The Buck Starts Here: the Federal Reserve and Monetary Politics from World War to Cold War, 1941-1951

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Buck Starts Here: the Federal Reserve and Monetary Politics from World War to Cold War, 1941-1951 THE BUCK STARTS HERE: THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND MONETARY POLITICS FROM WORLD WAR TO COLD WAR, 1941-1951 A dissertation submitted to Kent State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctorate of Philosophy by Timothy W. Wintour December, 2013 Dissertation written by Timothy W. Wintour B.A., Canisius College, 2002 M.A., John Carroll University, 2006 Ph.D., Kent State University, 2013 Approved by __________________________________, Chair, Doctoral Dissertation Committee Mary Ann Heiss __________________________________, Members, Doctoral Dissertation Committee Walter L. Hixson __________________________________, Steven W. Hook __________________________________, Clarence Wunderlin, Jr. __________________________________, Michael Ellis Accepted by __________________________________, Chair, Department of History Kenneth Bindas __________________________________, Associate Dean, College of Arts and Sciences Raymond Craig ii Table of Contents List of Figures…………………………………………………………………………….iv List of Tables……………………………………………………………………………...v Acknowledgments………………..……………………………………………………....vi Introduction……………………………………………………..…..……………………..1 Chapter One: “If We Lose the War We Cannot Save Freedom”: The Federal Reserve and War Finance, 1941-1945.……………………………..……………..………24 Chapter Two: “For a Peaceful and Prosperous World”: The Federal Reserve and the Political Economy of the World Bank, 1942-1945………………………..……..67 Chapter Three: “New Lanes in Uncharted Seas”: The Federal Reserve and International Exchange Stabilization, 1941-1945……………………………..……………...113 Chapter Four: “Messenger Boys” or “Men of Ability”: The Federal Reserve, Foreign Financial Policymaking, and the NAC…………………………………………174 Chapter Five: “No Particular Fear of Russia, Just of Chaos”: The Federal Reserve, Postwar Reconversion, and the British Loan, 1945-1947……...……………….231 Chapter Six: “On the Horns of a Dilemma”: European Reconstruction, the Postwar Economy, and the Federal Reserve, 1946-1950……...……..……………….....305 Chapter Seven: “The Shadow of the Soviets”: Federal Reserve Policy, Korea, and Perpetual Cold War, 1947-1951…………………………………………….....386 Conclusion……………………………………………………………………………...463 Bibliography……………………………………………………………………………469 iii List of Figures 1. Consumer Price Index, 1942-1947…………………………………………………..286 2. Federal Cash Surplus or Deficit for the United States, 1945-1951…………….……372 3. Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers, 1946-1948………………………405 4. Average Open-Market Money Rates in New York City & Bond Yields, 1946- 1951…………………………………………………………………………….410 iv List of Tables 1. External Liabilities of Great Britain…………………………………………………263 2. Proposed Sterling Balance Reductions……………………………………………....264 3. Postwar Pattern of Interest Rates…………………………………………………….393 v Acknowledgments There are innumerable individuals who deserve thanks and a substantial amount of credit for the final completion of this dissertation. I owe an immense debt of gratitude to the members of my dissertation committee. First and foremost, my advisor, Ann Heiss. Her insight, feedback, and patience are present in every facet of the dissertation. Additionally, her keen editing surely saved me from doing irreparable damage to the English language. Clarence Wunderlin provided critical understanding of political ideology, and his willingness to indulge my fascination with political economy offered my important opportunities to broaden my exposure and knowledge. Steven Hook helped me to develop an appreciation for the role of social and ideational forces in the process of foreign policy making. His insights helped me to bridge the gap between the worlds of domestic and foreign policy. From the University of Akron, Walter Hixson’s comments on the nature of the military-industrial complex helped push my thinking in enlightening directions. Each and every one of them deserves far more credit and thanks than I can ever express. There are a number of individuals at Kent State University, the University of Akron, and at various professional organizations who did not serve on my committee but that nevertheless played an important part in my intellectual development. Either in class or in conversation they helped me to broaden my intellectual horizons in new and sometimes unexpected ways. In this way they played an integral role in this dissertation. These people include Rebecca Pulju, Kevin Adams, Stephen Harp, Leonne Hudson, and vi Mark Cassell. I am also grateful to John McNay and Alonzo Hamby. Their thoughtful comments and those of the other conference goers and panelists from the Ohio Academy of History helped clarify and strengthen my thinking at critical points. I also owe a deep debt of gratitude to professors and teachers who helped shape my academic career before I even arrived at Kent State University. Even before my days as an undergraduate at Canisius College in Buffalo, New York through my early graduate work at John Carroll University, I had the privilege of encountering fine scholars and teachers who encouraged my academic aspirations. These include the late Edwin L. Neville and the late J. David Valaik, as well as René de la Pedraja, Maria Marsilli, Robert Kolesar, Daniel Kilbride, and Fr. Lawrence Ober, S.J. As with every other historical inquiry, unnamed and innumerable archivists, librarians, and clerks, through their diligence and dedication deserve great credit. The employees of the National Archives in College Park, Maryland enabled me to tap into