Taxation Research As Economic Research

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Taxation Research As Economic Research Taxation Research as Economic Research Paper number 01/07 Simon James University of Exeter Simon James, School of Business and Economics, University of Exeter, Streatham Court, Rennes Drive, Exeter, EX4 4PU, United Kingdom. Email: [email protected] Acknowledgements The author is grateful for comments on earlier versions from Alan Macnaughton, John Maloney and Claudio Radaelli, for comments on an earlier draft. 1 ISSN No: 1473 2939 2 1. Introduction Economics is concerned with the production and distribution of wealth. Taxation has either direct or indirect effects on almost every aspect of production and distribution in modern economies and is therefore an important aspect in economic research. Indeed taxation is associated with almost everything economic from globalisation (Owens, 1993) to divorce (Cebula and Belton, 1995). The result has been an enormous body of literature and all that can be attempted here is to indicate some of the main areas of research activity. The research ranges from highly technical and theoretical work to more practical economic analyses of policy questions. It includes theoretical contributions, econometric studies, interview surveys and some experimental work. In terms of interdisciplinary research, it is the policy area that has the most scope for successful work because it is here that an economic approach has the greatest opportunities to strengthen the research by drawing on other disciplines such as Accounting, Law, Psychology and Sociology. In Economics the main direct contribution to tax research is based in the general subject area of Public Finance. Taxation is therefore dealt with as a major part of general public finance texts such as Brown and Jackson (1990) and Cullis and Jones (1998). Atkinson and Stiglitz (1980) give an introduction to the subject at graduate level and a further technical treatment is supplied by Jha (1998). Tax is the specific focus of other textbooks. These include Kay and King (1990) who deal with the subject with reference to the British tax system and James and Nobes (2000) who offer a more general treatment. Although much of the emphasis in economics research relates to markets of one sort or another, it is widely agreed by economists that the public sector has important economic functions. Therefore a general theme in tax research is how the necessary tax revenue to support the public sector can be raised in the most efficient and equitable way. The next two sections of the paper deal with economic efficiency, Section 2 with respect to the allocation of resources and Section 3 with tax and incentives to work, save and invest. Section 4 turns to equity and the distribution of 3 income and Section 5 to macroeconomic considerations. Section 6 gives a brief account of experimental work in Economics. Section 7 turns to research focused on particular types of taxation and Section 8 to some specific areas of tax policy and reform. Finally there has been some criticism both inside and outside the profession that the contribution of economics to policy research may not always be as relevant as it might be and this is discussed briefly in Section 9. 2. Economic Efficiency and the Allocation of Resources. ‘He’s spending a year dead for tax reasons,’ wrote the science fiction writer Douglas Adams in The Restaurant at the End of the Universe. Generally, it is thought that if people do things for tax reasons, rather than because of the underlying economic costs and benefits, they are behaving inefficiently in economic terms even if they gain some personal financial advantage. While it is possible that people might in the future wish to spend time dead as a matter of personal choice, it is not economically efficient if they do so only to avoid taxation. Economic efficiency is about maximising economic output given the resources available to the community. This is not just maximising production but also producing the goods and services that consumers value most. It is possible to show that, in certain circumstances, markets are economically efficient. If a tax distorts an otherwise efficient market this is known as the excess burden of taxation. This is the extra economic cost imposed on the community because taxes have caused people to make economic decisions they would not otherwise have made. In the Douglas Adams case it would be the loss of one year of life given up to save tax. There are countless examples throughout an economy of distortionary behaviour caused by taxation and a great deal of economic tax research has been undertaken into the excess burden caused by different taxes in different circumstances (James and Nobes, 2000). Some of the economic research in this area is very technical but general conclusions can be drawn, subject to a number of limitations and exceptions. In efficient markets, taxes that have a wider base are less likely to create distortions