Corporate Takeovers Handbook.Pdf

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Corporate Takeovers Handbook.Pdf Tuck School of Business at Dartmouth Tuck School of Business Working Paper No. 2008-47 Corporate Takeovers Sandra Betton John Molson School of Business, Concordia University [email protected] B. Espen Eckbo Tuck School of Business at Dartmouth [email protected] Karin Thorburn Tuck School of Business at Dartmouth [email protected] May 2008 This version, August 2008 This paper can be downloaded from the Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1131033 Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1131033 Corporate Takeovers∗ Sandra Betton John Molson School of Business Concordia University [email protected] B. Espen Eckbo Tuck School of Business Dartmouth College [email protected] Karin S. Thorburn Tuck School of Business Dartmouth College [email protected] May, 2008 This version, August 2008 To appear in B. E. Eckbo (ed.), Handbook of Corporate Finance: Empirical Corporate Finance, Volume 2 (North-Holland/Elsevier, Handbooks in Finance Series), Chapter 15, 2008. Keywords: takeover, merger, tender offer, auction, offer premium, bidder gains, toeholds, markups, hostility, executive compensation, arbitrage, announcement return, long-run performance, monopoly, antitrust ∗Surveying the vast area of corporate takeovers is a daunting task, and we have undoubtedly missed many inter- esting contributions. We apologize to those who feel their research has been left out or improperly characterized, and welcome reactions and comments. Some of the material in Section 3 is also found in Eckbo (2008). Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1131033 Abstract This essay surveys the recent empirical literature and adds to the evidence on takeover bids for U.S. targets, 1980-2005. The availability of machine readable transaction databases have allowed empirical tests based on unprecedented sample sizes and detail. We review both aggregate takeover activity and the takeover process itself as it evolves from the initial bid through the final contest outcome. The evidence includes determinants of strategic choices such as the takeover method (merger v. tender offer), the size of opening bids and bid jumps, the payment method, toehold acquisition, the response to target defensive tactics and regulatory intervention (antitrust), and it offers links to executive compensation. The data provides fertile grounds for tests of everything ranging from signaling theories under asymmetric information to strategic competition in product markets and to issues of agency and control. The evidence is supportive of neoclassical merger theories. For example, regulatory and technological changes, and shocks to aggregate liquidity, appear to drive out market-to-book ratios as fundamental drivers of merger waves. Despite the market boom in the second half of the 1990s, the proportion of all-stock offers in more than 13,000 merger bids did not change from the first half of the decade. While some bidders experience large losses (particularly in the years 1999 and 2000), combined value-weighted announcement-period returns to bidders and targets are significantly positive on average. Long-run post-takeover abnormal stock returns are not significantly different from zero when using a performance measure that replicates a feasible portfolio trading strategy. There are unresolved econometric issues of endogeneity and self-selection. Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1131033 Contents 1 Introduction 1 2 Takeover activity 5 2.1 Merger waves . 5 2.2 Takeover contests, 1980-2005 . 9 2.2.1 Initial bidders and offer characteristics . 9 2.2.2 Duration, time to second bid, and success rates . 13 2.3 Merger negotiation v. public tender offer . 15 2.3.1 Merger agreement and deal protection devices . 15 2.3.2 Mandatory disclosure and tender offer premiums . 17 2.3.3 Determinants of the merger choice . 19 3 Bidding strategies 20 3.1 Modeling the takeover process . 20 3.1.1 Free-riders and post-offer dilution . 20 3.1.2 Auction with single seller . 24 3.2 The payment method choice . 25 3.2.1 Taxes . 26 3.2.2 Information asymmetries . 