a wealth of documentation. I am also immensely indebted to the Federal Reserve System and its dedication to the preservation of historical materials. The Federal Reserve Archival System for Economic Research (FRASER) places a tremendous amount of material right at the fingertips of researchers, and to those unnamed souls who scanned, uploaded, and catalogued vast quantities of material that founds its way into this dissertation you have my everlasting thanks. Friends and family absolutely deserve credit here. My sister, Elizabeth, and my parents, Marcia and William Wintour, encouraged throughout my studies. While my vii mother did not live to see the completion of this work, I know it would not have been possible without her support first in body and then in spirit. The person, however, who deserve the most credit is my wife, Christa Adams. Without her constant and unwavering support this dissertation would never have been completed. She kept me sane in periods of stress and anxiety and supported me in bouts of research and writing. A last word. While many people contributed to and strengthened this dissertation any errors are mine alone. viii Introduction In the aftermath of the First World War, American, British, and French policymakers attempted to create a stable international economic and political order. Unfortunately, that order failed to satisfactorily address a number of potentially destabilizing issues, including harmonizing the restoration of an inherently powerful Germany with French security concerns; establishing a flexible international monetary system to provide the economic stability of the prewar gold standard without the associated rigidity; ensuring American participation in and commitment to the international political and economic order; and resolving postwar German reparations and Allied war debts with the restoration of economic prosperity. The result was an ad hoc political and economic system that survived thanks to the superficial prosperity of the 1920s but ultimately collapsed during the 1930s, leading to the Great Depression. Rejecting the apparent failure of the capitalist democratic model supported by the Western allies, the Axis sought national economic self-sufficiency through the creation of closed economic blocs controlled by totalitarian and autocratic states and secured by powerful military establishments. The failure to conclude the First World War in a manner that secured universal economic prosperity and political peace set the stage for the conflict of the 1940s. The United States entered the Second World War still mired in the economic problems of the Great Depression but emerged from the conflict as the world’s premier 1 2 military and economic power. During the war average weekly wages increased 65-70 percent while corporate profits doubled. The nation controlled half the world’s manufacturing capacity and electrical generation and fully two-thirds of the global gold stock, and it dominated industries from international shipping to the production of petroleum. At the same time, inflation remained relatively in check, with prices rising by roughly 28 percent, compared to the First World War experience of 100 percent.1 Militarily, the nation maintained a monopoly control over the newly developed atomic bomb. This vast national wealth and strength positioned the United States to bear the costs of simultaneously reconstructing the economies of Europe and Asia, restoring a system of relatively free international trade, creating an international monetary system essentially based upon the dollar, and building a defense establishment capable of countering Soviet expansion. Reflecting on the strengths of the United States during the 1940s, the nation’s economic and physical security seems almost inevitable. Such a perspective, however, fails to appreciate the great uncertainty policymakers felt during and after the war. Fear that the United States might sink back into recession or slump under the weight of spiraling price inflation plagued policymakers, including the central
Recommended publications
  • The Region, Vol
    Henry Parker Willis and the Location of the Federal Reserve Districts and the Headquarter Cities By David Hammes, Professor of Economics, University of Hawaii-Hilo 200 W. Kawili Street, Hilo, HI 96720-4091 [email protected] The Federal Reserve Act of 1913 called for dividing the USA into eight to twelve separate Reserve districts to help provide regional and national economic stability. The Committee responsible for designating the districts and headquarter cities made its decision public on April 2, 1914. Since that time, suspicion has been that political influences determined both the number and location of the reserve bank districts and cities. Based on the writings of Henry Parker Willis (1874 – 1937), this paper outlines the process used in 1914 to determine the number and locations of reserve districts and banks. Introduction1 The framers of the Federal Reserve System intended each of the Federal Reserve district banks to play a significant role in regional economic stability. Given changes in legislation (e.g. the Federal Reserve Act of 1935), and the greater mobility of capital, people, and information through time, monetary policy has been centralized in the Board of Governors and 2 Federal Open Market Committee. Public interest in the System has naturally followed the policy-power shift to the Board in Washington, DC. Interest today in the Reserve district banks is often limited to questions such as: ‘Why are there two Federal Reserve banks in the state of Missouri?’ and/or ‘Why are there so many reserve bank cities in the east versus the west?’ Following early commentary the answers are usually attributed to ‘politics’.
