Managing the Agricultural Biotechnology Revolution: Responses to Transgenic Seeds in Developing Countries

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Managing the Agricultural Biotechnology Revolution: Responses to Transgenic Seeds in Developing Countries University of Massachusetts Amherst ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst Doctoral Dissertations Dissertations and Theses July 2016 Managing the Agricultural Biotechnology Revolution: Responses to Transgenic Seeds in Developing Countries Alper Yagci University of Massachusetts Amherst Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.umass.edu/dissertations_2 Part of the Asian Studies Commons, Comparative Politics Commons, Environmental Policy Commons, Environmental Studies Commons, Food Security Commons, Growth and Development Commons, International Relations Commons, Latin American Studies Commons, Politics and Social Change Commons, Public Policy Commons, Quantitative, Qualitative, Comparative, and Historical Methodologies Commons, and the Science and Technology Policy Commons Recommended Citation Yagci, Alper, "Managing the Agricultural Biotechnology Revolution: Responses to Transgenic Seeds in Developing Countries" (2016). Doctoral Dissertations. 703. https://doi.org/10.7275/8420639.0 https://scholarworks.umass.edu/dissertations_2/703 This Open Access Dissertation is brought to you for free and open access by the Dissertations and Theses at ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst. It has been accepted for inclusion in Doctoral Dissertations by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks@UMass Amherst. For more information, please contact [email protected]. MANAGING THE AGRICULTURAL BIOTECHNOLOGY REVOLUTION: RESPONSES TO TRANSGENIC SEEDS IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES A Dissertation Presented by ALPER YAGCI Submitted to the Graduate School of the University of Massachusetts Amherst in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY May 2016 Political Science © Copyright by Alper Yagci 2016 All Rights Reserved MANAGING THE AGRICULTURAL BIOTECHNOLOGY REVOLUTION: RESPONSES TO TRANSGENIC SEEDS IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES A Dissertation Presented by ALPER YAGCI Approved as to style and content by: _________________________________________ Peter M. Haas, Chair _________________________________________ Frederic C. Schaffer, Member _________________________________________ James K. Boyce, Member _________________________________________ Kevin Young, Member _________________________________________ Jane E. Fountain, Department Head Political Science ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I would like to thank my supervisor Peter M. Haas and committee members Frederic C. Schaffer, James K. Boyce, and Kevin Young for inspiring me with their research, putting much trust in me and closely advising the dissertation. The research benefited from National Science Foundation grant 1124079, and a Mellon- ACLS Dissertation Completion Fellowship facilitated writing. Marcos Silveira de Buckeridge, Michelle Chauvet, Roberto Bisang, Sebastian Sztulwark, José Maria da Silveira, Antonio Marcio Buainain, Ricardo Tatesuzi de Sousa, Daniela Aviani, Mehmet Uyanık, Arzu Ünal helped me to understand technical aspects of agricultural biotechnology and related economic issues. Conversations with André Roncaglia de Carvalho and Ceren Soylu gave me ideas about analytical strategies. İlker Yağcı, Martin Rapetti, Hüseyin Şerarettin Suveren, Michael Hannahan provided invaluable help in accessing contacts necessary for the fieldwork. Mere citation would not be enough to acknowledge the generous help of colleagues who shared with me their unpublished work on topics closely related to mine, so special thanks to Felipe Filomeno, Tamara Perelmuter and Barış Gençer Baykan. Filomeno’s 2012 PhD thesis, especially, which I came to know of during my field research, provided me with many leads to follow. Participants to presentations at WZB Berlin Social Science Center, TOBB University of Economics and Technology, Özyeğin University, and Boğaziçi University, especially Michael Zürn, Martin Krzywdinski, Pieter de Wilde, Martijn Mos, Başak Yavcan, Yeşim Arat, Hakan Yılmaz provided excellent feedback. The writing process was facilitated by semester-long visiting scholar positions at WZB Berlin, and Koc University’s GLODEM Institute in Istanbul. iv The Interdisciplinary Institute for Political Economy at the University of Buenos Aires, and the Political Science department of Torcuato di Tella University helped with access to campus facilities. I benefited from the publicly available resources of the universities of São Paulo and Brasília. I accessed Boğaziçi University library as a Boğaziçi graduate. During my studies at UMass Amherst, apart from the members of my dissertation committee, other faculty taught me a lot in their respective fields: Brian Schaffner, Jesse Rhodes, Amel Ahmed, Mohan Rao, Mwangi wa Githinji, Jillian Schwedler, Nick