than those with a 4 narrower base. Thus a tax on all goods and services is likely to be less distortionary than taxes on only a limited number of goods and services. Another conclusion relates to goods and services that are inelastic in demand or supply, in other words the amount bought and sold changes relatively little when the price changes. Higher taxes on such goods cause a relatively low fall in consumption and also, therefore, the level of tax revenue is more robust. Examples include the taxation of alcohol and tobacco. With inefficient markets, there may be scope to use taxation to guide economic behaviour in the right direction. For example, some economic activities, such as those causing pollution, impose costs on the wider community. It might be possible to assign such costs to the producers and consumers by imposing a special tax. The result has been the development of various forms of corrective taxation, including ‘pollution charges’, ‘green taxes’ and so on (Cordes, et al., 1990, Nicolaisen et al. 1991, Symonds, et al. Smith, 1992 and Oates, 1995). A particularly topical issue here is the debate regarding road congestion taxes (Newbery and Santos, 1999). There may be other costs to the consumers themselves and this has been used, for instance, as part of the justification for higher taxation on alcohol (Irving and Sims, 1993, Cook and Moore, 1994) and tobacco (Viscusi, 1994). 3. Economic Efficiency and Incentives Another very large part of tax research relating to economic efficiency is concerned with incentives, particularly the effects of taxation on the willingness of individuals to work, to save and to invest. The effects of taxation on work effort, or labour supply, has generated a huge amount of research. When an income tax is increased this reduces the net financial return to work and individuals might substitute other activities or leisure for paid employment - and this is known as the substitution effect. On the other hand, a tax increase would make individuals worse off and therefore that might make them work harder to maintain their incomes - the income effect. The overall effect of taxation on labour supply is therefore an empirical question and has been subject to a very large number of investigations. 5 Interviews asking individuals about the effects of taxation on their work effort might well be subject to bias of one sort or another. However, an early interview study by Break (1957) became something of a classic because of the care it took to avoid influencing the respondents. This study was replicated by Fields and Stanbury (1971) and similar studies have been conducted by Barlow et al. (1966) and others. There is also a considerable amount of econometric evidence largely based on the relationship between labour supply and net wages. Useful sources covering the material include Brown (1983) for a general overview, Pencavel (1986) with respect to the labour supply of men and Killingsworth and Heckman (1986) regarding female labour supply. A survey of the subject is presented by Blundell (1992). The main result of this work is the conclusion that in general taxation does not have much effect on the labour supply of most individuals. However, some econometric evidence has been taken to suggest that the effect of taxation on married women provides a significant disincentive to paid labour supply. For instance Killingsworth’s (1983: 432) survey found that ‘most of the available evidence suggests that female labour supply, measured either as labour force participation or as hours of work, is considerably more wage and property income elastic than male labour supply.’ This seems to be an example of an area where economic analysis and econometric studies can be enhanced by a multidisciplinary input. For instance there is psychological and sociological evidence that, despite many years of discussion about possible changes in gender roles, many women with children still see themselves primarily as care-givers, while their male partners still see themselves as ‘breadwinners’ (James et al., 1992, James, 1995). If women have difficulties in combining their family and paid work with current labour market practices this may affect econometric evidence of the effect of taxation on their labour market behaviour. Also, further econometric work which has tackled some of the problems of estimation has indicated that the effects of taxation on the paid employment of women is less than earlier work has suggested – see, for example Mroz (1987) and Blundell (1992). The effects of taxation on saving have also received a considerable amount of attention. Only through saving can economic resources be released for capital investment and the rate of saving can affect the level of economic activity by 6 influencing the aggregate level of demand. The tax system can make a substantial difference to the rate of return to saving. However it is not clear how far this adversely affects saving since different researchers have produced different results.
