2 the Basic Solow Model

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

2 the Basic Solow Model Economic Growth Models: A Primer /Student's Guide, Miguel Lebre de Freitas 2 The basic Solow model “A thrifty society will, in the long run, be wealthier than an impatient one, but it will not grow faster” [Robert Lucas Jr.] Learning Goals: Acknowledge the distinctive feature of capital, as compared to labour and land in terms of availability to production. Understand the extent to which capital accumulation can overcome the law of diminishing returns The mechanics of the Solow growth model. Evaluation of the Solow model through the lenses of the Kaldor facts. Distinguish the effects of a change in the saving rate from those of an exogenous change in technology Discuss the optimality of the saving rate in the context of the Solow model 2.1 Introduction The neoclassical theory of economic growth was pioneered by two independent economists, the American Robert Solow and the Australian Trevor Swan 30 . The main innovation of the Neoclassical model in respect to the Malthusian Model is the replacement of land by “capital” in the production function. By “capital”, we mean machinery, buildings, and other equipment. This modification is more than a mere change in form: contrary to land, which is available in finite supply, capital can be produced and accumulated. This opens an avenue to overcome diminishing returns on labour: by allowing the capital stock to expand over time, 30 Solow, R., 1956. “A contribution to the theory of economic growth”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 50, 65-94. Swan, T., 1956. “Economic growth and capital accumulation”, Economic Record 32, 334-61. https://mlebredefreitas.wordpress.com/teaching-materials/economic-growth-models-a-primer/ 11/02/2021 75 Economic Growth Models: A Primer /Student's Guide, Miguel Lebre de Freitas the Solow model avoids the tendency for productivity to decrease with the size of population that plagues the Malthus model. In the Solow model, the long run is not characterized by a low income equilibrium trap. Still, because capital itself faces diminishing returns, capital accumulation alone cannot generate long-run growth: in the Solow model, a higher investment rate translates into a higher level of per capita income in the long run, but it does deliver sustained growth of per capita income. This chapter presents the Solow model in its simplest formulation. In Section 2.2, we describe the main assumptions of the model and we characterize the equilibrium. In Section 2.3, we compare the predictions of the model with the main stylized facts of Modern Economic Growth. In Section 2.4 we discuss how the main endogenous variables of the model respond to changes in the exogenous parameters. Section 2.5 addresses the question as to whether a government should try to influence an economy’ saving rate. Section 2.6 extends the model to the case in which the saving rate is optimally decided by individual agents. Section 2.7 introduces a growth accounting exercise to illustrate the fundamental limitation of this simple version of the Solow model, which is not to account for productivity growth. Section 2.8 concludes. 2.2 The Solow model 2.2.1 The neo-classical production function In the Malthus model, with all else constant, an increase in the size of the labour force leads to a decline in per capita income. This is a direct consequence of the Law of Diminishing Returns: as long as the availability of land is unchanged, its higher intensive use will translate into lower labour productivity. The Solow model retains the assumption of diminishing returns to labour, but explores another property of the neoclassical production function: Constant Returns to Scale (see box). Under constant return to scale, per capita https://mlebredefreitas.wordpress.com/teaching-materials/economic-growth-models-a-primer/ 11/02/2021 76 Economic Growth Models: A Primer /Student's Guide, Miguel Lebre de Freitas income may remain constant over time in spite of an expanding increase labour force, provided the stock of capital expands at the same rate as employment. To see this, let’s assume that the aggregate production function in the economy is as follows31: 1 Yt AK t N t , 0 < < 1 (2.1) where K denotes for the economy’ capital stock, N for the size of the labour force, Y for output and A is Total Factor Productivity. Dividing the production function (2.1) by the size of the workforce (N), one obtains an expression that relates per capita output to capital per worker: K y t A Ak t , (2.2) N In (2.2), y=Y/N denotes for per capita income and k=K/N is the capital-labour ratio. Equation (2.2) is called the production function in the intensive