Xenos, Bruce Desmarais. Administrative support provided by Michelle Gonçalvez and Jennie Southgate deserved all praise. Conversations over many years with Mine Eder, Huricihan İslamoğlu, Cem Oyvat, Mert Arslanalp, Aytuğ Şaşmaz, Osman Berker Yağcı, Caterina Scaramelli, Ali Can Yıldırım, Evren Aydoğan, Esra Bakkalbaşıoğlu and Aytekin Ertan contributed to my intellectual development. I was lucky to have Hilal Sweiti as a teacher. Oft-repeated questions from İlker Yağcı, Seref Yağcı and Nurcan Yağcı about what exactly I am doing with my life encouraged me to get work done at a respectable pace. While writing the dissertation I listened to music by the Gotan Project. All remaining mistakes should be attributed to them. v ABSTRACT MANAGING THE AGRICULTURAL BIOTECHNOLOGY REVOLUTION: RESPONSES TO TRANSGENIC SEEDS IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES MAY 2016 ALPER YAGCI, B.A., BOGAZICI UNIVERSITY M.A., BOGAZICI UNIVERSITY Ph.D., UNIVERSITY OF MASSACHUSETTS AMHERST Directed by: Professor Peter M. Haas There has been heated debate over transgenic or genetically modified (GM) crops in agriculture. Advocates and critics argue over possible economic, environmental, public health implications of this technology. This study examines varying policy approaches to regulating GM crop cultivation in four developing countries where the technology has large potential application. Why have some countries banned GM crop cultivation in their territory while others encouraged it? In countries where GM crops were allowed, why have varying systems of intellectual property rights (IPR) protection been constructed? To investigate these questions I comparatively examine the policy experience (1995-2015) of Argentina, Brazil, Turkey relying on original fieldwork and India based on secondary literature. The explanation combines structural considerations with a social constructivist understanding of how actors make use of ideas to interpret and articulate their interests in a context defined by novelty and uncertainty. I find that transnational biotechnology companies lobby developing country governments for permission of GM crop cultivation and strict IPR protection so as to be able to charge the cultivators technology fees. While public opinion tends to be opposed to these crops, associations of big farmers tend to favor their adoption and view the IPR claims by vi biotechnology companies as relatively tolerable. Smaller farmers and domestic seed industry, on the other hand, seek guarantees from the state that technology adoption conditions will not be established to their disadvantage. Which agenda is prioritized in policy-making will depend not only on the political weight of each pressure group but also on the statesmen’s management of the available knowledge on such questions as how the GM plants work, who they are good for, why they may or may not be needed. I observe that coalitions of scientists, civil society activists and pro-active bureaucrats are influential in shaping the policy vision by generating policy knowledge and ideas offering answers to such questions. I call them “epistemic coalitions.” They strategically mix selective scientific evidence with social and ideological narratives, under conditions of incomplete scientific consensus. I demonstrate that GM-skeptic epistemic coalitions can have a good chance at policy influence where the pro-GM producer sector is highly fragmented, but where the producer sector is strong the same opposition can be functional in obtaining a domestic producer- oriented policy by challenging the legitimacy of extensive IPR claims advanced by transnational biotechnology firms. The study thus provides an empirical account of the political reactions provoked, and some of the social-economical outcomes generated, by a controversial agricultural technology. On a theoretical level it contributes to debates in political science about the place of ideas, cognitive frames and social learning in public policy; and advances the epistemic communities research program. vii TABLE OF CONTENTS Page ACKNOWLEDGMENTS ............................................................................................................. iv ABSTRACT .................................................................................................................................. vi LIST OF TABLES ....................................................................................................................... xiii LIST OF FIGURES .......................................................................................................................xv CHAPTER I. INTRODUCTION .......................................................................................................................1 The Question ............................................................................................................................... 1 Why Pursue This Question ........................................................................................................