Recommended publications
  • CURRICULUM VITAE Arnold C. Harberger 2017 Distinguished
    CURRICULUM VITAE Arnold C. Harberger 2017 Distinguished Professor Emeritus, University of California, Los Angeles And Gustavus F. and Ann M. Swift Distinguished Service Professor, Department of Economics, University of Chicago (Emeritus since Oct. 1991) Born: July 27, 1924; Newark, New Jersey Marital Status: Widowed since June 26, 2011 Education Johns Hopkins University, 1941-43 University of Chicago, 1946-49; A.M. (International Relations), 1947 Ph.D. (Economics), 1950 Career Academic Positions Assistant Professor of Political Economy, Johns Hopkins University, 1949-1953 Associate Professor of Economics, University of Chicago, 1953-59 Professor of Economics, University of Chicago, 1959-76 Gustavus F. and Ann M. Swift, Distinguished Service Professor in Economics, University of Chicago, 1977 - 1991 Chairman, Department of Economics, University of Chicago, 1964-71; 1975-1980 Director, Center for Latin American Economic Studies, University of Chicago, 1965 - 1991 Gustavus F. and Ann M. Swift Distinguished Service Professor Emeritus, University of Chicago, 1991 - Professor of Economics, University of California, Los Angeles, 1984 – Distinguished Professor, 1998- Professor Emeritus since December 2014 Temporary Academic Positions Research Assistant, Cowles Commission for Research in Economics, 1949 Visiting Professor, MIT Center for International Studies (New Delhi), 1961-62 Visiting Professor, Harvard University, 1971-72 Visiting Professor, Princeton University, 1973-74 Visiting Professor, University of California, Los Angeles, 1983-84 Professor,
    [Show full text]
  • On the Mechanics of Economic Development*
    Journal of Monetary Economics 22 (1988) 3-42. North-Holland ON THE MECHANICS OF ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT* Robert E. LUCAS, Jr. University of Chicago, Chicago, 1L 60637, USA Received August 1987, final version received February 1988 This paper considers the prospects for constructing a neoclassical theory of growth and interna­ tional trade that is consistent with some of the main features of economic development. Three models are considered and compared to evidence: a model emphasizing physical capital accumula­ tion and technological change, a model emphasizing human capital accumulation through school­ ing. and a model emphasizing specialized human capital accumulation through learning-by-doing. 1. Introduction By the problem of economic development I mean simply the problem of accounting for the observed pattern, across countries and across time, in levels and rates of growth of per capita income. This may seem too narrow a definition, and perhaps it is, but thinking about income patterns will neces­ sarily involve us in thinking about many other aspects of societies too. so I would suggest that we withhold judgment on the scope of this definition until we have a clearer idea of where it leads us. The main features of levels and rates of growth of national incomes are well enough known to all of us, but I want to begin with a few numbers, so as to set a quantitative tone and to keep us from getting mired in the wrong kind of details. Unless I say otherwise, all figures are from the World Bank's World Development Report of 1983. The diversity across countries in measured per capita income levels is literally too great to be believed.
    [Show full text]
  • SECOND OPEN LETTER to Arnold Harberger and Muton Friedman
    SECOND OPEN LETTER to Arnold Harberger and MUton Friedman April 1976 II Milton Friedman and Arnold Harberger: You will recall that, following Harberger's first public visit to Chile after the military coup, I wrote you an open letter on August 6, 1974. After Harberger's second visit and the public announcement of Fried- man's intention to go to Chile as well, I wrote you a postscript on February 24, 1975. You will recall that in this open letter and postscript I began by reminis- cing about the genesis, during the mid-1950's, when I was your graduate student, of the "Chile program" in the Department of Economics at the University of Chicago, in which you trained the so-called "Chicago boys", who now inspire and execute the economic policy of the military Junta in Chile. I then went on to summarize the "rationale" of your and the Junta's policy by quoting Harberger's public declarations in Chile and by citing the Junta's official spokesmen and press. Finally, I examined with you the consequences, particularly for the people of Chile, of the applica- tion by military .force of this Chicago/Junta policy: political repression and torture, monopolization and sell-out to foreign capital, unemployment and starv- ation, declining health and increasing crime, all fos- tered by a calculated policy of political and economic genocide. 56 ECONOMIC GENOCIDE IN CHILE Since my last writing, worldwide condemnation of the Junta's policy has continued and increased, cul- minating with the condemnation of the Junta's violation of human rights by the United Nations General Assembly in a resolution approved by a vast majority including even the United States and with the Junta's condemnation even by the Human Rights Committee of the US-dominated reactionary Organiz- ation of American States.
    [Show full text]
  • Dams Economic Development Institute *;14,P of the World Bank Public Disclosure Authorized the Economic Evaluation of Projects
    -I51,5 OoWIc9& *dams Economic Development Institute *;14,P of The World Bank Public Disclosure Authorized The Economic Evaluation of Projects Papersfrom a Curriculum Development Workshiop Public Disclosure Authorized Edited by David G. Davies Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized EDI LEARNING RESOURCES SERIES EDI LFARNNG RESOURCESSERIES The Economic Evaluation of Projects Papersfrom a Curriculum Development Workshop Edited by David G. Davies The World Bank Washington, D. C. / 1996 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / THE WORLD BANK 1818 H Street, N.W. Washington, D.C. 20433, U.S.A. All rights reserved Manufactured in the United States of America First printing July 1996 The Economic Development Institute (EDI) was established by the World Bank in 1955 to train officials concemed with development planning, policymaking, investment analysis, and project implementation in member developing countries. At present the substance of the EDI's work emphasizes macroeconomic and sectoral economic policy analysis. Through a variety of courses, seminars, and workshops, most of which are given overseas in cooperation with local institutions, the EDI seeks to sharpen analytical skills used in policy analysis and to broaden understanding of the experience of individual countries with economic development. Although the EDI's publications are designed to support its training activities, many are of interest to a much broader audience. EDI materials, including any findings, interpretations, and conclusions, are entirely those of the authors and should not be attributed in any manner to the World Bank, to its affiliated organizations, or to members of its Board of Executive Directors or the countries they represent. Because of the informality of this series and to make the publication available with the least possible delay, the manuscript has not been edited as fully as would be the case with a more formal document, and the World Bank accepts no responsibility for errors.