form and stresses the role of the capital-labour ratio as a key driver of per capita income. Thus, as long as capital and labour expand at the same rate, the capital labour ratio will remain constant and so will do per capita income. The interesting feature of the Solow model is that we do not need to postulate K to grow at the same rate as the labour force. As we will see next, the properties of the model are such that the capital stock, even if endogenous, will end up growing at the same rate as the labour force in the long run, ensuring that per capita income remains constant. Box 2.1 Constant returns to scale The key assumption of the neoclassical growth model is that of constant returns to scale (CRS). CRS means that if one increases the use of all inputs by a given proportion, 31 The Solow model is consistent with more general specifications for the production function. The Cobb-Douglas production function is assumed for mathematical convenience. https://mlebredefreitas.wordpress.com/teaching-materials/economic-growth-models-a-primer/ 11/02/2021 77 Economic Growth Models: A Primer /Student's Guide, Miguel Lebre de Freitas output will rise in the same proportion. For instance, duplicating the use of labour and capital we will obtain the double of output. The CRS property can easily be checked in equation (2.1): for any q 0, AqK qN 1 qY . Note that CRS is not inconsistent with the LDR: the Law of Diminishing Returns states that increasing the use of one input while holding the other inputs constant, output will grow less than proportionally. The law of diminishing returns applied when only onf input is increasing: the Constant Returns to Scale property applies when all inputs increase in the same proportion at the same time. Figure 2.1. Diminishing returns versus constant returns to scale yY N C y0 K A y A1 N1 y1 B K y A0 N0 N N N 0 1 The Figure displays the average product of labour as a function of the size of the labour force. The curve is negatively sloped because of diminishing returns (from A to B). When the capital stock increases, the schedle shifts to the right. If the capital stock and population increase in the same propostion, the average product of labour remains constant (from A to C). To illustrate the difference, we refer to Figure 2.1. The figure displays the average product of labour as a function of the labour force. The schedule is negatively sloped because of the Law of Diminishing Returns: all else constant (including the capital stock), an increase in the use of labour from N 0 to N1 implies a decline in the output per worker from y0 (point A) to y1 (point B). This is the main mechanism in the Malthusian model. In the Solow model, in contrast, the second input, capital, is allowed to expand: moreover, the steady state of the model is such that the capital stock grows exactly in the same proportion as labour. In that case, we see from (2.2) that per capita income remains constant. In terms of Figure 2.1, this is illustrate by a move from A to C: if, when labour expands from N 0 to N1 , the capital https://mlebredefreitas.wordpress.com/teaching-materials/economic-growth-models-a-primer/ 11/02/2021 78 Economic Growth Models: A Primer /Student's Guide, Miguel Lebre de Freitas stock also increases, and exactly in the same proportion (such that KL0 0 KL 1 1 ), then the capital labour ratio remains constant and so will be per capita income, y0 . In general, production functions may exhibit decreasing returns to scale (when output grows less than proportionally than all inputs) and increasing returns to scale (when output grows more than proportionally than all inputs). Decreasing returns to scale in its pure form is unlikely: if we managed to increase all inputs in a given proportion, there should be no reasons for output to respond less than proportionally. The case with increasing returns is trickier and will be addressed later in this book. 2.2.2 Main assumptions of the Solow model Consider a closed economy with no government with a large number of small firms producing a single homogeneous good, Y, using two inputs: labour (N), and capital (K). Population and the labour force are the same. Inputs are hired from households, who are also the owners of the firms and the consumers in this economy. Households spend a fraction (1-s) of their income on consumption, and save the remaining fraction, to acquire new capital. The capital stock depreciates at a constant rate, . Perfect competition and flexible prices are assumed, so full employment holds each moment in time. Since in this model there is no tendency for per capita income to approach a low level subsistence trap, one no longer needs to worry with Malthusian barriers limiting population growth.
