Energy Externality and the Economy of Switzerland

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Energy Externality and the Economy of Switzerland 409 Energy Externality and the Economy of Switzerland by Gonzague Pillet and Howard T.Odum, Gainesville Fla. 1. Presentation In the economic literature an externality is any effect caused by market decision­ making, but all benefits and costs regarding the community and the environment are not taken into account in the setting up of market equilibrium and in the definition of its optimality. However, these external economies or diseconomies can be inter­ nalized either through bargaining, tax, or subsidy. In general, such externalities are priced and a new market equilibrium is set up. Now if we go further and look at externalities that are not merely market and micro external effects, but joint productions of goods and "bads" parallel to econ­ omic production in general, their internalization has to be formulated in another way. Any attempt at internalizing these effects gives rise to "new" goods such as clean water and air, free space, or healthy environment, all entities we cannot easily price. Unlike micro market externalities those externalities now look like public goods or bads whose typical features have to be therefore taken into account. Fi­ nally, this criterion prevents use of the old way of internalizing micro-externalities (Pillet, 1980). Moreover, in order to tell one thing from another, we call these large-scale exter­ nalities, externalities of second generation because they set out effects, which not only deal with market decision-makers, but strictly speaking have their origin out­ side of the economic sphere. They really are energy flows that come in from outside and go out into a used form after having done useful work. Classic externalities had their causes and effects in the market-place. Now externalities of second generation have their sources outside the market circle but have effects on the general course of the economy of a country. So we may stress that they are literally external effects. As a result, if we want to deal with externalities of second generation, we have to pro­ ceed both on an economic and on an eco-energetic scale. It is with the intention of acquiring a better understanding of this ecoenergetic- type externality that a concept of energy externality has been considered regarding energy analysis (Odum, 1971,1976,1983; Pillet, 1983). The part this concept has to play at the interface between ecoenergetics and economics is to evaluate external environmental effects upon the economic sphere. By extension it is concerned with economic impacts upon environment. In general, this is a key principle regarding economics of the environment. On a macro-level, such an energy externality analysis takes place in an energy an­ alysis "overview" of a nation, the task in this paper. Therefore, according to energy Schweiz. Zeitschrift für Volkswirtschaft und Statistik, Heft 3/1984 410 systems procedure (Odum, Odum et al., 1983) we try here to draw a somewhat novel energetic overview of the Swiss economy, featuring its typical energy externality. This study is in three parts. The first one deals with the concept of Energy Externality by means of different "cas défigure." In addition, it presents the energy language concerned with the study of Energetics, Environment, and Economics. The second part gives practice in understanding energy analysis procedure as a contribution to the economic internalization of energy externalities. According to the above analysis, part three delivers an overview of the Swiss economy regarding its external energy basis. This part concentrates on some of the important means of achieving an evaluation of the energy externality at the inter­ face between environment, energetics, and economics. 2. Energy Externality Unlike market externalities, which are potentially internal to revised market deci­ sions, externalities of second generation are real edge effects. Their main character­ istic is to be a flow that comes in through a source from outside the main economy and goes out into a used degraded form through the heat sink. In addition, external­ ities cannot be appropriated through a price-oriented system. Therefore, we cannot place cash value on air, water, open space and even human life from an economic point of view in order to "internalize" either external contribution from the environ­ ment or negative economic impact upon it. Energy externalities, as far as they are externalities of second generation are to be neither internalized nor priced. Market prices deal with human service only, not with environmental service. They need to be evaluated on a macro level both from an indépendant point of view (i. e. from out­ side the price-circle) and from an economic one. In this sense, energy externality is the proportion of economic work ultimately caused from outside without any pric­ ing process, in other words through pathways of action that are indirect and even unrecognized. For example, the price paid for the raw material does not take into