Enterprise-Based Public Finance: Blending the Old and the New

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Enterprise-Based Public Finance: Blending the Old and the New PUBLIC CHOICE E POLITICAL ECONOMY I fondamenti positivi della teoria di finanza pubblica XXI Pavia, Università, 24-25 settembre 2009 CONFERENZA ENTERPRISE-BASED PUBLIC FINANCE: BLENDING THE OLD AND THE NEW GIUSEPPE EUSEPI and RICHARD E. WAGNER società italiana di economia pubblica dipartimento di economia pubblica e territoriale – università di Pavia Enterprise-based Public Finance: Blending the Old and the New Giuseppe Eusepi Department of Public Economics Sapienza University of Rome Via del Castro Laurenziano, 9 00161 Rome ITALY Email: [email protected] http://www.eco.uniroma1.it http://w3.uniroma1.it/ecspc/ and Richard E. Wagner Department of Economics, 3G4 George Mason University Fairfax, VA 22030 USA Email: [email protected] http://mason.gmu.edu/~rwagner Abstract This paper seeks to overcome a deep antinomy within the theory of public finance: while market outcomes are treated as resulting from polycentric competition, political outcomes are treated as resulting from hierarchic planning. We seek to overcome this antinomy by treating political outcomes as likewise resulting from polycentric competition, taking due account of relevant institutional differences. For example, a parliamentary assembly is treated as a peculiar form of investment bank: a parliament intermediates between the sponsors of enterprises and those within the citizenry who have means to support those enterprises. What results is a theory in which budgets emerge in largely bottom-up fashion through complex networks of exchanges. Much of the inspiration for this paper arises from the Italian School of Public Finance, particularly Giovanni Montemartini, Maffeo Pantaleoni and, in more general terms, Antonio De Viti de Marco. Keywords: political pricing, political-economic interaction, polycentric politics, economic calculation, emergence, spontaneous order, order vs. organization JEL Codes: D2, D7, H1, H7 This article was written under the aegis of the European Center for the Study of Public Choice while Richard E. Wagner was a visiting fellow at Sapienza University of Rome May-June 2009. Enterprise-based Public Finance: Blending the Old and the New There is a theoretical antinomy with respect to the treatment of polity and economy within the theory of public finance. Economy is treated as an order (Hayek 1973) which is organized through polycentric processes of competition. In contrast, polity is treated as an organization, a gigantic one to be sure, that imposes teleologically-guided planning onto what otherwise would have been market-generated outcomes. The relation between market and state is thus sequential, with state’s acting in light of given market outcomes. Our alternative research program seeks to eliminate this antinomy by treating polity from the same scholarly orientation as economists treat economy. As an order, polity contains many organizations within its precincts, and with those organizations interacting both among themselves and with various organizations organized within economy. The relation between market and state is thus simultaneous, with mutual interactions operating in both directions. While all organizations are oriented teleologically through plans, the resulting order emerges spontaneously through interaction among participants. Within polity there is no one organization that denotes polity, for polity is plural and not singular with respect to its organizational pattern. Neither a president nor a parliamentary assembly represent a polity but rather denote particular organizations within polity. For instance, we treat a parliamentary assembly as a peculiar form of investment bank that operates inside a polity: people come to a parliament to secure support for the enterprises they are sponsoring, and 2 parliament intermediates between the sponsors of those enterprises and those among the citizenry who have means to support those enterprises. That those who have the means are often forced investors is what makes parliament a peculiar and not a regular form of investment bank. This analytical framework treats budgetary configurations as emerging in largely bottom-up fashion through complex networks of transactions, in contrast to the typical top-down framework of contemporary political economy. The core of this theoretical effort entails dissolution of the theoretical antinomy within the orthodox model of political economy. It should be noted that this antinomy was recognized long ago in Paul Samuelson’s (1954)(1955) formulations of the theory of public goods, where he noted the institutional disjuncture between polity and economy. Subsequent work has not bridged that disjuncture but has evaded it through making claims about demand revelation. The most common evasion in this respect is the claim that an election selects the set of policies that maximizes utility for the median voter, as illustrated nicely by Persson and Tabellini (2000). Dissolution of this theoretical antinomy requires an alternative framework where both policy and economy contain numerous enterprises, each teleologically oriented, and that all such enterprises operate within a non-teleological order where organizational actions are framed by constitutive rules. The earlier portions of this paper explain the theoretical distinction between these alternative orientations toward political economy; the later portions explore some possible avenues for pursuing an integrated, order- based orientation toward the material of public finance. 