Recommended publications
  • NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GROWTH ACCOUNTING Charles
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GROWTH ACCOUNTING Charles R. Hulten Working Paper 15341 http://www.nber.org/papers/w15341 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 September 2009 Paper prepared for the Handbook of the Economics of Innovation, Bronwyn H. Hall and Nathan Rosenberg (eds.), Elsevier-North Holland, in process. I would like to thank the many people that commented on earlier drafts: Susanto Basu, Erwin Diewert, John Haltiwanger, Janet Hao, Michael Harper, Jonathan Haskell, Anders Isaksson, Dale Jorgenson, and Paul Schreyer. Remaining errors and interpretations are solely my responsibility. JEL No. O47, E01. The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2009 by Charles R. Hulten. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Growth Accounting Charles R. Hulten NBER Working Paper No. 15341 September 2009 JEL No. E01,O47 ABSTRACT Incomes per capita have grown dramatically over the past two centuries, but the increase has been unevenly spread across time and across the world. Growth accounting is the principal quantitative tool for understanding this phenomenon, and for assessing the prospects for further increases in living standards. This paper sets out the general growth accounting model, with its methods and assumptions, and traces its evolution from a simple index-number technique that decomposes economic growth into capital-deepening and productivity components, to a more complex account of the growth process.
    [Show full text]
  • 41 CHAPTER 3 EXOGENOUS and ENDOGENOUS GROWTH Neo-Classical Theory, in All Its Forms, Shows a Strong Tendency to Reduce the Econo
    41 University of Pretoria etd - De Jager, JLW (2004) CHAPTER 3 EXOGENOUS AND ENDOGENOUS GROWTH Neo-classical theory, in all its forms, shows a strong tendency to reduce the economic complexity of the analysis, doing so by holding the institutional framework constant. Choi (1983:33) 3.1 INTRODUCTION In terms of the initial neoclassical theory described by Solow (1956) and augmented by others, sustained economic growth occurs through an exogenous factor of production, that is, the passage of time. The neoclassical production function used in this theory relates output to factor inputs, which consist of the stock of accumulated physical capital goods (buildings, machinery, transport equipment, computers, and so on) and labour, which is regarded as only one type. The theory imposes decreasing returns with respect to the use of each (reproducible) factor of production (and constant returns overall). From these assumptions it follows that an increase in the stock of capital goods will result in a less than proportionate increase in output, provided the amount of labour employed stays the same (Van der Ploeg and Tang 1992:15). Eventually more capital stock will produce no more output, resulting in lower profits, and for this reason output growth cease. If new technologies improve the productivity of labour and of capital and so prevent a decrease in the rate of return on investment, the labour force will grow at an exogenous rate. The growth of output is accordingly related to the amount and quality of the stocks of production factors. That part of output growth that cannot be explained by the growth in production factors is often called the Solow residual by economic researchers and/or total factor productivity in applied work.
    [Show full text]
  • Solow Residuals Without Capital Stocks
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Burda, Michael C.; Severgnini, Battista Working Paper Solow residuals without capital stocks SFB 649 Discussion Paper, No. 2008,040 Provided in Cooperation with: Collaborative Research Center 649: Economic Risk, Humboldt University Berlin Suggested Citation: Burda, Michael C.; Severgnini, Battista (2008) : Solow residuals without capital stocks, SFB 649 Discussion Paper, No. 2008,040, Humboldt University of Berlin, Collaborative Research Center 649 - Economic Risk, Berlin This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/25290 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die
    [Show full text]
  • Growth Accounting
    University College Dublin, Advanced Macroeconomics Notes, 2020 (Karl Whelan) Page 1 Growth Accounting The final part of this course will focus on what is known as \growth theory." Unlike most of macroeconomics, which concerns itself with what happens over the course of the business cycle (why unemployment or inflation go up or down during expansions and recessions), this branch of macroeconomics concerns itself with what happens over longer periods of time. In particular, it looks at the question \What determines the growth rate of the economy over the long run and what can policy measures do to affect it?" As we will also discuss, this is related to the even more fundamental question of what makes some countries rich and others poor. We will also examine how economies behaved prior to the modern era of economic growth and discuss the tensions between economic growth and environmental sustainability. In this set of notes, we will cover what is known as \growth accounting" { a technique for explaining the factors that determine growth. Production Functions The usual starting point for growth accounting is the assumption that total real output in an economy is produced using an aggregate production function technology that depends on the total amount of labour and capital used in the economy. For illustration, assume that this takes the form of a Cobb-Douglas production function: α β Yt = AtKt Lt (1) where Kt is capital input and Lt is labour input. Note that an increase in At results in higher output without having to raise inputs. Macroeconomists usually call increases in At \technological progress" and often refer to this as the \technology" term.