ac­ count the contribution of renewable or nonrenewable sources, and of the environ­ mental system. However, from the point of view of the interface between energetics and economics, such a contribution is an effective one. Finally, evaluating energy externalities may give us a better understanding regarding evaluations of environ­ mental contributions or effects on dollar economy as well as a better understanding of environmental economics on a macroeconomic level. (1) Energy Externality as a Concept The real basis of the economic systems is outside the price circle. On one hand, such an externality is concerned with sources of energy. On the other hand, energy 411 as a property of all other flows is the common denominator for evaluating the re­ source basis for economies. At this interface the keyword is therefore "work." In order to keep our attention fixed on energy externality sources let us first con­ sider energy analysis and consequently the interface word "work." Earlier efforts to use energy and work as a value measure were not very successful because energy of various types were regarded as equivalent, whereas energies of different types do not accomplish similar work. However, by converting all types of energy into equivalent units of one type of energy, that of sunlight, various environ­ mental goods and economic commodities may be compared on an equivalent abil­ ity-to-do-work at the interface between systems of humanity and nature1. There­ fore, speaking about energy externalities does not mean speaking about one typical kind of energy as economists often do regarding only high quality energy products like fuel, but it means considering many kinds of energy flows, from the low quality to the high quality ones. It means considering environmental contributions to the main economy on an equivalent ability-to-do-work. Hence, we can emphasize two points about energy externalities as follows: as a general construction, energy externalities are concerned with all kinds of external contributions to the main economy from the environment; as a concept, energy ex­ ternality deals with the evaluation by means of indices and ratios, of such contribu­ tions or of economic miscontributions regarding the environment. (2) Energy Systems Analysis The study of energy externalities deals with Energy Systems Analysis, which is the process of representing a system, such as a nation, with a network diagram in which the pathways are flows of energy and the pathway connections represent pro­ cesses and entities of the system. With a special set of symbols that have mathemati­ cal and energy meanings, the energy network diagram shows in overview the way energy sources generate work processes and the workings of the economies of the nation at the interface with its environmental partner. Evaluating the energy flows of principal pathways provides quantitative measures of the energy-economic sys­ tem2. (3) Energy Language Symbols An overview of a nation is facilitated by diagrams that show energy basis, causal relationships, parts, sources, and hierarchical relationships. Energy language sym­ bols used by Odum (1971,1972,1983) are given here in Table 2.1. Drawn on the left of a diagram are abundant forms of low quality whereas high quality forms of en- 1 For more elaborate discussions of the historical roots of these energy theories of value that were continued by M.Boltzmann and A. P. Lotka, see recent review by Odum (1983). 2 For more elaboration, see Odum (1983) and Odum, Odum et al. (1983). 412 Table 2.1: Symbols of the energy language used to represent national systems in overview (Odum, 1983) . Energy circuit. A pathway whose flow is proportional to the quantity in the storage or source upstream. /^N Source. Outside source of energy delivering forces according to a program controlled V^/ from outside; a forcing function. Tank. A compartment of energy storage within the system storing a quantity as the balance of inflows and outflows; a state variable. Heat sink. Dispersion of potential energy into heat that accompanies all real trans­ formation processes and storages; loss of potential energy from further use by the T system. Interaction. Interactive intersection of two pathways coupled to produce an outflow in proportion to a function of both; control action of one flow on another; limiting factor action; work gate. Consumer. Unit that transforms energy quality, stores it, and feeds it back autocatal- ytically to improve inflow. -> Switching action. A symbol that indicates one or more switching actions. Producer. Unit that collects and transforms low-quality energy under control interac­ tions of high-quality flows. X Self-limiting energy receiver. A unit that has a self-limiting output when input drives are high because there is a limiting constant quantity of material reacting on a circu­ •p- lar pathway within. Box. Miscellaneous symbol to use for whatever unit or function is labeled. 1 S Constant-gain amplifier. A unit that delivers an output in proportion to the input / but changed by a constant factor as long as the energy source S is sufficient.