Recommended publications
  • The Political Economy of Intellectual Property Treaties
    THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY TREATIES Suzanne Scotchmer* National Bureau of Economic Research Cambridge, MA 02138 Working Paper 9114 August 2002, revised January 2003 Abstract: Intellectual property treaties have two main types of provisions: national treatment of foreign inventors, and harmonization of protections. I address the positive question of when countries would want to treat foreign inventors the same as domestic inventors, and how their incentive to do so depends on reciprocity. I also investigate an equilibrium in which regional policy makers choose IP policies that serve regional interests, conditional on each other's policies, and investigate the degree to which \harmonization" can redress the resulting ine±ciencies. *I thank Stylianos Tellis and Kevin Schubert for research assistance, and Brian Wright, Alan Deardor®, Nancy Gallini, Rich Gilbert, Gene Grossman, Mark Lemley, Stephen Maurer, Pam Samuelson, and seminar participants at Industry Canada, Ecole des Mines, and University of Auckland for helpful comments. I thank the National Science Foundation for ¯nancial support. 1 1Introduction The economic rationale for intellectual property (IP) is that it encourages development of new products, and thus generates consumers' surplus. The net pro¯t that accrues to inventors is also a social bene¯t, since it is a transfer from consumers. However pro¯t is recognized as a necessary evil, since the °ip side of pro¯t is deadweight loss. There is no economic rationale for protecting inventors per se. This reasoning gets subverted in the international arena. To a trade policy negotia- tor, pro¯t earned abroad is unambiguously a good thing, and the consumers' surplus conferred on foreign consumers does not count at all.
    [Show full text]
  • 32:1 Berkeley Technology Law Journal
    32:1 BERKELEY TECHNOLOGY LAW JOURNAL 2017 Pages 1 to 310 Berkeley Technology Law Journal Volume 32, Number 1 Production: Produced by members of the Berkeley Technology Law Journal. All editing and layout done using Microsoft Word. Printer: Joe Christensen, Inc., Lincoln, Nebraska. Printed in the U.S.A. The paper used in this publication meets the minimum requirements of American National Standard for Information Sciences—Permanence of Paper for Library Materials, ANSI Z39.48—1984. Copyright © 2017 Regents of the University of California. All Rights Reserved. Berkeley Technology Law Journal University of California School of Law 3 Boalt Hall Berkeley, California 94720-7200 [email protected] http://www.btlj.org BERKELEY TECHNOLOGY LAW JOURNAL VOLUME 32 NUMBER 1 2017 TABLE OF CONTENTS ARTICLES THE “ARTICLE OF MANUFACTURE” IN 1887 .......................................................... 1 Sarah Burstein STANDING AGAINST BAD PATENTS ..................................................................... 87 Sapna Kumar DIVERSIFYING THE DOMAIN NAME GOVERNANCE FRAMEWORK ..................... 137 Alice A. Wang THE DATA-POOLING PROBLEM .......................................................................... 179 Michael Mattioli HOW OFTEN DO NON-PRACTICING ENTITIES WIN PATENT SUITS? ................... 237 John R. Allison, Mark A. Lemley & David L. Schwartz SUBSCRIBER INFORMATION The Berkeley Technology Law Journal (ISSN1086-3818), a continuation of the High Technology Law Journal effective Volume 11, is edited by the students of the University of California, Berkeley, School of Law (Boalt Hall) and is published in print three times each year (March, September, December), with a fourth issue published online only (July), by the Regents of the University of California, Berkeley. Periodicals Postage Rate Paid at Berkeley, CA 94704-9998, and at additional mailing offices. POSTMASTER: Send address changes to Journal Publications, University of California, Berkeley Law—Library, LL123 Boalt Hall—South Addition, Berkeley, CA 94720-7210.