    [Show full text]
  • Flemming, Arthur S.: Papers, 1939-1996
    DWIGHT D. EISENHOWER LIBRARY ABILENE, KANSAS FLEMMING, ARTHUR S.: PAPERS, 1939-1996 Accession: 86-18, 97-7, 97-7/1, 99-3 Processed by: DES Date Completed: 2005 On October 23, 1985 Arthur S. Flemming executed an instrument of gift for these papers. Linear feet: 128.8 Approximate number of pages: 254,400 Approximate number of items: Unknown Literary rights in the unpublished papers of Arthur S. Flemming have been transferred to the people of the United States. By agreement with the donor the following classes of documents will be withheld from research use: 1. Papers and other historical material the disclosure of which would constitute an invasion of personal privacy or a libel of a living person. 2. Papers and other historical materials that are specifically authorized under criteria established by statute or Executive Order to be kept secret in the interest of national defense or foreign policy, and are in fact properly classified pursuant to such statute or Executive Order. SCOPE AND CONTENT NOTE The Papers of Arthur S. Flemming were deposited with the Eisenhower Library in two major accessions. The first and largest accession arrived in 1986 and contained materials from Flemming’s early civil service career through the mid-1970s. The second accession arrived in late 1996. It more or less takes up where the first accession leaves off but there are a couple exceptions that must be noted. The second accession contains a few files from the early 1960s, which were probably held back at the time of the first shipment because they were still relevant to Flemming’s activities at the time, namely files related to aging.
    [Show full text]
  • The Great Moderation, the Great Panic and the Great Contraction By
    “The Great Moderation, the Great Panic and the Great Contraction” Speech given by Charles Bean, Deputy Governor for Monetary Policy and Member of the Monetary Policy Committee, Bank of England Given at the Schumpeter Lecture, Annual Congress of the European Economic Association, Barcelona 25 August 2009 I am grateful for the assistance of Adrian Penalver. The views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of either the Bank of England or the Monetary Policy Committee. 1 All speeches are available online at www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Pages/speeches/default.aspx Summary Charles Bean, the Bank of England’s Deputy Governor, Monetary Policy, was invited to deliver the Schumpeter lecture at the Annual Congress of the European Economic Association. The Great Moderation, the Great Panic and the Great Contraction, looks back at the causes of the financial crisis and subsequent recession. He argues that much of what went wrong can be analysed using standard economic tools. The Great Moderation was a period of unusually stable macroeconomic activity in advanced economies. This was partly thanks to good luck, including the integration of emerging market countries into the global economy, and partly a dividend from structural economic changes and better policy frameworks. The longer this stability persisted, the more markets became convinced of its permanence and risk premia became extremely low. Real short and long term interest rates were also low due to a combination of loose monetary policy, particularly in the US, and strong savings rates in a number of surplus countries. Low interest rates and low apparent risk created strong incentives for financial institutions to become highly geared.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Financial and Monetary History of the United States 1700 to 1933
    Financial and Monetary History of the United States 1700 to 1933 Economics 344:01 (Fall 2012) Monday/Thursday 11:30-12:50 Murray 211 Professor Michael D. Bordo Department of Economics New Jersey Hall, Room 304 Rutgers University (732) 932-7363 [email protected] http://econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo Office hours: Mondays 11-12 and Thursday 11-12 or by appointment Prerequisites Econ 320 (Intermediate Microeconomic Analysis) and Econ 321 (Intermediate Macroeconomic Analysis). Money and Banking Econ 301 is recommended. This is an upper level elective course where you are expected to apply the knowledge and expertise that you have gained in the prerequisites. Course Objective The focus of the course is on American Monetary and Financial history. The methodology of the course is to apply modern tools of monetary and macroeconomic theory to important historical issues. The introduction of theoretical tools and historical data can shed new light on controversies of the past and yield new insights for today’s economic problems. Attendance Policy and Academic Integrity Students are expected to attend every class. Attendance is highly correlated with performance in the course. As this is an upper level class I will not take attendance. It is the student’s responsibility to master the course work including the lectures and the readings. As always at Rutgers, you are expected to follow the University’s precepts of academic integrity. ( See http://academicintegrity.rutgers.edu/integrity.shtml). Course Requirements There will be a short research paper of maximum 12 pages, double-spaced including references, tables and figures worth 40% of the grade.