Recommended publications
  • Economic-Environmental Indicators to Support Investment Decisions: a Focus on the Buildings’ End-Of-Life Stage
    buildings Article Economic-Environmental Indicators to Support Investment Decisions: A Focus on the Buildings’ End-of-Life Stage Elena Fregonara *, Roberto Giordano ID , Diego Giuseppe Ferrando and Sara Pattono Architecture and Design Department, Politecnico di Torino, 10125 Turin, Italy; [email protected] (R.G.); [email protected] (D.G.F.); [email protected] (S.P.) * Correspondence: [email protected]; Tel.: +39-011-090-6432 Received: 29 May 2017; Accepted: 18 July 2017; Published: 21 July 2017 Abstract: The aim of this paper is to propose a methodology for supporting decision making in design activities; in case of new projects or retrofitting of existing buildings. A multidisciplinary approach is adopted; involving Real Estate Appraisal and Economic Evaluation of Project and Building Environmental Design. It is proposed a methodology for selecting the preferable solutions among technological options; considering both economic and environmental aspects; in terms of global performance. Assuming the principles of Life Cycle Thinking and Circular Economy focus is posed at the end-of-life stage. Attention is paid on disposal costs and residual value as relevant items enable to orient investment decisions. This is done through an approach for quantifying environmental indicators related to Life Cycle Assessment (Standard ISO 14040:2006); and economic indicators adopting the Life Cycle Costing (Standard ISO 15686:2008). The paper proposes a conjoint “economic-environmental indicator”. An application of Global Cost calculation is illustrated; including monetized environmental impacts (Embodied energy and Embodied carbon); disposal/dismantling costs and residual value. The result of the Global Cost calculation is expressed through a “synthetic economic-environmental indicator” in order to select; between two different technologies; the most viable solution for a multifunctional building glass façade project; in Northern Italy.
    [Show full text]
  • Detailed Assessment of Embodied Carbon of HVAC Systems for a New Office Building Based on BIM
    sustainability Case Report Detailed Assessment of Embodied Carbon of HVAC Systems for a New Office Building Based on BIM Christina Kiamili 1, Alexander Hollberg 2 and Guillaume Habert 1,* 1 Chair of Sustainable Construction, Institute of Construction and Infrastructure Management, Swiss Federal Institute of Technology (ETH), Stefano Franscini Platz 5, 8093 Zurich, Switzerland; [email protected] 2 Research Group Sustainable Building, Division of Building Technology, Department of Architecture and Civil Engineering, Chalmers University of Technology, 41296 Gothenburg, Sweden; [email protected] * Correspondence: [email protected] Received: 2 March 2020; Accepted: 16 April 2020; Published: 21 April 2020 Abstract: The global shift towards embodied carbon reduction in the building sector has indicated the need for a detailed analysis of environmental impacts across the whole lifecycle of buildings. The environmental impact of heating, ventilation, and air conditioning (HVAC) systems has rarely been studied in detail. Most of the published studies are based on assumptions and rule of thumb techniques. In this study, the requirements and methods to perform a detailed life cycle assessment (LCA) for HVAC systems based on building information modelling (BIM) are assessed and framed for the first time. The approach of linking external product data information to objects using visual programming language (VPL) is tested, and its benefits over the existing workflows are presented. The detailed BIM model of a newly built office building in Switzerland is used as a case study. In addition, detailed project documentation is used to ensure the plausibility of the calculated impact. The LCA results show that the embodied impact of the HVAC systems is three times higher than the targets provided by the Swiss Energy Efficiency Path (SIA 2040).
    [Show full text]
  • Download the Course
    Architecture Climate Change & Society Buell Center 2020 Course Development Prize Sara Stevens, Adam Rysanek, and Kees Lokman University of British Columbia CHANGING MINDS FOR A CHANGING CLIMATE Co-taught by a historian, a landscape architect, and a building scientist, this course proposes that design thinking has the potential to reframe the wicked problem of climate change. Weekly structured debates will pose provocations based on a set of historical and contemporary episodes and contested landscapes that position the designer in relation to societal change. Students assignments (Debate, Review, Conceive, and Impact) will analyze case studies in order to reimagine the relationship between design and climate change. Divided into modules that highlight different perspectives, the class will include lectures, workshops, and collective assignments intended to produce a small exhibition. Columbia University’s Temple Hoyne Buell Center for the Study of American Architecture Association of Collegiate Schools of Architecture Changing Minds for a Changing Climate Proposal for a graduate course in architecture, landscape architecture, and urban design Sara Stevens / Adam Rysanek / Kees Lokman School of Architecture and Landscape Architecture, University of British Columbia, Vancouver “If you care about the planet, and about the people and animals who live on it, there are two ways to think about [climate change]. You can keep on hoping that catastrophe is preventable, and feel ever more frustrated or enraged by the world’s inaction. Or you can accept that disaster is coming, and begin to rethink what it means to have hope.” — Jonathan Franzen, “What If We Stopped Pretending?” New Yorker, 8 September 2019 Franzen frames the problem of the climate apocalypse by pointing out the misalignment of rhetoric (stop climate change!) and evidence (it’s unstoppable!).