    [Show full text]
  • Intellectual Property's Leviathan
    KAPCZYNSKI_BOOKPROOF (DO NOT DELETE) 12/3/2014 2:10 PM INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY’S LEVIATHAN AMY KAPCZYNSKI* Neoliberalism is a complex, multifaceted concept. As such, it offers many possible points of entry into my primary field of study, that of intellectual property (IP) law. We might begin by investigating tensions between IP law and a purely economic conception of neoliberalism, for example.1 Or we might consider whether or how IP law might be “insulated from democratic governance” while also being rapidly assembled.2 In these few pages, I want to focus instead on a different line of inquiry, one that reveals the powerful grip that one particular neoliberal conception has on our contemporary imaginary: the neoliberal conception of the state. Today, both those who defend robust private IP law and their most prominent critics, I will show, typically describe Copyright © 2014 by Amy Kapczynski. This article is also available at http://lcp.law.duke.edu/. * Associate Professor of Law, Yale Law School. Many thanks to Talha Syed, David Grewal, and Jed Purdy for helpful conversation and comments. This paper is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-Non-Commercial 4.0 International license and should be reproduced as “first published in 77 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS 131 (Fall 2014).” 1. Neoliberalism is commonly understood in economic terms. See, e.g., David Singh Grewal & Jedediah Purdy, Introduction: Law and Neoliberalism, 77 LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS., no. 4, 2014 at 1. David Harvey has argued, however, that neoliberalism as “a political project to re-establish the conditions for capital accumulation and to restore the power of economic elites” tends to prevail over the “economic utopian” conception of neoliberalism.
    [Show full text]
  • Peer Monitoring, Ostracism and the Internalization of Social Norms$
    Peer Monitoring, Ostracism and the Internalization of Social NormsI Rohan Dutta1, David K. Levine2, Salvatore Modica3 Abstract We study the consequences of endogenous social norms that overcome public goods problems by providing incentives through peer monitoring and ostracism. We examine incentives both for producers and for monitors. The theory has applications to organizational design - oering possible explanations for why police are rotated between precincts while professional organizations such as doctors are self-policing. It leads to a Lucas critique for experiments and natural experiments - a small level of intervention may be insucient to produce changes in social norms while a high level of intervention may have a very dierent eect because it becomes desirable to change social norms. Finally we study the internalization of social norms - showing how on the one hand it makes it possible to overcome incentive problems that pure monitoring and punishment cannot, and on the other how it leads to an interesting set of trade-os. We conclude with some discussion of cultural norms where norms are not established benevolently by a particular group for its benet but established by others for their own benet. Keywords: one, two IFirst Version: October 14, 2017. We would like to thank Andrea Mattozzi. We gratefully acknowledge support from the EUI Research Council. ∗Corresponding author David K. Levine, 1 Brooking Dr., St. Louis, MO, USA 63130 Email addresses: [email protected] (Rohan Dutta), [email protected] (David K. Levine), [email protected] (Salvatore Modica) 1Department of Economics, McGill University 2Department of Economics, EUI and WUSTL 3Università di Palermo Preprint submitted to Mimeo: dklevine.com February 19, 2018 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Beithr LATE THAN EARLY: VERTICAL DIFFERENTIATION in the ADOPTION of a NEW TECHNOLOGY
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES BEIThR LATE THAN EARLY: VERTICAL DIFFERENTIATION IN THE ADOPTION OF A NEW TECHNOLOGY Prajit K. Dutta Saul Lach Aldo Rustichini Working Paper No. 4473 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 September 1993 We thank seminar audiences at Chicago, Rochester, Rutgersandthe Game Theory Conference at Stonybrook as well as loannis Benopoulos, Andrew Caplin, Jay P11 Chol, Drew Fudcnberg, Ananth Madhavan, Axle! Pakes, Suzanne Scotchmer and John Sutton for helpful comments. We have also benefitted from the comments of two anonymous referees and a co-editor. The usual disclaimer, unfortunately, applies. Any opinions expressed are those of the authors and not those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER Working Paper #4473 September 1993 BhntR LATE THAN EARLY: VERTICAL DIFFERENTIATION IN THE ADOPTION OF A NEW TECHNOLOGY ABSTRACT After the initial breakthrough in the research phase of R&D a new productundergoes a process of change, improvement and adaptation to market conditions. We model the strategic behavior of fw in this development phase of R&D. We emphasize that a key dimensionto this competition is the innovations that lead to product differentiation and quality improvement. In a duopoly model with a single adoption choice, we derive endogeneously the level and diversity of product innovations. We demonstrate the existence of equilibria in which one firm enters early with a low quality product while the other continues to develop the technology and eventually markets a high quality good. In such an equilibrium, no monopoly rent is dissipated and the later innovator makes more profits.