    [Show full text]
  • TFP Growth in Old and New Europe
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Burda, Michael C.; Severgnini, Battista Working Paper TFP growth in old and new Europe SFB 649 Discussion Paper, No. 2009,033 Provided in Cooperation with: Collaborative Research Center 649: Economic Risk, Humboldt University Berlin Suggested Citation: Burda, Michael C.; Severgnini, Battista (2009) : TFP growth in old and new Europe, SFB 649 Discussion Paper, No. 2009,033, Humboldt University of Berlin, Collaborative Research Center 649 - Economic Risk, Berlin This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/39330 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort
    [Show full text]
  • What Do Endogenous Growth Models Contribute?
    What Do Endogenous Growth Models Contribute? David C. Maré Motu Working Paper 04–04 Motu Economic and Public Policy Research July 2004 Author contact details David C. Maré Motu Economic and Public Policy Research PO Box 24390 Wellington New Zealand Email: [email protected] Acknowledgements This paper was commissioned by the Ministry of Economic Development, as a contribution to their seminar series on “Approaches to understanding economic growth”. The paper was presented at the Ministry of Economic Development on 3 March 2004. Motu Economic and Public Policy Research PO Box 24390 Wellington New Zealand Email [email protected] Telephone +64-4-939-4250 Website www.motu.org.nz © 2004 Motu Economic and Public Policy Research Trust. All rights reserved. No portion of this paper may be reproduced without permission of the authors. Motu Working Papers are research materials circulated by their authors for purposes of information and discussion. They have not necessarily undergone formal peer review or editorial treatment. ISSN 1176-2667. ii Abstract Endogenous growth theory is one of the mainstream economics approaches to modelling economic growth. This paper provides a non-technical overview of some key strands of the endogenous growth theory (EGT) literature, providing references to key articles and texts.1 The intended audience is policy analysts who want to understand the intuition behind EGT models. The paper should be accessible to someone without much economics training. JEL classification O31—Technological Change; Research and Development—Innovation and Invention: Processes and Incentives O40—Economic Growth and Aggregate Productivity—General Keywords Endogenous Growth, Innovation 1 Aghion and Howitt (1998) provide an extremely useful broad treatment of EGT.
    [Show full text]
  • Solow and Growth Accounting: a Perspective from Quantitative Economic History
    SOLOW AND GROWTH ACCOUNTING: A PERSPECTIVE FROM QUANTITATIVE ECONOMIC HISTORY NICHOLAS CRAFTS (University of Warwick) August 2008 Revised draft of paper for HOPE Conference, Robert Solow and the Development of Growth Economics, Duke University, April 2008. I am grateful to Steven Durlauf, Mary Morgan and two anonymous referees for helpful comments on an earlier version. Lennart Schon and Gianni Toniolo kindly provided data. I am responsible for all errors. 1. Introduction Robert Solow's (1957) paper was a landmark in the development of growth accounting. As is well-known, it was not the first paper to make an explicit decomposition of the sources of growth into contributions from factor inputs and from output per unit of total input. This had been done several times since the pioneering paper by Jan Tinbergen (1942). Nor was it original to claim that virtually all recent labour productivity growth in the United States had come from the residual contribution of total factor productivity (TFP); research at the NBER summarized by Solomon Fabricant (1954), and with more detail, by Moses Abramovitz (1956) had already come to pretty much the same conclusion. The culmination of the NBER work was the magisterial volume by John Kendrick (1961) which found that 80.0 and 88.5 per cent of the growth of labor productivity between 1869 and 1953 and between 1909 and 1948, respectively, was due to TFP. But it was Solow (1957) that put the growth economics into growth accounting making clear its interpretation in terms of the distinction between shifts of and moves along the aggregate production function.