    [Show full text]
  • 46 Post-Growth Economics
    46 POST-GROWTH ECONOMICS Niko Paech Introduction Today’s sustainability concepts are mostly based on ecological modernisation. Modern societies follow this trend and tend to shift the necessity of changing their consumption habits to a point later in time, or even deny the necessity of change completely. This is based on the hope that technological progress can solve the sustainability problem without having to go through difficult changes in lifestyle and a moderation of consumption habits. However, many of those ‘Green’ innovations intensify material and energy overexploitation by making use of previously unspoilt landscapes and untouched resources. As long as decoupling by technological means turns out to be impossible, sustainable development can only be understood as a programme for economic reduction rather than conjuring Green Growth solutions. In this chapter I will explore an alternative to this popularised approach. That is a world that no longer clings to the growth imperative and makes the post-growth economy its goal. I start by defining what is meant by post-growth economics and how it has developed. This is followed by an exploration of the case for limits to growth and why decoupling runs into problems, including the rebound effect. I then outline some key aspects of a post-growth economy, before briefly identifying future directions and finishing with some concluding remarks. The development and meaning of post-growth economics Development of post-growth economics The terms post-growth economics (as an analytical framework) and post-growth economies (as a concrete draft for the future) arose in debates over sustainability held at Carl von Ossietzky University in Oldenburg during 2006.
    [Show full text]
  • IZA Discussion Paper No. 154 May 2000
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Lechner, Michael; Gerfin, Michael Working Paper Microeconometric Evaluation of the Active Labour Market Policy in Switzerland IZA Discussion Papers, No. 154 Provided in Cooperation with: IZA – Institute of Labor Economics Suggested Citation: Lechner, Michael; Gerfin, Michael (2000) : Microeconometric Evaluation of the Active Labour Market Policy in Switzerland, IZA Discussion Papers, No. 154, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), Bonn This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/20997 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially
    [Show full text]
  • Marxism and Ecological Economics
    Marxism and Ecological Economics Toward a Red and Green Political Economy by Paul Burkett BRILL LEIDEN • BOSTON 2006 Contents Preface .............................................................................................................. vii Introduction .................................................................................................... 1 Chapter One The Value Problem in Ecological Economics: Lessons from the Physiocrats and Marx ................................................ 16 Chapter Two Values in Ecological Value Analysis: What Should We Be Learning from Contingent Valuation Studies? ........................ 56 Chapter Three Natural Capital in Ecological Economics .................... 93 Chapter Four Marxism and the Resistance to Natural Capital .......... 115 Chapter Five Entropy in Ecological Economics: A Marxist Intervention .............................................................................. 142 Chapter Six Energy, Entropy and Classical Marxism: Debunking the Podolinsky Myth ............................................................ 174 Chapter Seven Power Inequality and the Environment ...................... 208 Chapter Eight Sraffian Models of Ecological Conflict and Crisis ...... 220 Chapter Nine Towards a Marxist Approach to Ecological Conflicts and Crises .................................................................................................... 260 vi • Contents Chapter Ten Marxism, Ecological Economics, and Sustainable Human Development ...............................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Growth and Structural Change in China•S Energy Economy
    ARTICLE IN PRESS Energy xxx (2009) 1–10 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Energy journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/energy Growth and structural change in China’s energy economy Fredrich Kahrl a, David Roland-Holst b,* a Energy and Resources Group, University of California, Berkeley, CA, USA b Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of California, Berkeley, CA, USA article info abstract Article history: China has been the world’s most vibrant economy and its largest source of energy demand growth over Received 12 September 2007 the past two decades, accounting for more than one-quarter of net growth in global primary energy Received in revised form consumption from 1980 to 2005. To sustain economic growth and rising living standards, China needs 20 March 2009 effective policies that anticipate and shape the country’s future energy requirements. In this paper, we Accepted 21 March 2009 examine China’s national economic and energy accounts over the past decade for insights into changing Available online xxx energy use patterns and their relationship to economic structure. Our results indicate that incipient structural changes in the Chinese energy economy and sustained economic and energy demand growth Keywords: China in China will pose important, and different, challenges for policymakers. Chinese economy Ó 2008 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. Chinese energy use Energy intensity 1. Growth and structural change in China’s energy economy exports rising to near parity with domestic household consumption in 2006 (Fig. 2). In short, a significant portion of China’s post-2001 The Chinese economy’s energy needs have increased dramati- GDP growth has been driven by investment and export growth.