    [Show full text]
  • With Or Without a Patent?
    JOURNAL OF SMART ECONOMIC GROWTH www.jseg.ro ISSN: 2537-141X Volume 3, Number 1, Year 2018 WHAT KIND OF INTELLECTUAL PROPFRTY REGIME IS MORE FAVORABLE TO INNOVATION: WITH OR WITHOUT A PATENT? Mohamed MABROUKI ISAEG MACMA [email protected] Abstract: Theoretically, the introduction of a patent system serves two purposes: to encourage firms to produce new knowledge and to disseminate information. However, economic practice has highlighted the dilemma between protection and diffusion. In addition, there has been criticism that patents constitute a handicap to research that would result from them and therefore hinder technological progress. Thus, some economists emphasize the preference of secrecy over the patent. Others go even further in criticizing the protection of intellectual property rights and propose the removal of such rights by promoting a world without patents. In this article we will analyze some ideas that do not see the patent as the most effective way to ensure protection, in exchange for a dissemination of knowledge. The authors who defend this position raise the questions: Patents an incentive or brake to innovation? The patent: is it not an unjustifiable property right? JEL classification: O30, O31, O34. Key words: innovation, patent, secret, intellectual property. INTRODUCTION Theoretically, the introduction of a patent system serves two purposes: to encourage firms to produce new knowledge and to disseminate information. However, economic practice has highlighted the dilemma between protection and diffusion. Despite a broad consensus that the patent is essential to spur innovation, there is no consensus on the optimal level of protection across the three dimensions of patents. In addition, there has been criticism that patents constitute a handicap to research that would result from them and therefore hinder technological progress.
    [Show full text]
  • Putting Innovation Incentives Back in the Patent-Antitrust Interface, 11 Nw
    Northwestern Journal of Technology and Intellectual Property Volume 11 | Issue 5 Article 5 2013 Putting Innovation Incentives Back in the Patent- Antitrust Interface Thomas Cheng University of Hong Kong Recommended Citation Thomas Cheng, Putting Innovation Incentives Back in the Patent-Antitrust Interface, 11 Nw. J. Tech. & Intell. Prop. 385 (2013). https://scholarlycommons.law.northwestern.edu/njtip/vol11/iss5/5 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Northwestern Pritzker School of Law Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Northwestern Journal of Technology and Intellectual Property by an authorized editor of Northwestern Pritzker School of Law Scholarly Commons. NORTHWESTERN J O U R N A L OF TECHNOLOGY AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY Putting Innovation Incentives Back in the Patent-Antitrust Interface Thomas Cheng April 2013 VOL. 11, NO. 5 © 2013 by Northwestern University School of Law Northwestern Journal of Technology and Intellectual Property Copyright 2013 by Northwestern University School of Law Volume 11, Number 5 (April 2013) Northwestern Journal of Technology and Intellectual Property Putting Innovation Incentives Back in the Patent-Antitrust Interface By Thomas Cheng* This Article proposes a new approach, the constrained maximization approach, to the patent-antitrust interface. It advocates a return to the utilitarian premise of the patent system, which posits that innovation incentives are preserved so long as the costs of innovation are recovered. While this premise is widely accepted, it is seldom applied by the courts in patent-antitrust cases. The result is that courts and commentators have been overly deferential to dynamic efficiency arguments in defense of patent exploitation practices, and have failed to scrutinize the extent to which patentee reward is genuinely essential to generating innovation incentives.