    [Show full text]
  • Productivity and Unemployment in the Short and Long Run
    SCHWARTZ CENTER FOR ECONOMIC POLICY ANALYSIS THE NEW SCHOOL WORKING PAPER 2007-8 Productivity and Unemployment in the Short and Long Run Pu Chen, Armon Rezai and Willi Semmler Schwartz Center for Economic Policy Analysis Department of Economics The New School for Social Research 6 East 16th Street, New York, NY 10003 www.economicpolicyresearch.org Suggested Citation: Chen, Pu, Rezai, Armon and Semmler, Willi. SEPTEMBER (2007) “Productivity and Unemployment in the Short and Long Run” Schwartz Center for Economic Policy Analysis and Department of Economics, 2007 The New School for Social Research, Working Paper Series. Abstract The nexus between productivity growth and unemployment has been studied in various ways for a long time. In this paper we present a new one, which is to disaggregate data on productivity growth into its short and long run component. First, we discuss some important contributions in the literature studying the relationship between productivity growth and unemployment both in the short run and long run perspective. Second, we explore the effect of productivity growth on unemployment empirically. Using maximum likelihood estimation (MLE), structural vector autoregression (SVAR) and non-parametric time-varying estimation, we show that in the short run productivity growth affects unemployment positively. In the long run, however, the productivity growth reduces unemployment. * We thank R. Solow for useful comments on earlier drafts and gratefully acknowledge the valuable contributions of Tarron Khemraj in the preparation of this paper. † Department of Economics, University of Bielefeld ‡ Schwartz Center of Economic Policy Analysis, New School, New York § Schwartz Center of Economic Policy Analysis, New School, New York, and Center for Empirical Macroeconomics, Bielefeld 1 Introduction The relationship between productivity growth and unemployment has been debated ever since the classical economists.
    [Show full text]
  • Explicit Derivation of the Bias in the Solow Residual in the Existence of Imperfect Competition and Non-Constant Returns to Scale
    D.E.Ü.İ.İ.B.F.Dergisi Cilt:18 Sayı:1, Yıl:2003, ss:63-70 EXPLICIT DERIVATION OF THE BIAS IN THE SOLOW RESIDUAL IN THE EXISTENCE OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND NON-CONSTANT RETURNS TO SCALE Sacit Hadi AKDEDE(∗) ABSTRACT The main purpose of this paper is to explicitly derive the possible bias in the Solow residual when there is imperfect competition and non-constant returns to scale. As is known very well, the standard Solow residual assumes perfect competition and constant returns to scale. As is also known, Solow residual is one of the measures of total factor productivity. Therefore, if there is imperfect competition and non-constant returns to scale, then standard Solow measure of productivity will be biased and all the comparisons based on this residual will be unreliable. In this study, we shed some light on these issues. Key words: Total Factor Productivity, Bias in the Solow Residual. 1. Introduction Productivity varies enormously across different nations. In 1988, output per worker was 48 times higher in the most productive compared to least productive countries ( Hall and Jones, 1996). In this last sentence we understand that productivity is measured by output per worker. Output per worker is not the only measure of the productivity. There are many different measures of productivity other than labor productivity. These different measures of productivity and measurement issues and procyclical nature of productivity can make the comparisons among industries and nations difficult. ( Baily and Gordon, 1988: 347-420; Basu, 1993; Shapiro 1987:118-124). In this respects, in discussing statistical problems associated with measurement error, Evans (1992: 191-208) states that mismeasurement of inputs creates a serious problem.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 5 Real Business Cycles
    Chapter 5 Real business cycles 5.1 Real business cycles The most well known paper in the Real Business Cycles (RBC) literature is Kydland and Prescott (1982). That paper introduces both a specific theory of business cycles, and a methodology for testing competing theories of business cycles. The RBC theory of business cycles has two principles: 1. Money is of little importance in business cycles. 2. Business cycles are created by rational agents responding optimally to real (not nominal) shocks - mostly fluctuations in productivity growth, but also fluctuations in government purchases, import prices, or pref- erences. The “RBC” methodology also comes down to two principles: 1. The economy should always be modeled using dynamic general equi- librium models (with rational expectations). 2. The quantitative implications of a proposed model should be taken se- riously. In particular, a model’s suitability for describing reality should be evaluated using a quantitative technique known as “calibration”. If the model “fits” the data, its quantitative policy implications should be taken seriously. 1 2 CHAPTER 5. REAL BUSINESS CYCLES Romer, writing just a few years ago, treats these two meanings of the term as essentially the same. But since then, the RBC methodology has taken hold in a lot of places - researchers have analyzed “RBC” models with money, with all sorts of market imperfections, etc. In order to reflect this change, researchers are trying to change the name of the methodology to the more accurate (if awkward) “stochastic dynamic general equilibrium macroeconomics.” 5.1.1 Some facts about business cycles Business cycles are the reason why macroeconomics exists as a field of study, and they’re the primary consideration of many macroeconomists.