    [Show full text]
  • Regional Analysis of Tourism. Central and Eastern Europe
    Knowledge Horizons - Economics Volume 10, No. 2, pp. 46 – 58 , © 2018 Pro Universitaria “Dimitrie Cantemir” Christian University Knowledge Horizons - Economics Volume 10, No. 2, pp. 46 - 58 P-ISSN: 2069-0932, E-ISSN: 2066-1061 © 2018 Pro Universitaria www.orizonturi.ucdc.ro REGIONAL ANALYSIS OF TOURISM. CENTRAL AND EASTERN EUROPE Gabriela STANCIULESCU1, Elisabeta MOLNAR2 1PhD, Bucharest University of Economic Studies, E-mail: [email protected] 2PhD, Bucharest University of Economic Studies, E-mail: [email protected] Abstract The intensification of globalization brings to the forefront the role of the regions in economic Key words: growth, regions which are considered to be active and causal elements of economic development. Tourism, Regional These are considered places where the most advanced forms of economic development and development, innovation are concentrated. Economic Local (regional) economic development is defined by increases in the local (regional) development, CEE economy's capacity to create wealth for residents of the respective region or locality. These increases countries can occur if local resources, such as labor and land, are used more productively, or if the increase in JEL Codes: employment determines the use of labor force and land previously not being used (Camarda, 2008). Z30 Because the local level is defined in a more or less comprehensive manner, even the concept Q26 of local development has narrower or broader meanings. Thus, the concept of local economic M2 development means "the process of diversification and development of economic and social activity O52 at the level of a locality or a smaller territorial-administrative entity” (Profiroiu, Racoviceanu and Țarălungă, 1998, pp.8-16).
    [Show full text]
  • Historical and Critical Review on Biophysical Economics 1
    July 21, 2016 9:55 WSPC/S1793-0480 204-BRL 1630001 Biophysical Reviews and Letters Vol. 11, No. 2 (2016) 63–86 c World Scientific Publishing Company DOI: 10.1142/S1793048016300012 Historical and Critical Review on Biophysical Economics Yekbun Adig¨uzel Department of Biophysics, School of Medicine Istanbul Kemerburgaz University Kartaltepe Mah. Incirli Cad. No:11 Bakirkoy, Istanbul, Turkey [email protected] Received 18 March 2016 Revised 25 April 2016 Accepted 3 May 2016 Published 21 July 2016 Biophysical economics is initiated with the long history of the relation of economics with ecological basis and biophysical perspectives of the physiocrats. It inherently has social, economic, biological, environmental, natural, physical, and scientific grounds. Biological entities in economy like the resources, consumers, populations, and parts of production systems, etc. could all be dealt by biophysical economics. Considering this wide scope, current work is a “biophysical economics at a glance” rather than a comprehensive review of the full range of topics that may just be adequately covered in a book-length work. However, the sense of its wide range of applications is aimed to be provided to the reader in this work. Here, modern approaches and biophysical growth theory are pre- sented after the long history and an overview of the concepts in biophysical economics. Examples of the recent studies are provided at the end with discussions. This review is also related to the work by Cleveland, “Biophysical Economics: From Physiocracy to Ecological Economics and Industrial Ecology” [C. J. Cleveland, in Advances in Bioeconomics and Sustainability: Essay in Honor of Nicholas Gerogescu-Roegen,eds.