3 Society as an Emergent and Entangled Ecology of Enterprises The conventional polarization leads theoretical thought astray by ignoring the ecological nature of human enterprise. A society contains an entangled set of enterprises, some commercial and others political. Those enterprises don’t operate independently of one another in separate ponds of activity. They are entangled in a complex human ecology. Prices emerge through commerce, which is possible only with alienable property. Economists study how alienable property promotes social cooperation through competition among commercial enterprises. Complex forms of social organization are made possible by the information that is created by the market prices that arise from commercial transactions. Those prices provide navigational aids that promote the growth of complex commercial ecologies. These could never have arisen without private property. If anyone doubts this, just compare South and North Korea now or West and East Germany 20 years ago. Market-based cooperation, however, is only part of the story of social cooperation. A complete story requires political enterprises to be brought into the picture. Suppose you stay at a resort and rent a boat at a nearby marina. These activities are organized by businesses. But you travel between the resort and the marina over roads that are built and maintained by governments. Moreover, the marina may be adjacent to the mouth of a river that requires dredging by some government agency to remain usable. Your activities rely upon cooperation and coordination throughout an array of enterprises, private and public. 4 Within the complexity of modern societies, that ecology must necessarily rest heavily on alienable private property. Hence, commercial enterprises occupy the foreground and political enterprises the background of a healthy social ecology. The value of a marina, and of commercial activity generally, is determined directly by the willingness of people to support the marina. The value of the highways and the dredging that support the marina, and of political activity generally, are subordinate to and derived from the desires for the marina. People don’t support dredging services for their own sake, but do so only in consequence of their desire to visit the marina; the demand for collective services is derived from the demand for market services. All theories of public finance treat the economy as a complex organism that is self-organized through interaction among people in the presence of private property. To say something like “the market works” is to engage in metaphorical and not material speech. There is no market that does anything. “Market” is an abstract noun that is used to denote processes of commercial interaction. When it comes to polity, however, fiscal theorists typically treat the state as some optimizing entity. This is the state as a mechanic who tunes the social engine.1 To be sure, the literature contains extensive debates over how competent the mechanic-state might actually be, but those debates occur within the presumed antinomy between polity and economy. The alternative orientation public finance that we pursue here rejects this antinomy by treating political entities as operating on the same plane as 1For presentations of this orientation, see Barzel (2002), Drazen (2000), and Persson and Tabellini (2000). 5 economic entities. The polity, just like the economy, contains multiple participants who differ both in what they know and in what they desire and yet who operate within the same social order. It is just as metaphorical to assert that the state does something as it is to assert that the market does something. What we denote as state activity, as with market activity, emerges out of complex patterns of interaction. Achieving Coordination: Pricing and Calculation in Political Economy The economic theory of markets treats only a subset of all economic relationships, those that are organized through private property and free exchange. We can use this theory to understand the coordinated network
Recommended publications
  • Classical Liberalism in Italian Economic Thought, from the Time of Unification · Econ Journal Watch : Italy,Classical Liberalis
    Discuss this article at Journaltalk: http://journaltalk.net/articles/5933 ECON JOURNAL WATCH 14(1) January 2017: 22–54 Classical Liberalism in Italian Economic Thought, from the Time of Unification Alberto Mingardi1 LINK TO ABSTRACT This paper offers an account of Italians who have advanced liberal ideas and sensibilities, with an emphasis on individual freedom in the marketplace, since the time of Italy’s unification. We should be mindful that Italy has always had a vein of liberal thought. But this gold mine of liberalism was seldom accessed by political actors, and since 1860 liberalism has been but one thin trace in Italy’s mostly illiberal political thought and culture. The leading representatives of Italian liberalism since 1860 are little known internationally, with the exception of Vilfredo Pareto (1848–1923). And yet their work influenced the late James M. Buchanan and the development of public choice economics.2 Scholars such as Bruno Leoni (1913–1967) joined—and influenced— liberals around the world, and they continue to have an impact on Italy today. Besides their scholarship, all the liberal authors mentioned here share a constant willingness to enter the public debate.3 Viewed retrospectively they appear a pugnacious lot, even if not highly successful in influencing public policy. The standout is Luigi Einaudi (1874–1961), at once a scholar and journalist who also became a leading political figure in the period after World War II. 1. Istituto Bruno Leoni, 10123 Turin, Italy. I am grateful to Jane Shaw Stroup for valuable editorial feed- back. I also wish to thank Enrico Colombatto and three anonymous referees for their helpful comments.
