Following the Yellow Brick Road: How the United States Adopted the Gold Standard

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Following the Yellow Brick Road: How the United States Adopted the Gold Standard View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Research Papers in Economics Following the yellow brick road: How the United States adopted the gold standard François R. Velde Introduction and summary why it disappeared so suddenly, and whether the In 1900 L. Frank Baum published a childrens tale, United States could have taken another road. The Wonderful Wizard of Oz. In it, a little girl from Definitions the Midwest plains is transported by a tornado to the Land of Oz and accidentally kills the Wicked Witch I begin with some definitions. A commodity money of the East, setting the Munchkins free. Yearning to system is a monetary system in which a commodity return home, she takes the witchs silver shoes1 and (usually a metal) is also money; that is, the objects follows the Yellow Brick Road to the Emerald City, that serve as medium of exchange are made of that in search of the Wizard who will help her. She and the commodity. The essential feature of such a system is companions she meets on her way ultimately discov- that the commodity be easily turned into money and er that the wizard is a sham, and that the silver shoes back. This requires: 1) unrestricted minting, in the alone could have returned her to Aunt Em. Littlefield sense that the public mint always be ready to convert (1964) and Rockoff (1990) have decoded Baums tale any desired amount of metal into coin; and 2) unre- as an allegory on the monetary politics of late nine- stricted melting and exporting, allowing money to be teenth century America. The silver shoes are the silver converted into the commodity, or into other goods at standard, the witch of the East represents the mon- world prices. ied interest of the East Coast, the scarecrow and the A commodity money system based on gold or sil- tin man are the farmers and workers of the Midwest, ver is also described as a gold or silver standard. In while the cowardly lion is their unsuccessful champi- such a standard, the medium of exchange may not be on, William Jennings Bryan. The yellow brick road is limited strictly to coins, but may include notes (private- the gold standard, whose fallacy is exposed by Dorothys ly or publicly issued), as long as the notes are convert- triumphant return home borne by the silver shoes. ible on demand and at sight into coin. William Jennings Bryan, as nominee of the Dem- The double standard is one where both gold and ocratic Party in the presidential election of 1896, cam- silver are money. This is also called a bimetallic stan- paigned on a platform to reverse the so-called crime dard, or bimetallism. The characteristics of bimetallism of 1873. The phrase referred to the change in the include: United States monetary system from bimetallism, in 1. Concurrent use of gold and silver as money, which gold and silver are used concurrently, to the gold 2. Free minting and melting of both metals, standard. Bryan lost, and in 1900 a law was passed and firmly committing the United States to the gold stan- 3. A constant exchange rate between gold and dard. The bimetallic controversy soon died away. The silver coins. United States had taken the yellow brick road. Condition 1 usually means that both gold and In this article, I recount the historical background silver coins are unlimited legal tender. Any limitation to the bimetallic controversy, replacing it in its inter- national context. Bimetallism, which until 1873 had been the system in a number of other countries, dis- François R. Velde is a senior economist in the Economic Research Department at the Federal Reserve Bank of appeared abruptly. I use a model to understand how Chicago. bimetallism could have been viable in the first place, 42 2Q/2002, Economic Perspectives on the size of debts that can be paid in coins of either with limited success. The way this was done was by metal is therefore a departure from condition 1. assigning a legal tender or face value to each coin. All three characteristics should be present to The government assigns a number N to coin i, such i have a proper bimetallic system. For example, condi- that coin i is legal tender for a debt of N units of ac- i tions 1 and 2 alone define a regime where one metal count. Often, N = 1 for some particular coin j, and that j is the standard (say, silver) and the price of the gold coin was by definition the unit of account. For a long coin is not fixed, but varies according to the market. time, governments had difficulties enforcing these laws, The fluctuating coin is called trade money. Conditions and market rates between two coins often diverged far 1 and 3 alone, but with only one metal freely minted, from the ratio of their legal tender values. Neverthe- result in a limping standard. It is similar to a single less, governments kept trying, and by the eighteenth standard based on the metal freely minted, except that century it was commonly seen as a desirable goal to some portion of the money stock is made up of the achieve stability in the relative price between the ob- other metal. The government regulates the size of that jects that served as money, so that it might not matter portion. A number of countries moved from a bime- which ones were used in payment of an obligation. By tallic to a limping standard, as we shall see later. 