    [Show full text]
  • The Character of Vermont : Twentieth-Anniversary Reflections Michael Sherman
    University of Vermont ScholarWorks @ UVM Center for Research on Vermont Occasional Papers Research Centers and Institutes 1996 The character of Vermont : twentieth-anniversary reflections Michael Sherman Jennie G. Versteeg Samuel B. Hand Paul S. Gillies Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.uvm.edu/crvocc Recommended Citation Sherman, Michael; Versteeg, Jennie G.; Hand, Samuel B.; and Gillies, Paul S., "The character of Vermont : twentieth-anniversary reflections" (1996). Center for Research on Vermont Occasional Papers. 5. https://scholarworks.uvm.edu/crvocc/5 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Research Centers and Institutes at ScholarWorks @ UVM. It has been accepted for inclusion in Center for Research on Vermont Occasional Papers by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks @ UVM. For more information, please contact [email protected]. OCCASIONAL PAPER #19 CENTER FOR RESEARCH ON VERMONT UNIVERSITY OF VERMONT BURLINGTON, VERMONT . ... : . ~.._ - - THE CHARACTER OF VERMONT Twentieth-Anniversary Reflections By MICHAEL SHERMAN and JENNIE VERSTEEG SAMUEL B. HAND and PAUL GILLIES WILB F ,Sfen 19'/b ~ ./ © 1996 by the University of Vermont. All rights reserved ISBN 0-944277-34-9 The Center for Research on Vermont University of Vermont Burlington, VT 05401-3439 802/656-43 89 email: [email protected] ...Wil!Ul CuONiVITi"iT LU CTIO yN J Of V!l!AONT l1 81A!T Contents Foreword Paul Eschholz . v11 Part 1 The Character of Vermont: Then and Now The Character of Vermont: Then and Now Michael Sherman and Jennie Versteeg . 1 Appendix 1. Taylor's "Sample" of Vermonters .............. ... ...... 35 Appendix 2. Taylor's Respondents ...........
    [Show full text]
  • The Tale of Two Great Crises
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Fratianni, Michele; Giri, Federico Working Paper The tale of two great crises FinMaP-Working Paper, No. 51 Provided in Cooperation with: Collaborative EU Project FinMaP - Financial Distortions and Macroeconomic Performance, Kiel University et al. Suggested Citation: Fratianni, Michele; Giri, Federico (2015) : The tale of two great crises, FinMaP-Working Paper, No. 51, Kiel University, FinMaP - Financial Distortions and Macroeconomic Performance, Kiel This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/125823 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu The Tale of Two Great Crises Michele Fratianni∗ Federico Giriy December 14, 2015 Abstract The great depression of 1929 and the great financial crisis of 2008 have been the two big events of the last 75 years.
    [Show full text]
  • What Is Past Is Prologue: the History of the Breakdown of Economic Models Before and During the 2008 Financial Crisis
    McCormac 1 What is Past is Prologue: The History of the Breakdown of Economic Models Before and During the 2008 Financial Crisis By: Ethan McCormac Political Science and History Dual Honors Thesis University of Oregon April 25th, 2016 Reader 1: Gerald Berk Reader 2: Daniel Pope Reader 3: George Sheridan McCormac 2 Introduction: The year 2008, like its predecessor 1929, has established itself in history as synonymous with financial crisis. By December 2008 Lehman Brothers had entered bankruptcy, Bear Sterns had been purchased by JP Morgan Chase, AIG had been taken over by the United States government, trillions of dollars in asset wealth had evaporated and Congress had authorized $700 billion in Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) funds to bailout different parts of the U.S. financial system.1 A debt-deflationary- derivatives crisis had swept away what had been labeled Alan Greenspan’s “Great Moderation” and exposed the cascading weaknesses of the global financial system. What had caused the miscalculated risk-taking and undercapitalization at the core of the system? Part of the answer lies in the economic models adopted by policy makers and investment bankers and the actions they took licensed by the assumptions of these economic models. The result was a risk heavy, undercapitalized, financial system primed for crisis. The spark that ignited this unstable core lay in the pattern of lending. The amount of credit available to homeowners increased while lending standards were reduced in a myopic and ultimately counterproductive credit extension scheme. The result was a Housing Bubble that quickly turned into a derivatives boom of epic proportions.