    [Show full text]
  • The Reception of Austrian Economics in Italy✩ Antonio Magliuloa,*
    Russian Journal of Economics 4 (2018) 65–86 DOI 10.3897/j.ruje.4.26006 Publication date: 23 April 2018 www.rujec.org The reception of Austrian economics in Italy✩ Antonio Magliuloa,* a University of International Studies, Rome, Italy Abstract Nowadays the Austrian School enjoys high reputation in Italy: books by Mises, Hayek and other Austrian economists are constantly republished and reviewed with great interest, both inside and outside academic circles. The situation was very different decades ago, when just a few Italian economists devoted attention to the Austrian School. This work studies the reception of Austrian Economics in Italy, from the beginning to our days, so as to bring out, by way of comparison, relevant features of Italian economic culture. We will try to offer just an overview of the entire story, in an attempt to provide useful elements for a deeper analysis of further topics and periods. Keywords: Austrian economics, Italian economics, international spread of economic ideas. JEL classification: B13, B19, B25, B29. 1. Introduction One of the great challenges of our time is to better understand the nature of the global society in which we live and discover what exactly allows individuals and countries to cooperate or compete fairly with each other, rather than looking at those different from ourselves as enemies. A key role is played by economic culture, construed as a general vision and perception of one’s own interest in rela- tion to that of other people. Economic culture is the result of a complex process of understanding general and abstract economic principles and adapting them to particular and concrete economic situations.
    [Show full text]
  • The Collected Works of James M. Buchanan Volume 2 Public
    The Collected Works of James M. Buchanan volume 2 Public Principles of Public Debt James M. Buchanan The Collected Works of James M. Buchanan volume 2 Public Principles of Public Debt A Defense and Restatement liberty fund Indianapolis This book is published by Liberty Fund, Inc., a foundation established to encourage study of the ideal of a society of free and responsible individuals. The cuneiform inscription that serves as our logo and as the design motif for our endpapers is the earliest-known written appearance of the word ``freedom'' (amagi), or ``liberty.'' It is taken from a clay document written about 2300 b.c. in the Sumerian city-state of Lagash. q 1999 by Liberty Fund, Inc. All rights reserved Printed in the United States of America First published in 1958 by Richard D. Irwin, Inc. 03 02 01 00 99 c 54321 03 02 01 00 99 p 54321 Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Buchanan, James M. Public principles of public debt. p. cm. Ð (The collected works of James M. Buchanan ; v. 2) Includes bibliographical references and index. isbn 0-86597-215-x (alk. paper). Ð isbn 0-86597-216-8 (pbk. : alk. paper) 1. Debts, Public. I. Title. II. Series: Buchanan, James M. Works. 1999 ; v. 2. hj8015.b8 1999 336.384Ðdc21 98-45533 liberty fund, inc. 8335 Allison Pointe Trail, Suite 300 Indianapolis, IN 46250-1684 ``I ®nd little use for the hypothesis that error becomes truth merely by long or consistent practice.'' ÐHenry Simons, ``On Debt Policy'' ``I must confess, that there is a strange supineness, from long custom, creeped into all ranks of men, with regard to public debts, not unlike what divines so vehemently complain of with regard to their religious doctrines.'' ÐDavid Hume, ``Of Public Credit'' Contents Foreword xi Preface xvii 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Philosophy and Science in Gramsci's Reconstruction