    [Show full text]
  • Book Review Feature the Chicago
    BOOK REVIEW FEATURE The Chicago School, Hayek and the Mont Pèlerin Society Craig Freedman Chicago Fundamentalism: Ideology and Methodology in Economics Singapore & Hackensack, NJ: World Scientific Publishing, 2008, 472 pp., $130.95. Philip Mirowski & Dieter Plewhe (eds.) The Road from Mont Pèlerin: the Making of the Neoliberal Thought Collective Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press, 2009, 480 pp., $62. Reviewed by Evan Jones Many people have heard of the ‘Chicago School of Economics’ and would have a superficial awareness of its character. It is reputedly a haven of ‘free-market’ economics and its best known exponent is the ubiquitous Milton Friedman, who died in 2006. Its critics see it as being at the core of the vast neoliberal ideological and political project that has seen the state re-engineered in the interests of capital over the last three decades. The detractors have been joined by the mainstream economist turned popular columnist Paul Krugman, who recently criticised the Chicago school in an extended article in the New York Times (Krugman, 1 2009). 1 Krugman condemns the Chicago school for its long term denial of the possibility of systemic economic crises. Krugman highlights that later generations of Chicago economists (citing Robert Lucas and John Cochrane) are even more hardline than Friedman’s more nuanced macroanalysis. However, Krugman criticises the entire American economics profession for its ‘blindness to the very possibility of catastrophic failures in a market economy’. ‘… economists, as a group, mistook beauty, clad in impressive-looking mathematics, for truth.’ The article, while highlighting the conceits of mainstream macroeconomics, is nevertheless limited because of its implicit presumption that the salvation from crisis (leave alone other ills) is readily amenable purely from a functional macroanalysis and appropriate policies derived from such analysis.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 the Nobel Prize in Economics Turns 50 Allen R. Sanderson1 and John
    The Nobel Prize in Economics Turns 50 Allen R. Sanderson1 and John J. Siegfried2 Abstract The first Sveriges Riksbank Prizes in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel, were awarded in 1969, 50 years ago. In this essay we provide the historical origins of this sixth “Nobel” field, background information on the recipients, their nationalities, educational backgrounds, institutional affiliations, and collaborations with their esteemed colleagues. We describe the contributions of a sample of laureates to economics and the social and political world around them. We also address – and speculate – on both some of their could-have-been contemporaries who were not chosen, as well as directions the field of economics and its practitioners are possibly headed in the years ahead, and thus where future laureates may be found. JEL Codes: A1, B3 1 University of Chicago, Chicago, IL, USA 2Vanderbilt University, Nashville, TN, USA Corresponding Author: Allen Sanderson, Department of Economics, University of Chicago, 1126 East 59th Street, Chicago, IL 60637, USA Email: [email protected] 1 Introduction: The 1895 will of Swedish scientist Alfred Nobel specified that his estate be used to create annual awards in five categories – physics, chemistry, physiology or medicine, literature, and peace – to recognize individuals whose contributions have conferred “the greatest benefit on mankind.” Nobel Prizes in these five fields were first awarded in 1901.1 In 1968, Sweden’s central bank, to celebrate its 300th anniversary and also to champion its independence from the Swedish government and tout the scientific nature of its work, made a donation to the Nobel Foundation to establish a sixth Prize, the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel.2 The first “economics Nobel” Prizes, selected by the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences were awarded in 1969 (to Ragnar Frisch and Jan Tinbergen, from Norway and the Netherlands, respectively).
