t) and with changes in yield (k). Using a Taylor Series Approximation, the change in bond price, ∆P , over some small interval, ∆t, is given by the following partial differential equation (PDE)... δP δP 1 δ2P ∆P = ∆t + ∆k + (∆k)2 (2) δt δk 2 δk2 δP The first term in the PDE is δt ∆t, which is the first derivative of the price equation with respect to time (t). This partial derivative measures the change in price that occurs with the passage of time while holding yield (k) constant. We are not interested in holding yield constant. We want to hold time constant and measure the change in price due to an instantaneous change in yield. For our purposes we can ignore this deriviative. δP The second term in the PDE is δk ∆k, which is the first derivative of the price equation with respect to yield (k). This partial derivative measures the first order change in price that occurs when yield changes while holding time (t) constant.
    [Show full text]
  • Copyrighted Material
    CONTENTS Preface xv Acknowledgments xvii About the CFA Institute Series xix PART I Fixed Income Essentials CHAPTER 1 3 Fixed-Income Securities: Defi ning Elements 3 Learning Outcomes 3 1. Introduction 3 2. Overview of a Fixed-Income Security 4 2.1. Basic Features of a Bond 5 2.2. Yield Measures 10 3. Legal, Regulatory, and Tax Considerations 10 3.1. Bond Indenture 10 3.2. Legal and Regulatory Considerations 18 3.3. Tax Considerations 21 4. Structure of a Bond’s Cash Flows 23 4.1. Principal Repayment Structures 23 4.2. CouponCOPYRIGHTED Payment Structures MATERIAL 28 5. Bonds with Contingency Provisions 34 5.1. Callable Bonds 34 5.2. Putable Bonds 36 5.3. Convertible Bonds 37 6. Summary 40 Practice Problems 42 v ftoc v 24 August 2019 2:22 PM vi Contents CHAPTER 2 47 Fixed-Income Markets: Issuance, Trading, and Funding 47 Learning Outcomes 47 1. Introduction 47 2. Overview of Global Fixed-Income Markets 48 2.1. Classifi cation of Fixed-Income Markets 48 2.2. Fixed-Income Indexes 55 2.3. Investors in Fixed-Income Securities 56 3. Primary and Secondary Bond Markets 57 3.1. Primary Bond Markets 58 3.2. Secondary Bond Markets 62 4. Sovereign Bonds 65 4.1. Characteristics of Sovereign Bonds 65 4.2. Credit Quality of Sovereign Bonds 66 4.3. Types of Sovereign Bonds 66 5. Non-Sovereign Government, Quasi-Government, and Supranational Bonds 68 5.1. Non-Sovereign Bonds 68 5.2. Quasi-Government Bonds 69 5.3. Supranational Bonds 69 6. Corporate Debt 70 6.1.
    [Show full text]
  • Fixed Income Securities
    Suman Banerjee © 2017-18 Fixed Income Securities 629A: Fixed Income Securities Stevens Institute Business School Dr. Suman Banerjee January 18 - May 3, 2017 Venue & Time Group 1: Hoboken Campus, Wednesday, 3:00 p.m. to 5:45 p.m. Focus Fixed-income securities include bonds that promise a fixed income stream and by exten- sion all securities whose valuation and hedging are related to interest rates. Quantitative tools are especially important for understanding fixed-income securities: Their cash flows are contractually specified which makes it relatively easy to quantify the payoffs, yet the subtleties of interest rate movements and variations in credit risk ensure that quantitative analysis is useful. This course is focused on the concepts and tools that are useful to corporate man- agers as well as fund managers who want to use fixed income securities, whether for investing, hedging, market-making, or speculating. Some of the topics to be covered are term structure modeling, option-embedded bond analysis, pooling and tranching of cash flows, asset-liability management, hedging with interest rate derivatives, mortgage-backed securities (MBS), and collateralized debt obligations (CDOs). Broad Learning Objectives After successfully completing this course in fixed income asset valuation, the student should have improved competencies in the following areas of: • Creative and Critical Thinking { Critical look at the capital market and determine if what they are following the \best" practices. { Determine alternate methods of enhancing \investors' wealth" in fixed income markets. • Creation of Value { Keeping the primary objective (shareholders' wealth maximization) clear, how can the firm add value to other stakeholders like debtholders, suppliers and customers? 1 Suman Banerjee © 2017-18 Fixed Income Securities • Field Specific Knowledge and Experience { Look at the traditional methods of how firms determine the way they finance themselves and apply concepts learned from this course to make changes to the status quo.