    PHILOSOPHY AND SCIENCE IN GRAMSCI’S RECONSTRUCTION OF MARXISM Alessandro Olsaretti Department of Sociology McGill University, Montreal July 2013 A thesis submitted to McGill University in partial fulfillment of the requirements of the degree of Doctor of Philosophy © Alessandro Olsaretti, 2013 CONTENTS (GENERAL): Abstract (English) 4 Abstract (French) 5 Acknowledgements 6 Introduction 7 THE PHILOSOPHY OF PRAXIS 1 – Philosophy, Intellectuals and Hegemony 38 2 – Practical Activity 76 3 – Human Nature 107 THE THEORY OF SCIENCE 4 – Natural Science 133 5 – Economics 165 6 – Political Science 199 Conclusions 243 Bibliographic Note 249 Bibliography 251 1 CONTENTS (DETAILED): Introduction 7 THE PHILOSOPHY OF PRAXIS 1 – Philosophy, Intellectuals and Hegemony 38 1.1 – The Development of the Notes on Philosophy I: Pre­Prison Antecedents 42 1.2 – The Development of the Notes on Philosophy II: the Miscellaneous Notebooks 45 1.3 – The Development of the Notes on Philosophy III: the Thematic Notebooks 49 1.4 – Philosophy and Intellectuals I: The Double Revision of Marxism 56 1.5 – Philosophy and Intellectuals II: the Success of Idealism 59 1.6 – Philosophy and Intellectuals III: the Intellectuals­Masses Dialectic 62 1.7 – Philosophy and Hegemony I: The Critique of Common Sense 65 1.8 – Philosophy and Hegemony II: The Critique of Implicit Philosophy 68 1.9 – Philosophy and Hegemony III: The Critical Conception of the World 71 Conclusion 74 2 – Practical Activity 76 2.1 – The Development of the Notes on Praxis 80 2.2 – Praxis as The Foundation of a Concrete
    [Show full text]
  • Public Choice and the Diffusion of Classic Italian Public Finance1 Richard E. Wagner the Period Roughly Bounded by 1880 and 1940
    Public Choice and the Diffusion of Classic Italian Public Finance1 Richard E. Wagner The period roughly bounded by 1880 and 1940 was one of great flourishing for Italian scholarship on public finance. Had George Shackle not already preempted the term, this period could well be designated the “Years of High Theory” for Italian public finance. During this period, Italian scholars created a unique theoretical orientation toward public finance. They treated public finance not just as one specialized field among several within economics, but as an independent object of study, partly in economics but also concerned with politics, law, and administration as well. In this integrated approach to public finance, the Italian scholars are reminiscent of the Cameralists, who likewise developed an integrated approach to public finance in the Germanic lands between roughly 1500 and 1850.2 The Italian orientation diffused only slowly and incompletely into Anglo- Saxon public finance. This slow diffusion was doubtless due partly to the language barrier. Even to this day, very little Italian public finance has been translated into English, with Buchanan (1960) being the only major secondary treatment. But it is more than language that slowed the diffusion of this tradition. The intellectual orientation of Italian public finance also surely slowed its diffusion. That orientation clashed sharply with the dominant orientation of Anglo-Saxon public finance. It took the development of public choice theorizing starting in the 1960s to prepare the intellectual climate for a more favorable reception for the classic Italian themes in public finance. Public choice theory has been the primary intellectual vehicle by which Italian public finance has diffused into Anglo-Saxon public finance, and the intellectual fortunes of the two are tied closely together.