    [Show full text]
  • 15/13/70 Liberal Arts and Sciences History Council for Basic Education Correspondence, 1956-1965
    The materials listed in this document are available for research at the University of Record Series Number Illinois Archives. For more information, email [email protected] or search http://www.library.illinois.edu/archives/archon for the record series number. 15/13/70 Liberal Arts and Sciences History Council for Basic Education Correspondence, 1956-1965 Box 1: All-An, 1956-57 Allen, Bertha letters - CBE, Life, Nat'l Review Concerning textbook difficulties in Alaska Alsop, Stewart - commendation for publications expressing views concurrent w/CBE Russell, Bertrand - letter written to Mrs. R. W. Angel concerning John Dewey and his ideas Ap-As, 1956-57 Aronfreed, Justin M. - use of quotation Asher, Grant - Arizona curricular study At-Az, 1956-57 Material exchange w/Western Interstate Council for Higher Education B-Ba, 1956-57 Bahm, Archie (U. of New Mexico) - teaching of ethics in high schools and elementary schools Bakeless, John - concerning H. Benjamin and Connecticut school survey Also - criticism of Alexander Stoddard's "Schools for Tomorrow" Original of crayon drawing published in bulletin Barewald, Robert - series of articles in progress Des Moines Register Barkdall, O. R. - Beginning of extended correspondence Barr, Stringfellow - authorization for use of name Barsotti, I. - Italian education Grant from William Volker Fund for foundation of CBE Baxter, Frank (TV Personality) Be-Bel, 1956-57 Bebbington, W. P. - suggestion for use of scientific societies to spread CBE ideas Beecher, Marguerite & Willard - authors of Parents on the Run Beers, Mrs. Edward W. - curriculum problem with "Home and Family Living Course" - Clarence, N. Y. Bem-Ber, 1956-57 Berridge, Ruth Reid - Suggestions for membership Bes-Bl, 1956-57 Biderman, Sol - Ed., Colorado Daily - Concerning series of articles about Dean Harl Douglass of Colorado University School of Education.
    [Show full text]
  • 15876 HON. JOSEPH R. Mccarthy
    15876 CONGRESSIONAl: RECORD;;...:_ SENATE Novemb·er 8 ,Maj. Gen. · Wllltam· ·Evens · Hall,- 460A . Maj. Gen. Lee Bird--Washbourne, 810A - To· be -briga.dier generals- (brigadier general, Regular Air Force) , (colonel, Regular Air- Force), United States - Col; John Colt·Baumont Elliott, 271A, Reg- United States Air Force. · Air Force: · Ular Air Force. - Lt. Gen. Donald Leander Putt, 494A (brig­ Brig. Gen. Frederick Jensen Dau, 834A Col., Hoyt Leroy .Prindle, S34A, Regular· Air adier general, Regular Air Force) , United (colonel, Regular Air Force), United States Force:·· Air Force. States Air Force. Col. Robert Loyal Easton, 368A, Re~rular Maj. Gen. Norris Brown Harbold, 369A The-following-named officers for temporary Air Force. - · · (brigadier general, Regular Air · Force) , appointment in the United -states Air Force '. coi. Emmett Felix Yost, 389A, Regular Air United States Air Force. ... under the provisions of section 515, Officer Force; · · ·. - - · · . · Maj. Gen. Albert Boyd, .424A (brigad~er Personnel Act of 1947: general, Regular Air Force), -United States · - Col. "'Holl1ngsworth Franklin Gregory, 496A, Regular Air Force. · · - Air Force. To be majqr generals Maj. Gen. Manuel Jose Asensio, 324A Brig. Gen. Matthew Kemp Deichelmann, Col. Tom William Scott," 536A, Regular Air (brigadier general, Regular Air Force), 331A, Regular .Air Force. Force. -- . · United States Air Force. · Brig. Gen. Merrill Davis Burnside, 495A. Col. Harold -Lester Smith, 564A, Regular Maj. Gen. John Stewart Mills, 357A (briga­ Regular Air Force. Air Force.- . dier general, Regular Air . Force), United Brig. Gen. Daniel Francis Callahan, 579A, . Col. Wendell Washington Bowman,- 596A, States Air Force. Regular Air Force. Regular Air Force. - Brig. Gen. Samuel Russ Harris,, Jr., 272A To be brigadier generals Col.