1800, enough stability had been achieved that denomi- Bimetallism used coins of silver and coins of gold nations could be inscribed on the coins with increasing with a fixed exchange rate between the two. For ex- frequency. But the stability had not necessarily been ex- ample, the gold eagle and the silver dollar were ex- tended to the whole range of coins, including silver and pected to circulate at a rate of 10:1 (10 silver dollars gold. In practice, a variety of monetary systems exist- for one gold eagle), and the values $10 and $1 were ed in Europe by the middle of the nineteenth century: inscribed on the coins themselves. Moreover, anyone I Gold in Great Britain, Portugal, and some could take any amount of silver to the mint in exchange colonies; for $1 coins and any amount of gold in exchange for I Silver in Central and Eastern Europe and the $10 coins.2 East (India, China), with gold as trade money Let X be the amount of gold in a gold eagle, and in some countries (Netherlands, Germany); and Y the amount of silver in a silver dollar. If both coins circulate, then, as money, X ounces of gold are worth I Bimetallism in France, Latin America (with a 10Y ounces of silver. The ratio (10Y/X) is called the 15.5 legal ratio), and U.S. (with a 16 legal ratio). (goldsilver) legal ratio. In the United States, after 1834, an eagle contained 232 grains3 of pure gold, while The controversy a dollar contained 371.25 grains of pure silver, so the Bimetallism became controversial in the mid- legal ratio was 16. The relative price of gold and sil- nineteenth century and remained so until around 1900. ver as metals in the market is called the market ratio. I first describe the nature of the controversy and then sketch its history. The history The controversy around bimetallism ultimately We are so used to our current system of fiat money, stems from the fact that it is a system that appears to where the only thing that matters about a coin or a defy economic logic. One of the textbook functions of note is the number inscribed on it, that it takes a slight money is to provide a unit of account and a standard effort to think of money in earlier times.4 of deferred payment. Accounts are kept in dollars, and In the Middle Ages, various objects were used as debt contracts promise payment of a known quantity money: round disks made of gold, silver, and copper of dollars. Thus, money serves as numeraire. The (or silver alloyed with copper). These disks had designs gold standard is a straightforward example, because on them by which one could determine where they a dollar is simply defined to be X ounces of gold. came from and how much metal they contained. But In reality, then, it is gold that is used as a numeraire. they did not have any numbers or other quantitative This poses no particular problem in economic theory. indication of value. And, in fact, the exchange rates In equilibrium, prices are determined as a vector, or between these objects were not necessarily constant. list of numbers, that sets the sum of excess demands One should think of such a system as one in which for each good to zero (or clears markets). Since noth- various goods are simultaneously used as means of ing changes when all units are consistently changed exchange, because some are more suited to certain by a given number, the price vector is indeterminate transactions than others. up to a constant rescaling. Any good (gold, say) can For a long time, governments endeavored to stabi- be chosen to be the unit of measurement of value, by lize the relation between the various monetary objects, setting the price of X ounces conventionally to one. All Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 43 prices in the economy are thus expressed in ounces The bimetallic camp argued that the system, far of gold or gold dollars.5 from degenerating into an alternation between stan- But bimetallism is something else: It defines the dards, could successfully maintain gold and silver in dollar to be X ounces of gold or Y ounces of silver.
Recommended publications
  • A Model of Bimetallism
    Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department A Model of Bimetallism François R. Velde and Warren E. Weber Working Paper 588 August 1998 ABSTRACT Bimetallism has been the subject of considerable debate: Was it a viable monetary system? Was it a de- sirable system? In our model, the (exogenous and stochastic) amount of each metal can be split between monetary uses to satisfy a cash-in-advance constraint, and nonmonetary uses in which the stock of un- coined metal yields utility. The ratio of the monies in the cash-in-advance constraint is endogenous. Bi- metallism is feasible: we find a continuum of steady states (in the certainty case) indexed by the constant exchange rate of the monies; we also prove existence for a range of fixed exchange rates in the stochastic version. Bimetallism does not appear desirable on a welfare basis: among steady states, we prove that welfare under monometallism is higher than under any bimetallic equilibrium. We compute welfare and the variance of the price level under a variety of regimes (bimetallism, monometallism with and without trade money) and find that bimetallism can significantly stabilize the price level, depending on the covari- ance between the shocks to the supplies of metals. Keywords: bimetallism, monometallism, double standard, commodity money *Velde, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago; Weber, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and University of Minne- sota. We thank without implicating Marc Flandreau, Ed Green, Angela Redish, and Tom Sargent. The views ex- pressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, the Fed- eral Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, or the Federal Reserve System.