    [Show full text]
  • Net Zero Is Not a Choice but an Ethical Practice – Evolution of Net Zero Building
    170 Ecological Ethics (and the Role of the Architect) Net Zero Is Not A Choice But An Ethical Practice – Evolution Of Net Zero Building MING HU University of Maryland Buildings are responsible for approximately one-third of There is large gap between 1930 to 1970. The only mentionable worldwide carbon emissions and account for over 40 percent development is the “Technical Alliance.” A group of architects, of primary energy consumption globally. High-performance engineers, economists, and ecologists formed a professional building design has become an overarching goal for the building group named the “Technical Alliance” in 1919 and disbanded and construction industry. The important and trendy domains in 1921. It started an Energy Survey of North America with an in the built environment are the “resilience” and “net zero” aim to document the wastefulness of the entire society, which associated with high-performance design that have their origin is the first attempt to quantify “net energy” [2]. in ecology. The performance of building and energy efficiency is one of the common measuring indexes accepted by multiple In the 1970s, Romanian-American mathematician and econo- fields. The ultimate goal of a net zero building has become a mist Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen further developed ecological hot trend, and an off-grid building has become the ultimate economics or eco-economics based on Soddy’s concepts. This “high-performance” standard. The fundamental misleading is a transdisciplinary and interdisciplinary field of research that concept around contemporary net zero buildings is that a net includes ecology, economics, and physics. Georgescu-Roegen zero building is one type of building, one type of design pro- proposed the application of entropy law in the field of econom- cess.
    [Show full text]
  • Doing Business in Switzerland
    Independent legal & accounting firms Doing Business in Switzerland Edition No. 1 / February 2019 Photo credit: Shutterstock MSI Global Alliance Doing business in Switzerland MSI’s guide on Doing Business in Switzerland provides current information about the financial, regulatory and legal considerations that could affect business dealings within Switzerland. For further assistance please contact our MSI member firms in Switzerland. Country overview Bern, Luzern, St Gallen and Lugano. agreements with the European Union, allowing to bridge the differences and to Population Currency protect its businesses. Switzerland is a Switzerland has a total population of The national currency is the Swiss Franc destination of choice for entrepreneurs 8.5 million inhabitants. (CHF). and companies, due to its tax attractiveness and the high flexibility of Government Economic summary its legal system. Despite its official name, the Helvetic GDP: CHF 659 billion Confederation is a federation of Income per capita: CHF 78,700 Setting up a business sovereign states named cantons. Inflation: 0.84% There are 26 cantons, and each of Switzerland represents a highly them is composed of many Main sectors of the economy competitive and innovative business municipalities. The Swiss economy is amongst the most environment. Swiss corporate law prosperous and developed in the world, provides a flexible and a wide range of Switzerland is governed at three despite the lack of raw material and options in designing business entities. If levels: federal, cantonal and access to sea. The unemployment rate is several individuals join together to municipal. The federal capital is structurally low (3.2% in 2017). establish a company, they are obliged to Bern.
    [Show full text]
  • Thermoeconomics
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Research Papers in Economics THERMOECONOMICS A Thermodynamic Approach to Economics John Bryant Third Edition Electronic Version Chapter 9 © VOCAT International Ltd 2012 All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise without the prior permission of the publisher. Published by VOCAT International Ltd 10 Falconers Field Harpenden Herts AL5 3ES UK Third Edition ISBN 978-0-9562975-3-2 The electronic versions of the book chapters are made available free on the website www.vocat.co.uk for personal and educational use only by interested readers. While the author has made every effort to be diligent and accurate in his researches, he cannot be held responsible for the use that readers may make of his work, and they should satisfy themselves as to logic and veracity of the conclusions drawn. Citation for the book: John Bryant. ‘Thermoeconomics – A thermodynamic approach to economics’, VOCAT International Ltd, 2011. ISBN 978-0-9562975-3-2 Contents Preface 1 Introduction 1 1.1 Historical Research 2 1.2 Economics and the Ideal Gas 6 2 Stock and Flow Processes 17 2.1 General Stock Model 19 2.2 Monetary Stock Model 31 2.3 Labour Sector 34 2.4 Stocks of Economic Output 40 2.5 Resource Stocks 46 2.6 Environment Waste Stocks 48 3 Thermodynamic Principles 50 3.1 First Law of Thermodynamics 50 3.2 Second Law of
    [Show full text]