    [Show full text]
  • Panel Data, Factor Models, and the Solow Residual"
    Panel Data, Factor Models, and the Solow Residual Alois Kneip Robin C. Sicklesy Department of Economics Department of Economics University of Bonn Rice University Bonn, Germany Houston, Texas Revised June 2010 Abstract In this paper we discuss the Solow residual (Solow, 1957) and how it has been interpreted and measured in the neoclassical production litera- ture and in the complementary literature on productive e¢ ciency. We point out why panel data are needed to measure productive e¢ ciency and innovation and thus link the two strands of literatures. We provide a discussion on the various estimators used in the two literatures, focusing on one class of estimators in particular, the factor model. We evaluate in …nite samples the performance of a particular factor model, the model of Kneip, Sickles, and Song (2009), in identifying productive e¢ ciencies. We also point out that the measurement of the two main sources of pro- ductivity growth, technical change and technical e¢ ciency change, may be not be feasible in many empirical settings and that alternative survey based approaches o¤er advantages that have yet to be exploited in the productivity accounting literature. JEL Classi…cation: Key words and phrases: .Productivity, Panel Data, Factor Models, Tech- nical E¢ ciency, This paper is based in part on keynote lectures given by Sickles at the Preconference Workshop of the 2008 Asia-Paci…c Productivity Conference, July 17-19, Department of Eco- nomics, National Taiwan University, Taipei, Taiwan, 2008; Anadolu University International Conference in Economics: Developments in Economic Theory, Modeling and Policy, Eski¸sehir, Turkey, June 17-19, 2009; and the 15th Conference on Panel Data, Bonn, July 3-5, 2009.
    [Show full text]
  • Elogi Solow.Qxp 27/02/2008 12:48 Pægina 1
    elogi solow.qxp 27/02/2008 12:48 PÆgina 1 ROBERT M. SOLOW LAUDATIO DR. JAUME VENTURA, Researcher at CREI and lecturer at Pompeu Fabra University's Department of Economics and Business. 29th February 2008 Ciutadella campus auditorium UNIVERSITAT POMPEU FABRA t is a great honor to introduce Robert Merton Solow, who will receive today a Doctor Honoris Causa degree from Pompeu Fabra I University. Among economists, Robert Solow needs no introduction. He is among a handful of great minds that laid the foundations of the field of macroeconomics for the 20th century and beyond. His influence on today’s practice of macroeconomics is evident everywhere. Robert Solow has earned numerous prizes and awards, including the Nobel Prize in Economics in 1987. Robert Solow was born in Brooklyn, New York on August 23, 1924. He was the eldest of three children. After going through New York’s public school system, the young Solow won a scholarship to Harvard College and moved there in 1940. His interests led him to study Sociology, Anthropology and Economics. In a short autobiography written for the Nobel Prize website, he says: “Like many other children of the Depression, I was curious about what makes society tick.” In 1942, Robert Solow interrupted his studies to join the Army. He served in North Africa and Italy as a spotter in small planes for artillery elogi solow.qxp 27/02/2008 12:48 PÆgina 2 guidance. After marrying Barbara (Bobbie) Lewis, he returned to Harvard in 1945 to complete his undergraduate degree and obtain his PhD. There he found Wassily Leontief who taught him, in Robert Solow’s own words, “the spirit as well as the substance of modern economic theory”.
    [Show full text]