The Politics and Economics of the U.S.-China Trade War

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Politics and Economics of the U.S.-China Trade War The Politics and Economics of the U.S.-China Trade War Deborah L. Swenson University of California, Davis Department of Economics 1122 SSH Davis, CA 95616 [email protected] Wing Thye Woo University of California, Davis Chinese Academy of Social Sciences, Beijing Sunway University, Kuala Lumpur Fudan University, Shanghai [email protected] Abstract The United States declared trade war after substantial defections from the internationalist (in geo- strategy and economics) lobby in U.S. politics to a new coalition between conflict-is-inevitable activists and anti-globalization proponents. Many internationalist businesses changed sides after experiencing disappointments on economic fronts including China’s non-compliance with some of its World Trade Organization (WTO) obligations, China’s acquisition of foreign technology at lower-than-expected prices, and the serious inadequacies in the WTO’s governance of global trade. Many of the disillusioned internationalists have given too much weight to the contribution of globalization to negative develop- ments in the U.S. labor market, and too little weight to the role of powerful capital-biased technological changes and to the inadequacies of state-provided programs for social insurance and human capital formation. Resolution of the trade war and prevention of its frequent occurrence will become more likely when (a) China adopts much greater reciprocity in its economic engagement with the advanced countries despite its status as a developing country under WTO rules; and (b) the United States stops equating geo-strategic competition with economic competition, recognizes that economic dynamism and economic resilience comes from strengthening indigenous innovation capability rather than from holding China back technologically,and institutes social programs to significantly reduce the trauma that is created by frequent job changes. Deep reform of the WTO is urgently needed but is unlikely to hap- pen in the medium run. For the medium run, the United States should mobilize country cooperation in regional settings (like the Trans-Pacific Partnership [TPP]) to introduce policy innovations to serve as templates for a re-designed WTO architecture, and to harness collective market power to be used in future negotiations on WTO reform. Asian Economic Papers 18:3 © 2019 by the Asian Economic Panel and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology https://doi.org/10.1162/asep_a_00710 Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/asep_a_00710 by guest on 28 September 2021 The Politics and Economics of the U.S.-China Trade War 1. Introduction After over 16 months of intense negotiations, marked by occasional drama but always lightened by late night tweets from Donald Trump,1 the United States and China agreed to a limited trade deal on 11 October 2019 that amounted to a truce in their trade war. The Americans put off a scheduled tariff increase on US$ 250 billion of Chinese imports, and the Chinese agreed to buy US$ 40 to 50 billion worth of U.S. agricultural products, be more transparent in foreign market interventions, ease U.S. entry into the financial services sec- tor, and enhance enforcement of intellectual property rights. Trump called this truce “a substantial phase one deal” even though specific details were not released, and nothing was signed.2 The U.S.–China trade war is only one part of Trump’s stated ambition to radically alter U.S. foreign economic relations. Just days after his inauguration in February 2017, Trump with- drew the United States from the TPP. Other early moves included the imposition of tariffs on steel and aluminum imports, and demands that Mexico, Canada, and Korea renegotiate the North American Free Trade Agreement and the Korea–U.S. Free Trade Agreement. On 22 March 2018, the United States Trade Representative (USTR 2018) released a report on China’s practices related to technology transfer, intellectual property, and innovation that accused China of unfair trade practices, and Trump announced that he would be imposing tariffs on Chinese imports. A series of China-specific tariffs were imposed be- ginning on 6 July 2018, and China retaliated in tit-for-tat fashion. By the time of the truce in October 2019, the United States had active tariffs on about US$ 375 billion of Chinese goods, and China had active tariffs on US$ 110 billion of U.S. merchandise exports.3 1 Noteworthy acts by the United States’ side included embarrassing Vice-Premier Liu He “on five different occasions by discarding understandings he thought had been reached or announcing measures on the eve of trade negotiations” (Mitchell, Tom. 2019. China makes few concessions in trade truce with U.S. Financial Times. Available at: https://www.ft.com/content/6a30ed00 -ecd1-11e9-ad1e-4367d8281195); the reduction in academic exchange; and Trump’s tweets that China badly needed the trade war to stop soon. Key acts from China’s side included the “unex- pected” rejection in May 2019 of a draft agreement that, according to the Americans, had been reached smoothly (Lo, Kinling. 