27 3.2.3 Capital structure and control motives . 31 3.2.4 Behavioral arguments for all-stock . 32 3.3 Toehold bidding . 33 3.3.1 Optimal bids . 33 3.3.2 The toehold puzzle . 35 3.4 Bid jumps and markup pricing . 38 3.4.1 Preemption and bid jumps . 38 3.4.2 Runups and markups . 40 3.5 Takeover defenses . 42 3.5.1 Legal basis for defensive measures . 44 3.5.2 Defenses and offer premiums . 46 3.6 Targets in bankruptcy . 53 3.6.1 Chapter 11 targets . 53 3.6.2 Bankruptcy auctions and fire-sales . 55 3.6.3 Testing for auction overbidding . 56 3.7 Offer premium summary . 59 4 Takeover gains 61 4.1 Econometric caveats . 62 4.2 Runup- and announcement-period returns . 63 3 4.3 Dollar returns . 67 4.4 Estimating expected bidder gains . 68 4.5 Post-takeover (long run) abnormal returns . 69 4.5.1 Buy-and-hold returns . 70 4.5.2 Portfolio performance estimation . 72 5 Bondholders, executives, and arbitrageurs 74 5.1 Takeovers and bondholder wealth . 74 5.2 Takeovers and executive compensation . 76 5.3 Merger arbitrage . 81 5.3.1 Arbitrage positions . 81 5.3.2 Arbitrage gains . 82 5.3.3 Limits to arbitrage . 84 6 Takeovers, competition and antitrust 86 6.1 Efficiency v. market power: predictions . 86 6.2 Effects of merger on rival firms . 89 6.3 Effects of merger on suppliers and customers . 91 6.4 Some implications for antitrust policy . 93 6.4.1 The market concentration doctrine . 93 6.4.2 Did the 1978 Antitrust Improvements Act improve antitrust? . 95 7 Summary and Conclusions 97 7.1 Takeover activity . 98 7.2 Bidding strategies and offer premiums . 99 7.3 Takeover gains . 102 7.4 Bondholders, executives, and arbitrage . 104 7.5 Competition and antitrust . 105 1 Introduction Few economic phenomena attract as much public attention and empirical research as the various forms of transactions in what Manne (1965) dubbed ”the market for corporate control.” Corporate takeovers are among the largest investments that a company ever will undertake, thus providing a unique window into the value implications of important managerial decisions and bid strategies, and into the complex set of contractual devices and procedures that have evolved to enable the deals to go through. Empirical research in this area has focused on a wide range of topics including the impact of statutory and regulatory restrictions on the acquisition process (disclosure and target defenses), strategic bidding behavior (preemption, markup pricing, bid jumps, toeholds, payment method choice, hostility), short- and long-run abnormal stock returns to bidder, and targets (size and division of takeover gains), and the origin and competitive effects of corporate combinations (efficiency, market power and antitrust policy). In this survey, we review empirical research on each of these and related topics. The structure of our survey differs from most earlier empirical reviews, where the focus tends to be on the final bid in completed takeovers.1 We follow the approach begun by Betton and Eckbo (2000) and examine the entire takeover process as it evolves from the first bid, through bid revision(s) and toward the final outcome (success or failure). This more detailed focus on the takeover process is also found in more recent publications.2 We provide new empirical updates in some areas, using takeovers found in the Thomson Financial SDC database for the period 1980– 2005. One limitation of the survey is that we do not discuss the general interplay between the market for corporate control, ownership structure and corporate governance (with the exception of hostile bids).3 We also limit the review to empirical studies of takeovers of U.S. target firms.4 Takeovers by financial buyers such as leveraged buyouts (LBOs) are surveyed in Eckbo and Thorburn (2008b), Chapter 16 of this volume. Throughout, we use the term takeover generically for any acquisition of corporate control 1Jensen and Ruback (1983), Jarrell, Brickley, and Netter (1988), Eckbo (1988), Andrade, Mitchell, and Stafford (2001), Martynova and Renneboog (2005, 2007). 2Bhagat, Dong, Hirshleifer, and Noah (2005), Boone and Mulherin (2007b), Betton, Eckbo, and Thorburn (2007). See also the survey by Burkart and Panunzi (2006). 