    [Show full text]
  • Sen's Capability Approach to Welfare Economics
    Sen’s Capability Approach to Welfare Economics (preliminary — comments welcome) do not quote without permission Wiebke Kuklys∗ Ingrid Robeyns† January 12, 2004 Abstract We describe Amartya Sen’s Capability Approach to welfare evaluation in the language of standard welfare economics, and assess to what extent it provides a genuine alternative for individual welfare measurement and policy evaluation. We review the nascent empirical literature on the ca- pability approach and assess whether it makes a genuine difference with standard welfare evaluation. Keywords: capability approach, welfare economics, welfare measure- ment, welfarism JEL Classifications:I31,I32 1Introduction Amartya Sen’s capability approach is a framework for the evaluation of indi- vidual welfare and social states, and as such can provide the theoretical basis for evaluative analyses and policy prescriptions. Sen’s capability approach has found wide resonance in a number of disciplines, including heterodox economics (Fukuda-Parr [23], Gasper [26], Robeyns, [54]), development economics (Alkire [1], Qizilbash [52]), development ethics (Crocker [20], Gasper [25]) and economic and political philosophy (Daniels [21], Nussbaum [46], Pettit [49], Williams [69]). This literature is characterised by its highly interdisciplinary nature and the pre- domination of philosophical and conceptual reasoning instead of modelling and ∗University of Cambridge and Max Planck Institute for Research Into Economic Systems, Jena, Germany. Correspondence to [email protected] †University of Amsterdam, Netherlands, and Columbia University, USA (visiting 2004). Correspondence to [email protected]. Both authors wish to thank Paul Anand, Werner Güth, Geoff Harcourt, Hamish Low and Stephan Klasen for comments on earlier versions. The usual disclaimer applies. 1 formalisations.
    [Show full text]
  • This PDF Is a Selection from a Published Volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research
    This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The Uses of Economic Research Volume Author/Editor: NBER Volume Publisher: NBER Vo l u me I S B N : Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/univ63-1 Conference Date: Publication Date: 1964 Chapter Title: Staff Reports; Authors of 1962–63 Studies; Publications Chapter Author(s): NBER Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c5384 Chapter pages in book: (p. 39 - 113) L ECONOMIC GROWTH TAXPOLICIES FOR ECONOMIC GROWTH This project focuses on the influence of various elements of the tax system on the economic processes which contribute to the expansion of production capability by increasing the volume of resources and their productivity. Our research efforts, therefore, aim at adding to our knowledge about the influence of the tax structure on the incentives and capabilities of taxpayers to undertake activities which con- tribute to growth in this way. Four sets of research projects are now under way. The first of these, financed by a grant from the Rockefeller Brothers Fund, is con- cerned with the effects of business income taxes P A R I IV oncapital formation and innovation. Challis A. Hall, Jr., Yale University, is investigating the impact of various features of the corpora- Staff tionincome tax on corporate policies with re- spect to capital expenditures and other activities relevantto business growth. Melvin I. White, Reorts Brooklyn College, initiated a study of the in- fluence of corporate income taxation on inno- vation in the textile industry which is being continued by Thomas M.
    [Show full text]
  • Hayek's Divorce and Move to Chicago · Econ Journal Watch
    Discuss this article at Journaltalk: https://journaltalk.net/articles/5973 ECON JOURNAL WATCH 15(3) September 2018: 301–321 Hayek’s Divorce and Move to Chicago Lanny Ebenstein1 LINK TO ABSTRACT The personal life of a great intellectual is not always highly pertinent. Al- though Friedrich Hayek may have been, in his son’s words, “the great philosopher with feet of clay” (L. Hayek 1994–1997), his clay feet would not necessarily detract from his scholarly contributions. But since Hayek was a moral philosopher—his title at the University of Chicago was Professor of Social and Moral Science—his personal life may be more relevant than would be the case for intellectuals in other fields. The history of Hayek’s personal life has not always, to this point, been accurately told. The story of his divorce and move to Chicago has often been presented as one in which he discovered after World War II on a visit to Vienna to see his mother and other family members that a distant cousin of his, Helene Bitterlich, with whom he had a relationship as a young man, felt free to marry him. After Helene’s husband died, she and Hayek decided to marry, requiring Hayek to divorce his first wife, the former Hella Fritsch. At the same time, it has been suggested, he began to feel out of place in England in the immediate postwar era as a result of the policies of the first Labour Party government. He relocated to America, having first sought a post in the Economics Department at the University of Chicago and then, after being turned down by it as a result of The Road to Serfdom (1944), having been offered a position in the Committee on Social Thought.