2019. What killed U.S.-China trade talks: A tale of two texts. South China Morning Post. Available at: https://www.scmp.com/news/china/diplomacy/article /3010456/what-killed-us-china-trade-talks-tale-two-texts); depreciation of the RMB–US$ rate to beyond 7; an announced total ban on U.S. agricultural products; and the abrupt departure of Chinese negotiators from Washington, DC, in September 2019. 2 Apparently, the details would be worked out by 15 November 2019 when Donald Trump meets with Xi Jinping at the Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation meeting in Chile. 3 These two numbers are from Timmons and Lawder (2019), which differ from US$ 550 billion and US$ 185 billion (respectively) in Wong and Koty (2019). The Wong and Koty numbers include scheduled tariffs that were announced but not implemented by 11 October 2019. For reference, in 2017, U.S. imports of goods from China were roughly US$ 505 bn, and U.S. exports of goods to China were about US$ 130 bn. 2 Asian Economic Papers Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/asep_a_00710 by guest on 28 September 2021 The Politics and Economics of the U.S.-China Trade War Our analysis of the U.S.–China trade war is organized as follows. Section 2 identifies the different U.S. interest groups on China trade, and Section 3 explains why U.S. trade policy has pivoted away from its traditional emphasis on trade liberalization and global inte- gration. The next four sections, Sections 4 through 7, focus on four economic factors that generated immense political pressure for U.S. protectionism: negative outcomes in the U.S. labor market, China’s violations of WTO norms, U.S. worries about China’s technology acquisition practices, and serious defects of the WTO system. Section 8 analyzes the eco- nomic consequences of the trade conflict on the United States and the world, and Section 9 proposes policy adjustments for the United States and China to resolve their trade war and forestall its frequent reoccurrence. 2. U.S.perspectives on economic engagement with China Policy choices are nearly always the end-products of two contests: the contest of ideas and the contest of interest groups. These two contests are often linked because each interest group naturally pushes for the set of worldviews and solutions from which they will bene- fit. For most important economic issues that affect many U.S. groups (e.g., U.S.–China eco- nomic relations and U.S.–Saudi economic relations), no single U.S. interest group is likely to be strong enough on its own to determine the U.S. policy position. As a result, when a coalition of interest groups brokers compromises among themselves, their formation of a majority coalition on their issue of interest generally enables them to steer the setting of the national policy position on that issue. Our point is that significant change in policy regarding important economic matters, in most cases, is the outcome of the emergence of a new majority coalition on that issue. The reason why the U.S.–China trade war started in 2018 when the U.S. merchandise trade deficit was under 4 percent of GDP—rather than in 2006 when U.S. merchandise trade deficit was over 6 percent—is that the majority coalition on China trade in 2006 was no longer the majority coalition in 2018. Clearly, other factors aside from the trade imbalance have played a larger role in the transformation of the majority coalition. To identify these factors of influence, we looked at the range of U.S. opinions on China trade, which can be classified into four lobby groups. Lobby Group 1 consists of geo-strategists who advocate preserving the primacy of the United States in the global system.4 They are strident supporters of protectionism against China because they believe that the logic of geo-strategic competition makes the U.S.– China conflict inevitable (e.g., Mearscheimer 2001). Members of this group believe that 4 Blackwill and Campbell (2016, 29–36) want “to avoid a U.S.-China confrontation” but they want to “maintain U.S. primacy in Asia. [Hence an] energized American pivot to Asia is the indispens- able ingredient in a successful U.S. policy to participate and project strength more consequentially in the region and to deal with Chinese power and influence under Xi Jinping.” 3 Asian Economic Papers Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/asep_a_00710 by guest on 28 September 2021 The Politics and Economics of the U.S.-China Trade War postponement of the conflict will make the final conflict costlier and the final outcome less certain for the United States because the extra time will allow China to reduce the techno- logical gap, and to strengthen the coalition of authoritarian regimes opposed to the United States.