    [Show full text]
  • Virtual Currencies in the Eurosystem: Challenges Ahead
    STUDY Requested by the ECON committee Virtual currencies in the Eurosystem: challenges ahead Monetary Dialogue July 2018 Policy Department for Economic, Scientific and Quality of Life Policies Authors: Rosa María LASTRA, Jason Grant ALLEN Directorate-General for Internal Policies EN PE 619.020 – July 2018 Virtual currencies in the Eurosystem: challenges ahead Monetary Dialogue July 2018 Abstract Speculation on Bitcoin, the evolution of money in the digital age, and the underlying blockchain technology are attracting growing interest. In the context of the Eurosystem, this briefing paper analyses the legal nature of privately issued virtual currencies (VCs), the implications of VCs for central bank’s monetary policy and monopoly of note issue, and the risks for the financial system at large. The paper also considers some of the proposals concerning central bank issued virtual currencies. This document was provided by Policy Department A at the request of the Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs. This document was requested by the European Parliament's Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs. AUTHORS Rosa María LASTRA, Centre for Commercial Law Studies, Queen Mary University of London Jason Grant ALLEN, Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin Centre for British Studies, University of New South Wales Centre for Law Markets and Regulation ADMINISTRATOR RESPONSIBLE Dario PATERNOSTER EDITORIAL ASSISTANT Janetta CUJKOVA LINGUISTIC VERSIONS Original: EN ABOUT THE EDITOR Policy departments provide in-house and external expertise to support EP committees
    [Show full text]
  • Final Years of the Silver Standard in Mexico: Evidence of Purchasing Power Parity with the United States
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive Final Years of the Silver Standard in Mexico: Evidence of Purchasing Power Parity with The United States Bojanic, Antonio N. 2 May 2011 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/45535/ MPRA Paper No. 45535, posted 27 Mar 2013 02:12 UTC final years of the silver standard in mexico: evidence of purchasing power parity with the united states Antonio N. Bojanic* Professor of Economics / CENTRUM – Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú Urbanización – Los Alamos de Monterrico – Surco, Perú ABSTRACT RESUMO This paper focuses on the use of silver as Este artigo enfoca o uso da prata como padrão a monetary standard in Mexico during monetário no México, durante aproximada- approximately the last three decades of the mente as três últimas décadas do século XIX nineteenth century and the first decade of e primeira década do século XX. Durante the twentieth century. During this period, esse período, vários eventos ocorreram no several events occurred in the market for mercado de prata, que afetaram os países silver that affected those countries attached atrelados a este metal. Estes eventos causa- to this metal. These events caused some ram alguns destes países a abandonar a prata of these countries to abandon silver for para o bem e adotar outros tipos de regime good and adopt other types of monetary monetário. México e alguns outros, preferiu arrangements. Mexico and a few others ficar com ele. As razões desta decisão são chose to stay with it.The reasons behind this analisados. Além disso prova, que apoia a decision are analyzed. Additionally, evidence teoria da paridade do poder de compra entre that supports the theory of purchasing power o México e os Estados Unidos são também parity between Mexico and the United States apresentados e analisados.