    [Show full text]
  • George Stigler As a Dissertation Supervisor*
    Do Great Economists Make Great Teachers? – George Stigler as a Dissertation Supervisor* President Reagan fared much better than the student who came to George complaining that he didn’t deserve the “F” he’d received in George’s course. George agreed but explained that “F” was the lowest grade the administration allowed him to give (Friedland 1993:782). In the eleven years that George Stigler labored at Columbia University he had exactly one dissertation student 1. That number did not radically increase during his subsequent first eleven years at Chicago, though it did in fact at least double 2. Stigler was an economist of great ability, skill and influence, arguably one of the best economic minds of his age. (This is a rather remarkable statement given compeers like Friedman and Samuelson.) Though he clearly thought teaching to be a lesser activity, an adjunct to research, George Stigler took his teaching very seriously (as he did all activities associated with his professional life). His influence on his colleagues in particular and the profession in general is unmistakable. Friends and foes alike (there were few, if any, who knowing George Stigler didn’t fall into one or the other category) conceded his ability to persuade whether in written or verbal form. The puzzle then is why such a formidable figure who contributed so much to economics, wasn’t sought out more as a dissertation advisor by the many graduate students passing through the economics department in Chicago? The answer reveals not only something about George Stigler himself (which might then remain on the purely idiosyncratic level), but also about graduate education in economics and more specifically about student supervision.
    [Show full text]
  • THE ACHIEVEMENT of ARNOLD HARBERGER by Julio H. Cole
    THE ACHIEVEMENT OF ARNOLD HARBERGER by Julio H. Cole Good morning. I should start out by saying what a great honor it is to comment on Professor Harberger’s paper. I’m very grateful for the opportunity, but I should also confess that when I first received the invitation I was also overcome by a sense of inadequacy. I was never a student of Harberger, nor did I ever work closely with him on any major project. (I did participate in a minor capacity on a project for policy reform in Guatemala that he led in the early 1990’s, but I was just one member of a very large team, and I did not have much direct interaction with him.) So I can’t say that I know him well. On the other hand, for a long time I have admired his style as an applied economist, and I have long been aware of his writings in several different fields of applied economics, writings that I have studied with care and often cited in my own work.1 And even though I have not myself worked in most of the areas to which he has devoted most of his career — public finance, for instance, has never been a major field of mine, nor have I done much work in project evaluation2 — I can say that “Alito”, as he is known throughout Latin America, has been a major role model for me, an experience that I know I share with many other Latin American economists of my generation. Unfortunately, I received the draft of his presentation only recently, so I haven’t had time enough to prepare a detailed comment on the paper he just delivered.
    [Show full text]
  • Understanding Robert Lucas (1967-1981)
    University of Brasilia Economics and Politics Research Group A CNPq-Brazil Research Group http://www.EconPolRG.wordpress.com Research Center on Economics and FinanceCIEF Research Center on Market Regulation–CERME Research Laboratory on Political Behavior, Institutions and Public PolicyLAPCIPP Master’s Program in Public EconomicsMESP Understanding Robert Lucas (1967-1981) Alexandre F. S. Andrada Universidade de Brasília Economics and Politics Working Paper 49/2015 April 15, 2015 Economics and Politics Research Group Working Paper Series Paper presented at the 4th ESHET Latin American Conference. Belo Horizonte – Brazil, November, 2014 _____________________________________________________________________________________ Understanding Robert Lucas (1967-1981) Alexandre F. S. Andrada [email protected] Universidade de Brasília (UnB) _____________________________________________________________________________________ Abstract This paper analyzes Robert Lucas’ contribution to economic theory between 1967 (year of his first solo publication) and 1981 (the year before the emergence of Real Business Cycle approach). The paper has two parts. In the first one, we do a citation analysis, using data from four different sources: Google Scholar, Web of Science, IDEAS RePEc and Jstor. With this data, we answer two questions: what is Lucas most influential papers nowadays? And how this influence changed over the time? We show, for instance, that according to three of those four sources, Lucas’ most influential paper today is not from his business cycle research agenda, which gave him his Nobel Prize. Moreover, it is clear the loss of influence of Lucas’ macroeconomic theory since early 1980s. In the second part, we construct a ranking with the papers Lucas most often used as reference in his paper, and we separate those reference in ‘positive’ and ‘negative’.
    [Show full text]