Recommended publications
  • Estimating the Market Effect of a Trade War: the Case of Soybean Tariffs
    Estimating the Market Effect of a Trade War: The Case of Soybean Tariffs Michael K. Adjemian, University of Georgia, Athens, GA1 Aaron Smith, University of California, Davis, CA Wendi He, University of California, Davis, CA Abstract: In 2018, China retaliated to U.S. trade actions by levying a 25% retaliatory tariff on U.S. soybean exports. That tariff shifted market preferences so that Chinese buyers—who make up a substantial share of total world consumption—favored Brazilian soybeans. We use the relative price of a substitute (RPS) method to estimate that the resulting trade disruption effectively drove a wedge into the world soybean market, lowering U.S. prices at Gulf export locations by $0.74/bu on average for about five months, and increasing Brazilian prices by about $0.97/bu, compared to what would have been observed without the tariff in place. By the end of that period, world markets adjusted and the soybean prices in both countries returned to the ex-ante state of near parity, although the U.S. export volume did not recover until the end of the following marketing year. Our price impact estimate is substantially lower than subsequent U.S. government “trade aid” payments to American soybean producers: although actual payments to producers varied based on county-level differences, USDA’s nominal calculation of the commodity- specific payment rate for soybeans under MFP summed to $3.70 for two bushels produced over the course of two years. We project that USDA’s near-$8.5 billion in trade aid to U.S. soybean producers exceeded the tariff damage by about $5.4 billion.
    [Show full text]
  • Developing Countries' Response to Trade Disputes
    WPS8640 Policy Research Working Paper 8640 Public Disclosure Authorized Traders’ Dilemma Developing Countries’ Response to Trade Disputes Public Disclosure Authorized Shantayanan Devarajan Delfin S. Go Csilla Lakatos Sherman Robinson Karen Thierfelder Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Development Economics Development Prospects Group November 2018 Policy Research Working Paper 8640 Abstract If trade tensions between the United States and certain trade agreements (RTAs) with all regions outside the United trading partners escalate into a full-blown trade war, what States; and (iv) option (iii) and unilaterally liberalize tariffs should developing countries do? Using a global, gener- on imports from the United States. The results show that al-equilibrium model, this paper first simulates the effects joining the trade war is the worst option for developing of an increase in U.S. tariffs on imports from all regions to countries (twice as bad as doing nothing), while forming about 30 percent (the average non-Most Favored Nation RTAs with non-U.S. regions and liberalizing tariffs on tariff currently applied to imports from Cuba and the U.S. imports (“turning the other cheek”) is the best. The Democratic Republic of Korea) and retaliation in kind reason is that a trade war between the United States and its by major trading partners—the European Union, China, major trading partners creates opportunities for developing Mexico, Canada, and Japan. The paper then considers four countries to increase their exports to these markets. Liberal- possible responses by developing countries to this trade war: izing tariffs increases developing countries’ competitiveness, (i) join the trade war; (ii) do nothing; (iii) pursue regional enabling them to capitalize on these opportunities.