    [Show full text]
  • Trading Bond Convexity - a Model Agnostic Approach
    Candidate no. 900228 Trading Bond Convexity - A Model Agnostic Approach A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the MSc in Mathematical Finance April 7, 2015 Candidate no. 900228 This thesis is dedicated to those multitude of Indian children who do not have the means to afford the luxury of education. 2 Candidate no. 900228 Acknowledgements I would like to express my sincere gratitude to my advisor Dr. Riccardo Rebonato for introducing me to this fascinating topic and for coaching me throughout. This thesis would not have been possible without his relentless patience in answering my many trivial questions and in explaining to me the key concepts. I have learned a lot, both from his classes at the Mathematical Institute and from our discussions over the phone and email. I have been extremely lucky to have interacted with Dr.Vladimir Putyatin throughout the course of this thesis. His insights, advice and review of my calculations have gone a long way in helping me to complete the analysis and write this thesis. The interactions with the faculty members at the Mathematical Institute have been extremely beneficial to my overall understanding of the nuances of Mathematical Finance and I would like to thank them for their quality teaching and feedback. My experience on each of the 7 visits to the Mathematical Institute has been very satisfying and it would not have been possible without the hard work that the staff of the Mathematical Institute put in prior to every visit. A big thank you to them. As we are all aware, life is much more easier to live when one has a supportive and caring family.
    [Show full text]
  • Bond Convexity: What Is It, and Why Should You Care? by Brian Haughey, CFA, FRM, CAIA
    © 2018 by the American Association of Individual Investors, 625 N. Michigan Ave., Chicago, IL 60611; 800-428-2244; www.aaii.com. Bond Convexity: What Is It, and Why Should You Care? By Brian Haughey, CFA, FRM, CAIA Article Highlights • As a bond yield decreases, its price rises at an increasing rate, whereas a bond’s price falls at a decreasing rate as its yield increases. This phenomenon is known as convexity. • The discount rates used to determine the future value of expected coupon rates when yields rise or fall differ and, as a result, have different price impacts. • A bond with more convexity will offer you more upside if rates decrease, while promising less downside if rates increase. increase to 11%, however, the bond’s The ideal sports team is price will decrease: one that is good at both offense and defense. P = ($50 ÷ 0.055) + [($1,000 – ($50 ÷ A football or soccer team, for 0.055)) × (1 + 0.055)–20] example, needs to be able to capitalize P = $940.25 on scoring opportunities when it has possession of the ball, but it is just as important that it fields a good defense in For bonds with a semiannual coupon, we divide the an- order to protect against attacks by the opposing team. We nual coupon payment by two to determine the semiannual can apply this analogy to investing in general, and to bonds payment. We also multiply the number of years by two to in particular. determine the number of coupon payments to be paid. In our example, the investor holding a 10-year bond paying 10% Bond Pricing ($100) annually would receive a $50 coupon payment every six months for 20 periods.
    [Show full text]
  • Option Adjusted Spread Model PRIME 3.0
    Option Adjusted Spread Model PRIME 3.0 Document: FCA 2276-1A (1) April 2004 Notices This edition This edition FCA 2276-1A (1) applies to application component PRIME 3.0 of FRONT CAPITAL SYSTEMS ARENA (hereafter referred to as FRONT ARENA) and to all subsequent releases of this component until otherwise indicated in new editions. Legal Information in this document is subject to change without notice and does not represent a commitment on the part of Front Capital Systems AB. © Copyright Front Capital Systems AB, 2003. All rights reserved. This material contains proprietary and copyrighted information, software and accompanying documentation belonging to Front Capital Systems AB that is protected by domestic laws and international conventions. Except as stated herein or in the Software License and Service Agreement, none of the information, software or accompanying documentation may be reproduced, distributed, displayed, posted or transmitted by any means, electronic or manual, for any purpose, without the express written permission of Front Capital Systems AB. FRONT CAPITAL SYSTEMS; FRONT CAPITAL SYSTEMS ARENA, FRONT ARENA, and all related logos are the registered trademarks of Front Capital Systems AB. Front Capital Systems AB recognises the registered trademarks of other suppliers mentioned in this document including Reuters and Sun Microsystems. UNIX is a registered trademark in the United States and other countries, licensed exclusively through X/Open Company Limited. Microsoft, Windows, Windows NT are registered trademarks of Microsoft Corporation. Other company, product, and service names may be trademarks or service marks of others. Supplementary legal notice Any information expressed in this document regarding standard practice or conventions in financial markets or in the administration or functioning of banks is included to provide context to information provided about our products and services and thereby clarify how these products and services function.