    [Show full text]
  • [ 543 ] V.—The Case for Bimetallism. by Joseph John Murphy. THE
    1891.] [ 543 ] V.—The Case for Bimetallism. By Joseph John Murphy. [Read Tuesday, 14th April, 1891.] THE question which this essay is an attempt to answer, may be thus expressed :—What would be the effect on prices, and on the financial and industrial interests of the world in general, if the leading nations of the world were to agree to make both gold and silver unlimited legal tender at the ratio of value between the two that prevailed during the seventy years which closed with 1873 >— namely, 15-5- ozs. silver as in France, or 16 ozs. as in the United States, equal to one oz. of gold ;—at the same time opening their mints to the unlimited and gratuitous coinage of both metals 1 The statistical data used in the present attempt to answer this question, are taken from the " Final Report of the Royal Com- mission, appointed to enquire into the recent changes in the relative values of the precious metals, 1888." The reply to such a question must of necessity be somewhat in- definite. The laws of political economy are laws of tendency only, though they are mathematical in their certainty, and almost mathe- matical in their nature; yet, as in many branches of physical science, we can predict the general character and the direction of the effects of given causes, but not their magnitude. In a word, their cer- tainty does not ensure precision. Before endeavouring to reply to this question, much preliminary exposition will be required. We do not, however, propose to begin at the very beginning of the theory of money.
    [Show full text]
  • Monetization of Fiscal Deficits and COVID-19: a Primer
    The Journal of Financial Crises Volume 2 Issue 4 2020 Monetization of Fiscal Deficits and COVID-19: A Primer Aidan Lawson Financial Stability Institute, Bank for International Settlements Greg Feldberg Yale University Follow this and additional works at: https://elischolar.library.yale.edu/journal-of-financial-crises Part of the Economic Policy Commons, Finance Commons, Finance and Financial Management Commons, Other Economics Commons, and the Public Administration Commons Recommended Citation Lawson, Aidan and Feldberg, Greg (2020) "Monetization of Fiscal Deficits and COVID-19: A Primer," The Journal of Financial Crises: Vol. 2 : Iss. 4, 1-35. Available at: https://elischolar.library.yale.edu/journal-of-financial-crises/vol2/iss4/1 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Journal of Financial Crises and EliScholar – A Digital Platform for Scholarly Publishing at Yale. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Monetization of Fiscal Deficits and COVID-19: A Primer Aidan Lawson† Greg Feldberg‡ ABSTRACT Monetization—also known as “money-financed fiscal programs” or “money-printing”— occurs when a government finances itself by issuing currency or other non-interest-bearing liabilities, such as bank reserves. It poses real risks—potentially excessive inflation and encroachment on central-bank independence—and some paint it as a relic of a bygone era. The onset of the COVID-19 crisis, however, forced governments to spend heavily to combat the considerable economic and public health impacts. As government deficits climbed, monetization re-entered the conversation as a way to avoid the massive debt burdens that some nations may face. This paper describes how monetization works, provides key historical examples, and examines recent central-bank measures.
    [Show full text]
  • The Ontology of Money and Other Economic Phenomena. Dan
    Economic Reality: The Ontology of Money and Other Economic Phenomena. Dan Fitzpatrick PhD Thesis Department of Philosophy, Logic and Scientific Method London School of Economics. 1 UMI Number: U198904 All rights reserved INFORMATION TO ALL USERS The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted. In the unlikely event that the author did not send a complete manuscript and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if material had to be removed, a note will indicate the deletion. Dissertation Publishing UMI U198904 Published by ProQuest LLC 2014. Copyright in the Dissertation held by the Author. Microform Edition © ProQuest LLC. All rights reserved. This work is protected against unauthorized copying under Title 17, United States Code. ProQuest LLC 789 East Eisenhower Parkway P.O. Box 1346 Ann Arbor, Ml 48106-1346 TH f , s*’- ^ h %U.Oi+. <9 Librw<V Brittsn utxwy Oi HouUco. J and Eoonowc Science m >Tiir I Abstract The contemporary academic disciplines of Philosophy and Economics by and large do not concern themselves with questions pertaining to the ontology of economic reality; by economic reality I mean the kinds of economic phenomena that people encounter on a daily basis, the central ones being economic transactions, money, prices, goods and services. Economic phenomena also include other aspects of economic reality such as economic agents, (including corporations, individual producers and consumers), commodity markets, banks, investments, jobs and production. My investigation of the ontology of economic phenomena begins with a critical examination of the accounts of theorists and philosophers from the past, including Plato, Aristotle, Locke, Berkeley, Hume, Marx, Simmel and Menger.