    [Show full text]
  • Austerity and Repressive Politics: Italian Economists in the Early Years of the Fascist Government
    LEMLEM WORKING PAPER SERIES Austerity and Repressive Politics: Italian Economists in the Early Years of the Fascist Government Clara E. Mattei ° ° Institue of Economics, Scuola Superiore Sant'Anna, Pisa, Italy 2015/17 June 2015 ISSN (online) 2284-0400 Austerity and Repressive Politics: Italian Economists in the Early Years of the Fascist Government Clara Elisabetta Mattei1 Scuola Superiore Sant'Anna, Institute of Economics. The historical forerunners of contemporary austerity are still largely unexplored. This essay considers the “liberal phase” of Fascist Italy (1922-1925) as a case study to explain austerity as a full-blown rationality, that is intrinsically, and simultaneously, theory and practice, encompassing the moral, the economic and the political. My explanation moves beyond the interpretation of austerity as the post-1980, neoliberal recipe of price deflation and budget cuts. The Italian case draws attention to a neglected connection: that between austerity and repression. Austerity was the guiding principle of the Fascist economic agenda during the 1920s. It served to extinguish the effects of the democratization process of the post-WWI years. The paper examines the work of four distinguished economists, Maffeo Pantaleoni, Luigi Einaudi, Alberto De Stefani and Umberto Ricci, who - in different roles as professors, journalists, advisors, and policy-makers – can be considered the source, the guardians and the enforcers of Fascist austerity. Key Words: Austerity, Repressive Politics, Economists as Consultants, Fascism. JEL Classification: B 41, N 44, N 14, B 13 Acknowledgments I would like to thank Giovanni Dosi, Alessandro Nuvolari, Pierluigi Ciocca, Claude Diebolt, George Peden, Anwar Shaikh and Adam Tooze for all their valuable ideas in developing and improving this project.
    [Show full text]
  • Preliminary Draft Only Neoliberalism, Governance and The
    Preliminary Draft Only Neoliberalism, Governance and the Washington Consensus: Empirics and Principles1 Michael Tribe Honorary Lecturer, Department of Economics, University of Strathclyde and Business School Affiliate, University of Glasgow Abstract This paper aims to critically review the principles of ‘neoliberalism’ in the context of the Washington Consensus and of empirical measures of governance. Particular attention will be given to the establishment of a working definition of Neoliberalism, and to a comparison between these principles and the content of Williamson’s (1990) original articulation of the ‘Washington Consensus’ and with Rodrik’s (2006) ‘augmented Washington Consensus’. Burnside and Dollar (2000) focussed on the importance of the ‘policy environment’ for good economic performance. Their definition of the policy environment is discussed in the context of neo-liberal principles. Later studies which followed up Burnside and Dollar have used complex indicators rather than a custom-selected set of variables to represent the ‘quality’ of the policy environment. Since the early 2000s an increasing number of indicators have become available relating to the ‘measurement’ of good governance, and these are widely used as a basis for policy decisions including allocation of Official Development Assistance to recipient developing countries. Some Governance Indicators will be critically compared with the principles of the Washington Consensus and of Neoliberalism in order to assess the extent to which the indicators implicitly embrace these principles. Published values for some of the indicators will be compared for countries with contrasting experiences, particularly focussing on sub- Saharan Africa but also extending the comparison to a number of developed and developing countries from other continents.
    [Show full text]
  • Vilfredo Pareto's Contribution to a Sociology of Globalization
    Chapter 3 Vilfredo Pareto’s Contribution to a Sociology of Globalization Emanuela Susca Introduction Regardless of his much-discussed links with early Italian fascism (Barbieri, 2003), Vilfredo Pareto was not a nationalist social thinker. On the contrary, his sociology can be seen as a significant stage of the theoretical course leading sociologists beyond the provincial and ethnocentric approach nowadays called “methodological nationalism.” My contribution will try to show this by focus- ing on the circumstances of Pareto’s life that may reveal his personal attitude, on his use of universalistic sociological categories and, most of all, on his detailed analysis of the historical happenings of his times. As, unlike many commentators, I do not believe that the Paretian writings are disorganized or tediously prolix, I will quote directly from Pareto on several occasions. I hope to illustrate how Pareto managed to be at times powerfully immediate and at other times sarcastically sharp and, more generally speaking, the reasons why his sociological work is still worth revisiting almost a century after his death. Aiming for a “Cosmopolitan Vision” Although generally considered one of the Italian “founding fathers” of sociol- ogy, Pareto was born in Paris, where his father was in exile because of his radical political ideals. The Marquis Raffaele Pareto was a republican supporter of Mazzini who wanted to call his only son “Wilfrid” in honour of the German Revolution of 1848 and probably as a reaction against the comparative inactiv- ity of the Italian bourgeoisie of his times. Pareto’s mother was a French woman named Marie Méténier. The other two most important women in his life were not Italian either: his first wife Alessandra Bakunin was Russian, while his sec- ond wife, Jeanne Régis, was from Paris.