    [Show full text]
  • 2012-11-1.Brookings-Tsinghua Book Launch.Posted.Pptx
    An Overview of “A New Economic Growth Engine for China: Escaping the Middle Income Trap by NOT Doing More of the Same” Wing Thye Woo (胡永泰) Fudan University, Shanghai Columbia University, New York City Brookings Institution, Washington D.C. Penang Institute, George Town University of California, Davis Central University of Finance and Economics, Beijing [email protected] Launch of Columbia-Fudan Report on Sustainable High Growth in China @ Brookings- Tsinghua Center, Beijing, 1 November 2012 1 Historical Perspective and Definition • In 2012, China has been the fastest growing country in the world for 35 years. • In 1912, what is the country that had been the fastest growing country in the world for the last 35 years? What is its position today? • When do we know that a country is caught in the middle-income trap? The country shows no tendency to converge to the living standard of the global economic leader, e.g. it stays at 50% of the living standard of the global leader for 20 years or more! Catch-Up Index (CUI) • CUI = country’s income level / US income level • boundaries of income group is based on notion that most of Western Europe is high- income and most of sub-Saharan Africa is low-income, – CUI >55% for high-income, – CUI<20% for low income – 1960: 20 countries high, 32 middle, 80 low – 2008: 27 countries high, 24 middle, 81 low – China entered middle-income in 2006 2 Club Convergence in Largest EuropeEconomies (High-Income in Western Club) and in South America (Middle- Income Club) 90.0 85.0 Western Europe: Maintain 70% 80.0 75.0
    [Show full text]
  • US Tariffs: EU Response and Fears of a Trade War
    AT A GLANCE US tariffs: EU response and fears of a trade war On 1 June 2018, US tariffs entered into force for steel and aluminium imports from the EU, Canada and Mexico, following US President Donald Trump's decision not to extend temporary exemptions. Argentina, Australia, Brazil and South Korea managed to obtain permanent exemptions as a result of deals struck with the Trump Administration. For all other countries, the US tariffs had already taken effect at the end of March 2018. After talks with the Trump Administration failed to result in a permanent exemption, the EU responded to the new tariffs by lodging a complaint at the WTO and instituting rebalancing measures on specific US exports. A safeguard investigation on steel imports into the EU is also on-going. Other US trading partners have responded in similar ways, raising fears that this could be the start of a full-blown trade war that would harm economic growth. Background On 23 March 2018, US tariffs of 25 % on steel imports and 10 % on aluminium imports took effect, following two Section 232 investigations that had concluded that such imports threatened to impair US national security. One day earlier, however, President Trump had decided to grant exemptions until 1 May 2018 to the EU as well as to Argentina, Australia, Brazil, Canada, Mexico and South Korea. The purpose of these exemptions was to provide these trading partners with an opportunity to discuss and address the Trump Administration's security concerns. On 30 April 2018, the US President decided to extend these temporary exemptions for another 30 days.
    [Show full text]
  • Trump's Trade War Timeline: an Up-To-Date Guide
    TRADE & INVESTMENT POLICY WATCH BLOG Trump’s Trade War Timeline: An Up-to-Date Guide Chad P. Bown and Melina Kolb, Peterson Institute for International Economics Updated May 17, 2021 This post, originally published on April 19, 2018, will be updated as trade disputes with China and other countries evolve. In 2018, former President Donald Trump started a trade war with the world involving multiple battles with China as well as American allies. Each battle has used a particular US legal rationale, such as calling foreign imports a national security threat, followed by Trump imposing tariffs and/or quotas on imports. Subsequent retaliation by trading partners and the prospect of further escalation risked significantly hampering trade and investment, and possibly the global economy. President Joseph R. Biden Jr. must now determine whether to keep US tariffs and other trade barriers in place or adjust policies in the wake of changing conditions, as well as the COVID-19 pandemic. The timelines below track the development of the most pressing trade conflicts with links to the latest available data and PIIE analysis. TABLE OF CONTENTS BATTLE #1: Solar Panel and Washing Machine Imports Injure US Industries, page 2 BATTLE #2: Steel and Aluminum as National Security Threats, page 3 BATTLE #3: Unfair Trade Practices for Technology, Intellectual Property (IP), page 8 BATTLE #4: Autos as National Security Threat, page 15 BATTLE #5: Illegal Immigration from Mexico, page 16 BATTLE #6: Safeguarding US Semiconductor Supremacy, page 17 References, page 20 1750 Massachusetts Avenue, NW | Washington, DC 20036-1903 USA | +1.202.328.9000 | www.piie.com TRADE AND INVESTMENT POLICY WATCH BLOG BATTLE #1: SOLAR PANEL AND WASHING MACHINE IMPORTS INJURE US INDUSTRIES USITC Recommends Remedies October 31, 2017 The US International Trade Commission finds that imports of solar panels (October 31, 2017) and washing machines (November 21, 2017) have caused injury to the US solar panel and washing machine industries and recommends President Trump impose “global safeguard” restrictions.