    [Show full text]
  • Is Monetary Financing Inflationary? a Case Study of the Canadian Economy, 1935–75
    Working Paper No. 848 Is Monetary Financing Inflationary? A Case Study of the Canadian Economy, 1935–75 by Josh Ryan-Collins* Associate Director Economy and Finance Program The New Economics Foundation October 2015 * Visiting Fellow, University of Southampton, Centre for Banking, Finance and Sustainable Development, Southampton Business School, Building 2, Southampton SO17 1TR, [email protected]; Associate Director, Economy and Finance Programme, The New Economics Foundation (NEF), 10 Salamanca Place, London SE1 7HB, [email protected]. The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute scholars and conference participants. The purpose of the series is to disseminate ideas to and elicit comments from academics and professionals. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, founded in 1986, is a nonprofit, nonpartisan, independently funded research organization devoted to public service. Through scholarship and economic research it generates viable, effective public policy responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in the United States and abroad. Levy Economics Institute P.O. Box 5000 Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000 http://www.levyinstitute.org Copyright © Levy Economics Institute 2015 All rights reserved ISSN 1547-366X ABSTRACT Historically high levels of private and public debt coupled with already very low short-term interest rates appear to limit the options for stimulative monetary policy in many advanced economies today. One option that has not yet been considered is monetary financing by central banks to boost demand and/or relieve debt burdens. We find little empirical evidence to support the standard objection to such policies: that they will lead to uncontrollable inflation.
    [Show full text]
  • Hong Kong's Currency Board and Changing Monetary Regimes
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HONG KONG’S CURRENCY BOARD AND CHANGING MONETARY REGIMES Yum K. Kwan Francis T. Lui Working Paper 5723 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 August 1996 This paper was presented at NBER’s East Asian Seminar on Economics, and the NBER conference “Universities Research Conference on the Determination of Exchange Rates.” This work is part of NBER’s project on International Capital Flows which receives support from the Center for International Political Economy. We are grateful to the Center for International Political Economy for the support of this project and to Barry Eichengreen and Zhaoyong Zhang for helpful and constructive comments. Any opinions expressed are those of the authors and not those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. O 1996 by Yum K. Kwan and Francis T. Lui. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including @ notice, is given to the source. NBER Working Paper 5723 August 1996 HONG KONG’S CURRENCY BOARD AND CHANGING MONETARY REGIMES ABSTRACT The paper discusses the historical background and institutional details of Hong Kong’s currency board. We argue that its experience provides a good opportunity to test the macroeconomic implications of the currency board regime. Using the method of Blanchard and Quah (1989), we show that the parameters of the structural equations and the characteristics of supply and demand shocks have significantly changed since adopting the regime. Variance decomposition and impulse response analyses indicate Hong Kong’s currency board is less susceptible to supply shocks, but demand shocks can cause greater short-term volatility under the system.
    [Show full text]
  • International Bimetallism
    STATEMENT RESPECTING THE WORK OF THE RECENT INTERNATIONAL BIMETALLIC COMh!ISSION HON.EDWARD 0.WOLCOTTa I I OF COLORADO, IN THE SENATE OF THE UNITED STATES, JANUARY 17, 1898. P WASHINGTON. 1898. r .C m: e* 4'~tatementRespecting the Work of the Recent Internationel Bimetallic Conkmission, BY I4UN. EDWAED 0. WOLGOTT, OF COLORADO, INTIIE SENATEOF TIIE UNITEDSTATES, Jaizunry 17, 1538. Mr. WOLCOTT s3id: Mr. PRESIDENT:In the statement which I am glad to make respecting certain phases of the work of the recent bimetallic com- mission. I must s-vealc, of course, entirely unoficiallv and as not committing my associates in the slightest degree &ither to my opinions or deductions. Later in the session we are certain to have ample discussion on the subject of silver, and it will proba- bly be acrid and bitter enough. In my remarks to-day, however, I mean to avoid, as far as possible, anything which may give rise to controversy, and while the account of our negotiations must necsssarily seem bare and colorless, the subject of them is one of surpassing interest and importance to every member of the Senate and to every citizen of our country. When Congress met a year ago, soon after the national election, there was a universal expression by the Republican membei-ship &nthe Senate that the pledge of the party in its St. Louis platform to promote international bimetallism by every aeans in its power was an undertaking to be faithfully carried out without evasion or delay. As a result of this sentiment, and growing out of the action of the Republican menibers of the Senate, I spent the monthsof Jan- uary and February last in London and Paris, with a day or two at Berlin, inquiring unofficially as to the apparent prospects of securing bimetallism by international agreement.