    [Show full text]
  • Valuation of Callable Convertible Bonds Using Binomial Trees Model with Default Risk, Convertible Hedging and Arbitrage, Duration and Convexity
    A University of Sussex PhD thesis Available online via Sussex Research Online: http://sro.sussex.ac.uk/ This thesis is protected by copyright which belongs to the author. This thesis cannot be reproduced or quoted extensively from without first obtaining permission in writing from the Author The content must not be changed in any way or sold commercially in any format or medium without the formal permission of the Author When referring to this work, full bibliographic details including the author, title, awarding institution and date of the thesis must be given Please visit Sussex Research Online for more information and further details Valuation of Callable Convertible Bonds Using Binomial Trees Model with Default Risk, Convertible Hedging and Arbitrage, Duration and Convexity. Fahad Aldossary Submitted for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy University of Sussex January 2018 II Declaration I hereby declare that this thesis has not been and will not be, submitted in whole or in part to another University for the award of any other degree. Signature: Fahad Aldossary III UNIVERSITY OF SUSSEX FAHAD ALDOSSARY, SUBMITTED FOR DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Valuation of Callable Convertible Bonds Using Binomial Trees Model with Default Risk, Convertible Hedging and Arbitrage, Duration and Convexity Abstract In this thesis, I develop a valuation model to price convertible bonds with call provision. Convertible bonds are hybrid instruments that possess both equity and debt characteristics. The purpose of this study is to build a pricing model for convertible and callable bonds and to compare the mathematical results of the model with real world market performance. I construct a two-factor valuation model, in which both the interest rate and the stock price are stochastic.
    [Show full text]
  • Decomposing Long Bond Returns: a Decentralized Modeling Approach∗
    Decomposing long bond returns: A decentralized modeling approach∗ Peter Carra, Liuren Wub aTandon School of Engineering, New York University, 12 MetroTech Center, Brooklyn, NY 11201, USA bBaruch College, Zicklin School of Business, One Bernard Baruch Way, New York, NY 10010, USA Abstract We develop a new, decentralized theory that determines the fair value of the yield to maturity on a bond or bond portfolio based purely on the near-term dynamics of its own yield, without the need to make assumptions on the instantaneous interest rate dynamics, nor the need to know whether and how the yield dynamics will change in the future. The new theory decomposes the yield into three components: near-term expectation, risk premium, and convexity effects. We propose to estimate the convexity effect with its recent time series and determine the expectation from either statistical models or economists forecasts, leaving the remaining component of the yield as a risk premium estimate. Empirical analysis on US and UK swap rates shows that this risk premium component can predict future bond excess returns. We also propose to perform comparative analysis of the yield curve via common factor structure assumptions on the rate of change across the yield curve. The extracted rate of change factor strongly predicts future changes in the swap curve slope. JEL Classification: C13; C51; G12; G13 Keywords: Yield decomposition; Expectation; Risk Premium; Near-term dynamics ∗Preliminary. We welcome comments, including references we have inadvertently missed. We thank seminar participants at Stevens Institute of Technology, and the 2016 JHU-QQR Conference on ”The Role of Derivatives in Asset Pricing” for their comments and suggestions.
    [Show full text]
  • THE BENEFITS of SYNTHETIC CONVERTIBLE BONDS By: Howard Needle, Portfolio Manager December 28, 2020
    20 William Street, Wellesley, MA 02481 781-416-4000 THE BENEFITS OF SYNTHETIC CONVERTIBLE BONDS By: Howard Needle, Portfolio Manager December 28, 2020 INTRODUCTION Convertible bond investors are often frustrated with limited investment choices or options regarding convertible securities especially related to sporadic or narrow convertible issuance, or that the universe of companies and sectors with outstanding convertibles is not larger or more diverse. 30+ years of experience has taught that there are frequently times an investor wants to purchase a convertible bond in a great company only to discover that no convertible exists. Or, a convertible exists, but it’s so busted there’s little equity sensitivity attached to the convertible; or conversely, it’s so far in the money that it is solely an equity surrogate and provides little potential downside protection (Graph 1)(1). In either case, it’s not a convertible bond in the balanced sense of the word and, therefore, does not afford a convertible bond’s hoped for benefits of potential upside participation with bond-like characteristics. Unfortunately, not every company issues a convertible security (in fact very few do), and often pricing is unappealing in terms of equity sensitivity or potential downside protection**. It’s almost as if convertible securities choose the investor as opposed to the investor choosing the investment. The possibility of some form of negative selection exists in this “take it or leave it” asset class. Graph 1 In the world of equities and to a lesser extent high yield, however, most investors find a stock, bond or sector they like and simply add exposure.
    [Show full text]