    [Show full text]
  • ECON 483: Economics of Innovation and Technology University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign College of Liberal Arts & Sciences Department of Economics
    ECON 483: Economics of Innovation and Technology University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign College of Liberal Arts & Sciences Department of Economics Jorge Lemus Spring 2021 ONLINE - Synchronous Tuesday and Thursday: 9:30AM - 10:50AM Communication: E-mail: [email protected] Office Hours: Friday 10:30am-11:30am. Appointment by email required. Catalog Description: Examines the economic factors shaping innovation and technical change since the industrial revolution with emphasis on the economic relationship between science and technology and the role of government in technical change. Credit: 3 undergraduate hours. 2 or 4 graduate hours. Prerequisite: ECON 102 or equivalent; ECON 302 or consent of instructor. Course Description: This course analyzes economics incentives to innovate and create new technology. Starting from the impact of institutions on innovation, the course then focuses on how market power, rewards to innovation, spillovers, and network effects, impact the intensity and direction of inventive activity. Throughout the course, students will be presented with theoretical models and empirical evidence to explore the economic incentives of innovators. The primary tool to analyze firms, consumers and government behavior is game theory. Knowing basic tools from calculus and statistics is required for the class. It is recommended for registered students to be familiar game theory (Nash equilibrium, Subgame Perfect equilibrium). We will devote a couple of lectures to review the basic game-theory concepts, which we will then apply to study strategic interactions in markets for innovation and technology. References (Optional): There is no required textbook. Two good references to complement the class lectures are: The Theory of Industrial Organization. Jean Tirole.
    [Show full text]
  • Firm Choices and Competition
    MSc in Economics Firm Choices and Competition Academic Year: 2018/2019 4th Quarter Instructor: Fernando Branco Contact(s) and Office hours: Email: [email protected] Office hours: TBD. _____________________________________________________________________________ Biography: Fernando Branco, Full professor at Católica-Lisbon School of Business and Economics, PhD in Economics from Massachusetts Institute of Technology, and undergraduate degree in Economics from Católica. He has served as Católica’s Vice-Rector (2004-2006), FCEE’s Dean (2001-2004), and Center for Applied Studies’s Director (1998-2001). He has taught in Católica’s several programs, with courses covering issues in microeconomics, industrial organization, and finance. He regularly advises companies and government agencies in these same areas. His scientific research has focused in topics in the strategic analysis of market, mostly involving auction theory and economics of regulation. ____________________________________________________________________________ Course overview and objectives: This is a course about modelling issues related to firm’s decisions and interactions in markets. The emphasis will be on the analysis and understanding of the models, with a discussion of the role of the assumptions and the development of relevant extensions. Completing this course a student that wants to have a managerial life will be equipped with tools to understand and anticipate competitor’s decisions, while students that want to continue an academic career will be better prepared to take
    [Show full text]
  • Università Degli Studi Di Siena DIPARTIMENTO DI ECONOMIA POLITICA UGO PAGANO MARIA ALESSANDRA ROSSI Incomplete Contracts
    Università degli Studi di Siena DIPARTIMENTO DI ECONOMIA POLITICA UGO PAGANO MARIA ALESSANDRA ROSSI Incomplete Contracts, Intellectual Property and Institutional Complementarities n. 355 – Luglio 2002 Abstract - In the New Property Rights model ownership of assets should be assigned to the most capable agents. While, in a world of incomplete contracts, the application of the model to IPRs provides insights on the nature of their second best allocation, also the opposite direction of causation may arise: owners of IPRs tend to develop more capabilities in the production of new IPRs. For some firms and countries, a virtuous complementarity between the development of IPRs and skills arises. For others the disincentive effect of the exclusion from intellectual property has more damaging consequences than the lack of access to material capital. Keywords: Intellectual Property, Incomplete contracts, Incentives, Efficient Allocation, Institutional Complementarity. JEL Classification: D23, K11, K12, O34 Introduction The New Property Rights approach emphasizes the important economic function of an efficient allocation of property rights over physical assets in a situation of incomplete contractibility. Control of residual rights over physical capital increases the owner’s bargaining power and therefore constitutes a safeguard against the possibility of opportunistic behaviour by other parties. The asset owner will thus have a greater incentive to make unverifiable specific investments in human capital in comparison to other individuals. In this paper we argue that, in many respects, the New Property Rights approach can be better interpreted as a theory of the allocation of intellectual property rights. In this case, ownership of intellectual assets can be allocated – similarly to ownership of physical capital – so as to provide incentives to the realization of the asset-specific investments in human capital that contractual incompleteness tends to reduce.