    [Show full text]
  • China Meets the Middle-Income Trap: the Large Potholes in the Road to Catching-Up Wing Thye Woo*
    Journal of Chinese Economic and Business Studies Vol. 10, No. 4, November 2012, 313–336 China meets the middle-income trap: the large potholes in the road to catching-up Wing Thye Woo* School of Economics, Fudan University, Shanghai; Penang Institute, George Town Economics Department, University of California, Davis, USA (Received 1 July 2012; final version received 11 August 2012) We follow Woo (2011) in using the Catch-Up Index (CUI) to define the middle-income trap and identify the countries caught in it. The CUI shows that China became a middle-income country in 2007–2008. We see five major types of middle-income trap to which China is vulnerable: (a) fiscal stress from the nonperforming loans generated by the interaction between the lending practices of the state banks and the innate desire by state enterprise managers to over-invest and embezzle; (b) the frequent use of macro-stabilization tools that hurt long-term productivity growth; (c) flaws in socio-political governance that exacerbate social tensions; (d) ineffective management of environmental challenges that threaten sustainable devel- opment; and (e) inept handling of international economic tensions that could unleash trade conflict. We recommend new governance principles and management methods to prevent China from falling into these five types of middle-income trap. Keywords: middle-income trap; overly-large state sector; urbanization under principle of future home ownership; environmental stress; trade war JEL Classifications: D31; E21; E26; E44; E51; E65; F41; G21; O53; P24; P31; P36; Q50 1. A new stage in China’s economic development but will this be the permanent stage? Downloaded by [Wing Thye Woo] at 04:06 16 November 2012 China will stand in 2013 where Argentina had stood in 1913 – the launch pad for high income-hood.
    [Show full text]
  • Impact of the U.S.-China Trade War on California Agriculture Colin A
    Impact of the U.S.-China Trade War on California Agriculture Colin A. Carter and Sandro Steinbach The U.S. Administration’s attempt In a 2018 ARE Update article, Carter Overall, the trade war has done little to force economic policy reform analyzed the initial round of China’s to change Chinese policies but the in China by starting a trade war retaliatory tariffs and concluded that tariffs have harmed U.S. consum- has failed to meet its goals. China for wine, walnuts and table grapes, ers and reduced economic growth retaliated with import tariffs that there would be little export price in the United States. A recent study target U.S. agriculture. We review impact but a loss of market share for found that due to higher prices, U.S. the impact of China’s retaliatory California exporters in the Chinese consumers have lost $51 billion on tariffs on a collection of California market. For almonds and pistachios, purchased products such as textiles, agricultural products, including Carter concluded that the volume of apparel, furniture, leather goods, and fruits, nuts, and wine. For almonds U.S. exports would not be unduly other manufactured products. impacted. We show below that the and pistachios, the tariffs did not U.S. consumers of the seven agricul- export volume impacts on these com- reduce the volume of U.S. exports tural commodities analyzed in this modities turned out as anticipated by to China. However, the trade war article may have benefitted from Carter. With the retaliatory tariffs in diminished California exports of lower prices (due to diminished place, Chinese consumers ended up walnuts, wine, oranges, and table exports) if wholesale/retailers passed paying higher prices for almonds and grapes.