    [Show full text]
  • Hindrances to the Acceptance of Bimetallism Author(S): R
    Hindrances to the Acceptance of Bimetallism Author(s): R. H. Inglis Palgrave Source: The Economic Journal, Vol. 4, No. 13 (Mar., 1894), pp. 165-168 Published by: Wiley on behalf of the Royal Economic Society Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2955888 Accessed: 28-06-2016 00:44 UTC Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://about.jstor.org/terms JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Royal Economic Society, Wiley are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Economic Journal This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Tue, 28 Jun 2016 00:44:14 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms HINDRANCES TO THE ACCEPTANCE OF BIMETALLISM 165 Now my contention was and is that, though there be a common cause it need not ' show itself in all or nearly all I the commodities quoted.' To take a new example, for which the data happen to be ready to hand; suppose that the average height of a regiment of 1,000 Italian recruits selected indiscriminately from all the provinces was returned as half an inch in excess of the average height of the whole army; one might infer with certainty that the difference was due to a real cause (as distinguished from chance); and that cause might well be ' single,' such as the circumstance that the men in the regiment were (contrary to the general practice) measured with their shoes on.
    [Show full text]
  • By “Fancy Or Agreement”: Locke's Theory of Money and the Justice of the Global Monetary System
    Erasmus Journal for Philosophy and Economics, Volume 6, Issue 1, Spring 2013, pp. 49-81. http://ejpe.org/pdf/6-1-art-3.pdf By “fancy or agreement”: Locke’s theory of money and the justice of the global monetary system LUCA J. UBERTI American University in Kosovo Rochester Institute of Technology Abstract: Locke argues that the consent of market participants to the introduction of money justifies the economic inequalities resulting from monetarization. This paper shows that Locke’s argument fails to justify such inequalities. My critique proceeds in two parts. Regarding the consequences of the consent to money, neo-Lockeans wrongly take consent to justify inequalities in the original appropriation of land. In contrast, I defend the view that consent can only justify inequalities resulting directly from monetized commercial exchange. Secondly, regarding the nature of consent, neo-Lockeans uncritically accept Locke’s account of money as a natural institution. In contrast, I argue that money is an irreducibly political institution and that monetary economies cannot develop in the state of nature. My political account of money has far-reaching implications for the normative analysis of the global monetary system and the justification of the economic inequalities consequent upon it. Keywords: Locke, metallism, chartalism, consent, equality, global monetary system JEL Classification: B11, E42, Z10 The extent to which Locke’s principles of justice (or ‘Law of Nature’) justifies permissible material inequalities is a long-standing terrain of contention in the neo-Lockean tradition. While some critics (e.g., left- libertarians) have argued that the way Locke’s law regulates original resource appropriation contains extensive egalitarian provisions (Vallentyne, et al.
    [Show full text]
  • Rules Versus Discretion at the Federal Reserve: on to the Second Century
    Rules versus Discretion at the Federal Reserve: On to the Second Century The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Friedman, Benjamin Morton. 2012. Rules versus discretion at the Federal Reserve System: On to the second century. Journal of Macroeconomics 34(3): 608-615. Published Version dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2012.05.009 Citable link http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:10886842 Terms of Use This article was downloaded from Harvard University’s DASH repository, and is made available under the terms and conditions applicable to Open Access Policy Articles, as set forth at http:// nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:dash.current.terms-of- use#OAP For: Journal of Macroeconomics April, 2012 RULES VERSUS DISCRETION AT THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM: ON TO THE SECOND CENTURY Benjamin M. Friedman Harvard University A look back over the soon-to-be-completed first century of the U.S. Federal Reserve System immediately highlights the continuing importance of a fundamental tension: between the desire, often on different grounds in diverse quarters, for rule-based policymaking, and the practicalities that, inevitably or not, lead central bankers to preserve an essential role for discretion in actual policy decisions. Such key episodes during this hundred years as the initial debate over the new central bank’s structure, the exploration of how it might conduct open market operations and the creation of the Federal Open Market Committee, the confused
    [Show full text]