    [Show full text]
  • Bounded Rationality and the Theory of Property
    ESSAY BOUNDED RATIONALITY AND THE THEORY OF PROPERTY Oren Bar-Gill and Nicola Persico* Abstract Strong, property rule protection – implemented via injunctions, criminal sanctions and supercomepnsatory damages – is a defining aspect of property. What is the theoretical justification for property rule protection? The conventional answer has to do with the alleged shortcomings of the weaker, liability rule alternative: It is widely held that liability rule protection – implemented via compensatory damages – would interfere with efficient exchange and jeopardize the market system. We show that these concerns are overstated and that exchange efficiency generally obtains in a liability rule regime. But only when the parties are perfectly rational. When the standard rationality assumption is replaced with a more realistic, bounded rationality assumption, liability rules no longer support exchange efficiency. Bounded rationality thus emerges as a foundational element in the theory of property. * Bar-Gill: William J. Friedman and Alicia Townsend Friedman Professor of Law and Economics, Harvard Law School (email: [email protected]); Persico: Professor of Managerial Economics and Decision Sciences, Kellogg School of Management (email: [email protected]). We thank Ronen Avraham, Omri Ben-Shahar, Oliver Board, Rick Brooks, Ryan Bubb, Peter DiCola, Richard Epstein, Lee Fennell, Clay Gillette, David Gilo, Howell Jackson, Louis Kaplow, Lewis Kornhauser, Saul Levmore, Anup Malani, Yoram Margalioth, Roger Myerson, Dotan Oliar, Gideon Parchomovsky,
    [Show full text]
  • The Political Economy of Intellectual Property Treaties
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY TREATIES Suzanne Scotchmer Working Paper 9114 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9114 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 August 2002 I thank Stylianos Tellis and Kevin Schubert for research assistance, and Alan Deardorff, Nancy Gallini, Rich Gilbert, Gene Grossman, Jean Lanjouw, Mark Lemley, Stephen Maurer, Pam Samuelson, and seminar participants at Industry Canada and Ecole des Mines for helpful comments. I thank the National Science Foundation for financial support. This paper is a revision of IBER Working paper E01-305 (August 2001). The views expressed herein are those of the author and not necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. © 2002 by Suzanne Scotchmer. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. The Political Economy of Intellectual Property Treaties Suzanne Scotchmer NBER Working Paper No. 9114 August 2002 JEL No. F1, L5 ABSTRACT Intellectual property treaties have two main types of provisions: national treatment of foreign inventors, and harmonization of protections. I address the positive question of when countries would want to treat foreign inventors the same as domestic inventors, and how their incentive to do so depends on reciprocity. I also investigate an equilibrium in which regional policy makers choose IP policies that serve regional interests, conditional on each other's policies. I compare these policies with a notion of what is optimal, and argue that harmonization will involve stronger IP protection than independent choices.
    [Show full text]