    [Show full text]
  • Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies Indonesia's Economic
    This article was downloaded by: On: 24 March 2011 Access details: Access Details: Free Access Publisher Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37- 41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.informaworld.com/smpp/title~content=t713406865 Indonesia's economic performance in comparative perspective and a new policy framework for 2049 Wing Thye Wooab; Chang Hongc a University of California, Davis, CA b Central University of Finance and Economics, Beijing c Clark University, Worcester, MA Online publication date: 17 March 2010 To cite this Article Woo, Wing Thye and Hong, Chang(2010) 'Indonesia's economic performance in comparative perspective and a new policy framework for 2049', Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, 46: 1, 33 — 64 To link to this Article: DOI: 10.1080/00074911003642237 URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00074911003642237 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Full terms and conditions of use: http://www.informaworld.com/terms-and-conditions-of-access.pdf This article may be used for research, teaching and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, re-distribution, re-selling, loan or sub-licensing, systematic supply or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representation that the contents will be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of any instructions, formulae and drug doses should be independently verified with primary sources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss, actions, claims, proceedings, demand or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with or arising out of the use of this material.
    [Show full text]
  • China's Dilemma
    CHINA’S DILEMMA i ii CHINA’S DILEMMA ECONOMIC GROWTH, THE ENVIRONMENT AND CLIMATE CHANGE Ligang Song and Wing Thye Woo (eds) Asia Pacific Press Brookings Institution Press SOCIAL SCIENCES ACADEMIC PRESS (CHINA) iii Co-published by ANU E Press and Asia Pacific Press The Australian National University Canberra ACT 0200 Australia Email: [email protected] This title available online at http://epress.anu.edu.au/china_dilemma_citation.html © 2008 ANU E Press, Asia Pacific Press, Brookings Institution Press and Social Sciences Academic Press (China) This work is copyright. Apart from those uses which may be permitted under the Copyright Act 1968 as amended, no part may be reproduced by any process without written permission from the publisher. Co-published with SOCIAL SCIENCES ACADEMIC PRESS (CHINA) C H I N A B O O K under the China Book International scheme. This scheme supports INTERNATIONAL co-publication of works with international publishers. National Library of Australia Cataloguing-in-Publication entry Title: China’s dilemma : economic growth, the environment and climate change / editors Ligang Song ; Wing Thye Woo. ISBN: 9780731538195 (pbk.) 9781921536038 (pdf.) Notes: Includes index. Bibliography. Subjects: Economic development--Environmental aspects--China. Climatic changes--China. Energy consumption--China. China--Economic conditions. China--Environmental conditions. Other Authors/Contributors: Song, Ligang. Woo, Wing Thye. Dewey Number: 338.900951 Cover design: Teresa Prowse Cover photo: Jason Lyon. iStockphoto, File Number: 2831996
    [Show full text]
  • The Free Trade System Facing the Threat of Collapse* Shujiro Urata**
    The Free Trade System Facing the Threat of Collapse The Free Trade System Facing the Threat of Collapse* Shujiro Urata** Abstract Triggered by the United States imposing tariffs on Chinese imports and subsequently China`s retaliatory action, the exchange of tariffs has escalated into a full-blown trade war between the two countries in 2018. The United States is aiming to reduce or eradicate its trade imbalance by using protectionist measures. There are two main reasons behind protectionism in the United States. One is an attempt to secure jobs in certain sectors of US industry. Another reason is the alarm it feels in the face of China’s rapid development in information technology (IT) and other areas of advanced technology. The latter concern is shared by many members of the US Congress and business leaders, and this makes it possible that measures against China may continue long beyond the Trump presidency. I propose three options that the rest of the world can take in these circumstances to persuade the United States to return to a rule-based free trade system: (1) a possible U-turn in US policy would be brought about by the increasing severity of the negative impact of protectionist measures on the US economy itself; (2) the world’s major economies̶Japan, the EU, China, and so on̶to work toward comprehensive and liberal regional integration without the United States on trade and investment, and thus push the United States into a disadvantageous position; and (3) countries that share interests in common, like Japan and the EU, to involve the United States in efforts to reform the World Trade Organization (WTO).