    [Show full text]
  • Neoliberalism and For-Profit Universities: the Case of Laureate International
    Neoliberalism and For-Profit Universities: The Case of Laureate International Kiev Antonio Ariza Garcia PhD University of York Management September 2018 Abstract For-profit universities are growing in importance as alternative providers in higher education. This thesis analyses structural changes in the configuration of global higher education systems, particularly where states have instrumented neoliberal policies, thus modifying traditional social structures and the meaning of the public good. Moreover, I describe existing global trends in higher education and explore the implications of neoliberalism in higher education. Adopting a qualitative positivist research strategy, I conduct a case study approach of an American multinational corporation with four units of analysis and using interviews with Laureate staff and higher education analysts (n=35) and documents as primary evidence, I drew my findings using thematic analysis. The thesis contributes to an emerging body of scholarly research about for-profit universities and multinational corporations investing in global higher education. Analysis indicates that the for-profit universities’ operational efficiency and strategic flexibility contributes to the reproduction of neoliberalism in higher education in the search for institutional legitimacy and that this is achieved through multiple strategic collaborations with public and private institutions. The profit motive is not only an ideological driver for the reproduction of neoliberalism in academia, but often a starting point in the
    [Show full text]
  • Austerity and Repressive Politics: Italian Economists in the Early Years of the Fascist Government
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Mattei, Clara Elisabetta Working Paper Austerity and repressive politics: Italian economists in the early years of the fascist government LEM Working Paper Series, No. 2015/17 Provided in Cooperation with: Laboratory of Economics and Management (LEM), Sant'Anna School of Advanced Studies Suggested Citation: Mattei, Clara Elisabetta (2015) : Austerity and repressive politics: Italian economists in the early years of the fascist government, LEM Working Paper Series, No. 2015/17, Scuola Superiore Sant'Anna, Laboratory of Economics and Management (LEM), Pisa This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/119862 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu LEMLEM WORKING PAPER SERIES Austerity and Repressive Politics: Italian Economists in the Early Years of the Fascist Government Clara E.
    [Show full text]
  • Italians and the Invention of Race: the Poetics and Politics of Difference in the Struggle Over Libya, 1890-1913
    Italians and the Invention of Race: The Poetics and Politics of Difference in the Struggle over Libya, 1890-1913 Lucia Re 1. Race and Italian identity The manifestations of racism and xenophobia in Italy since the 1990s, especially in response to the new waves of immigration from “the other side” of the Mediterranean, have prompted scholars and cultural critics to take up once again the question of the role of race in Italian history. 1 Once thought to be only a temporary aberration of the Fascist era and essentially alien to the Italian “character,” racism has emerged as a recurrent trait in the behavior and cultural assumptions of Italians, including some of its most prominent political leaders. It is a trait that can arguably be traced back to the nineteenth century, even before the country’s unification. 2 The myth of the “good Italian” finally seems to have crumbled, while race-oriented studies have started to unveil an Italian “tradition” of racism that most textbook accounts of Italian history had long obfuscated or entirely elided. Yet even as racism re-emerges, and is sanctioned by discriminatory laws and policies against immigrants, current political discourse continues to minimize it, while downplaying or denying the historic faults of Italian colonialism and resuscitating the proverbial myth of Italian kindness and moral superiority. 3 The contemporary 1 This study is part of a book in progress about Italy and Africa in the modern and modernist Italian literary imagination and cultural identity, from d’Annunzio to Ennio Flaiano’s Tempo di uccidere (1947). I would like to thank the anonymous peer-review readers of this study for their useful comments.
    [Show full text]