    [Show full text]
  • Congressional Overspeech
    ARTICLES CONGRESSIONAL OVERSPEECH Josh Chafetz* Political theater. Spectacle. Circus. Reality show. We are constantly told that, whatever good congressional oversight is, it certainly is not those things. Observers and participants across the ideological and partisan spectrums use those descriptions as pejorative attempts to delegitimize oversight conducted by their political opponents or as cautions to their own allies of what is to be avoided. Real oversight, on this consensus view, is about fact-finding, not about performing for an audience. As a result, when oversight is done right, it is both civil and consensus-building. While plenty of oversight activity does indeed involve bipartisan attempts to collect information and use that information to craft policy, this Article seeks to excavate and theorize a different way of using oversight tools, a way that focuses primarily on their use as a mechanism of public communication. I refer to such uses as congressional overspeech. After briefly describing the authority, tools and methods, and consensus understanding of oversight in Part I, this Article turns to an analysis of overspeech in Part II. The three central features of overspeech are its communicativity, its performativity, and its divisiveness, and each of these is analyzed in some detail. Finally, Part III offers two detailed case studies of overspeech: the Senate Munitions Inquiry of the mid-1930s and the McCarthy and Army-McCarthy Hearings of the early 1950s. These case studies not only demonstrate the dynamics of overspeech in action but also illustrate that overspeech is both continuous across and adaptive to different media environments. Moreover, the case studies illustrate that overspeech can be used in the service of normatively good, normatively bad, and * Professor of Law, Georgetown University Law Center.
    [Show full text]
  • Textbooks and Pure Fiscal Policy: the Neglect of Monetary Basics
    Econ Journal Watch, Volume 4, Number 1, January 2007, pp 60-70. Textbooks and Pure Fiscal Policy: The Neglect of Monetary Basics LEE C. SPECTOR AND T. NORMAN VAN COTT * ABSTRACT AGGREGATE DEMAND CANNOT CHANGE WITHOUT THE CONCOMITANT support of the monetary sector. At the initial level of output, either the money supply must change, the demand for money change, or the quantity of money demanded change. The link between money demand and money velocity means that changes in the demand for money and quantity of money demanded correspond to exogenous and endogenous changes in the velocity of money at the initial level of output. In any event, absent the support of the monetary sector, aggregate demand does not change. End of story. 1 One would hope that macroeconomic discussions of fiscal policy would utilize such monetary basics. Unfortunately, most leading textbooks in macro and monetary economics do not elucidate the monetary mechanisms crucial to understanding the effects of fiscal policy. Indeed, one must go back at least thirty years to find textbook discussions that do * Department of Economics, Ball State University. Muncie, IN 47306. The authors thank Milton Friedman and Richard Timberlake for their encouraging comments on a previous version of this paper. 1 At the initial level of output, endogenous changes in the quantity of money demanded or velocity can occur as a result of a change in the interest rate. Moreover, endogenous and exogenous changes in velocity at the initial level of output are probably better thought of as changes in the “desired” velocity since they stem from changes in people’s willingness to hold money.
    [Show full text]
  • Lessons from the Great American Real Estate Boom and Bust of the 1920S
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LESSONS FROM THE GREAT AMERICAN REAL ESTATE BOOM AND BUST OF THE 1920S Eugene N. White Working Paper 15573 http://www.nber.org/papers/w15573 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 December 2009 For their comments and suggestions, I would especially like to thank Lee Alston, Michael Bordo, Richard Grossman, Kris Mitchener, Carolyn Moehling, John Landon-Lane, Hugh Rockoff, Kenneth Snowden, Peter Temin, and the participants of seminars at Columbia University, the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, the Free University of Brussels, the German Historical Institute (Washington, D.C.), the Harvard Business School, the NBER Summer Institute, Rutgers University, the Universitat Pompeu Fabra, the University of Oslo, and the XVth World Economic History Conference, Utrecht. The view expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2009 by Eugene N. White. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Lessons from the Great American Real Estate Boom and Bust of the 1920s Eugene N. White NBER Working Paper No. 15573 December 2009 JEL No. E5,G01,G18,G21,N12,N22 ABSTRACT Although long obscured by the Great Depression, the nationwide “bubble” that appeared in the early 1920s and burst in 1926 was similar in magnitude to the recent real estate boom and bust.
    [Show full text]