    [Show full text]
  • Working Paper 19-7: the 2018 US-China Trade Conflict After 40
    WORKING PAPER 19-7 The 2018 US-China Trade Conflict After 40 Years of Special Protection Chad P. Bown April 2019 Abstract In 2018, the United States suddenly increased tariffs on nearly 50 percent of its imports from China. China imme- diately retaliated with tariffs on more than 70 percent of imports from the United States. This paper assesses what happened in 2018 and attempts to explain why. It first constructs a new measure of special tariff protection to put the sheer scope and coverage of the 2018 actions into historical context. It then uses the lens provided by the 2018 special tariffs to explain the key sources of economic and policy friction between the two countries. This includes whether China’s state-owned enterprises and industrial subsidies, as well as China’s development strategy and system of forc- ibly acquiring foreign technology, were imposing increasingly large costs on trading partners. Finally, it also examines whether the US strategy to provoke a crisis—which may result in a severely weakened World Trade Organization— was deliberate and out of frustration with the institution itself. JEL Code: F13 Keywords: Trade war, tariffs, retaliation, WTO Chad P. Bown is the Reginald Jones Senior Fellow at the Peterson Institute for International Economics. Author’s Note: A revised version of this paper is forthcoming in the China Economic Journal. Thanks to Eva Zhang for outstanding research assistance, William Melancon and Melina Kolb for assistance with graphics, and to Peter Schott and Judith Dean for assistance with data. I am also grateful for useful discussions and comments on an earlier draft from William Cline, Anabel Gonzalez, Egor Gornostay, Julien Gourdon, Bernard Hoekman, Gary Hufbauer, Brad Jensen, Soumaya Keynes, Maury Obstfeld, Tom Prusa, and Steve Weisman.
    [Show full text]
  • The Challenges of Governance Structure, Trade Disputes and Natural Environment to China's Growth
    Studia i Analizy Studies & Analyses Centrum Analiz Spoleczno – Ekonomicznych Center for Social and Economic Research 3 4 9 Wing Thye Woo The Challenges of Governance Structure, Trade Disputes and Natural Environment to China's Growth Warsaw,September 2007 Studies & Analyses 349- Wing Thye Woo -The Challenges of Governance Structure … Materials published here have a working paper character. They can be subject to further publication. The views and opinions expressed here reflect the author(s) point of view and not necessarily those of CASE. The publication was financed by Rabobank Polska S.A. I am most grateful to Ximing Yue for providing the estimates on rural poverty, and to John Bonin, Jeffrey Miller, Gerard Roland, and Wei Zhang for comments on an earlier draft presented at the Association for Comparative Economic Studies ASSA session, Chicago, 7 January 2007. This paper was inspired by the Debate on China's Economy in the Reframing China Policy Debate Series of the Carnegie Endowment for International Peace; see http://www.carnegieendowment.org/events/index.cfm?fa=eventDetail&id=929&&prog=zch Keywords: harmonious society, governance issues, mass incidents, environmental protection, water crisis, trade imbalances, protectionism JEL codes: H2, K4, O53, P36, Q50 © CASE – Center for Social and Economic Research, Warsaw 2007 Graphic Design: Agnieszka Natalia Bury ISSN 1506-1701, ISBN 978-83-7178-441-5 EAN 9788371784415 Publisher: CASE – Center for Social and Economic Research 12 Sienkiewicza, 00-010 Warsaw, Poland tel.: (48 22) 622 66 27, 828 61 33, fax: (48 22) 828 60 69 e-mail: [email protected] http://www.case.com.pl/ 2 Studies & Analyses 349- Wing Thye Woo -The Challenges of Governance Structure … Contents ABSTRACT.................................................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]