3Research on corporate ownership structure, managerial private benefits of control, shareholder activism and voting, etc., is surveyed in Becht, Bolton, and Roll (2003), Dyck and Zingales (2004), and Adams and Ferreira (2007). 4See Martynova and Renneboog (2006) for the European takeover market. 1 through the purchase of the voting stock of the target firm, regardless of whether the bid is in the form of a merger agreement or a tender offer. Moreover, in our vernacular, the first observed bid for a specific target starts a takeover ”contest” whether or not subsequent bids actually ma- terialize. All initial bids start a contest in the sense of attracting potential competition from rival bidders and/or incumbent target management. This is true even after signing a merger agreement, as director fiduciary duties require the target board to evaluate competing offers all the way un- til target shareholders have voted to accepted the agreement (the fiduciary out). Also, we know from the data that a friendly merger negotiation is not a guarantee against the risk of turning the takeover process into an open auction for the target. The contest perspective helps us understand why initially friendly merger bids are sometimes followed by tender offers and vice versa, why we sometimes observe bid revisions even in the absence of rival bidders, why target hostility emerges even when the initial bidder appears to be friendly, and why the auction for the target sometimes fail, altogether (no bidder wins). We begin in Section 2, ”Takeover activity,” with a brief discussion of takeover waves, followed by a detailed description of the initial bids in an unprecedented sample consisting of more than 35,000 takeover contests for U.S.
Recommended publications
  • Adopting a Poison Pill in Response to Shareholder Activism
    IN THE BOARDROOM CAPITAL MARKETS & CORPORATE GOVERNANCE Ismagilov/Shutterstock.com Adopting a Poison Pill in Response to Shareholder Activism In his regular column, Frank Aquila drafts a memo to a board explaining the considerations it should evaluate when deciding whether to adopt a poison pill. FRANCIS J. AQUILA PARTNER SULLIVAN & CROMWELL LLP Frank has a broad multidisciplinary practice that includes extensive experience in negotiated and unsolicited mergers and acquisitions, activist and takeover defense, complex cross-border transactions, global joint ventures, and private equity transactions. He regularly counsels boards of directors and board committees on corporate governance matters and crisis management. MEMORANDUM TO: The Board of Directors FROM: Frank Aquila RE: Considerations When Adopting a Poison Pill in Response to Shareholder Activism As we have discussed, the Investor has just filed a Schedule 13D with the Securities and Exchange Commission disclosing equity holdings in the Company equal to 8.8% of the Company’s common stock. The Investor has also disclosed its intentions to increase its stake to approximately 15%, seek representation on the Company’s Board, and then advocate for either a spin-off of certain business units or a sale of the Company. 22 April 2016 | Practical Law © 2016 Thomson Reuters. All rights reserved. To strengthen the Board’s negotiating leverage and provide adequate time to evaluate what alternatives would be in the best interests of the Company and its shareholders, the Board is considering adopting a shareholder rights plan, commonly known as a poison pill, with a 10% threshold. Correctly implemented, the triggering of this poison pill would massively dilute the Investor’s voting and equity stake as soon as the Investor acquires 10% of the Company’s outstanding common stock by allowing all other shareholders to purchase additional shares at a steep discount.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 IRREVOCABLE SUBSCRIPTION UNDERTAKING TO: Tryg A/S
    EXECUTION VERSION IRREVOCABLE SUBSCRIPTION UNDERTAKING TO: Tryg A/S Klausdalsbrovej 601 2670 Ballerup Denmark ("Tryg") and Morgan Stanley & Co. International plc 25 Cabot Square Canary Wharf London E14 4QA United Kingdom ("Morgan Stanley") and Danske Bank A/S Holmens Kanal 2 - 12 DK-1092 Copenhagen Denmark ("Danske Bank" and together with Morgan Stanley, the "Underwriters") FROM: TryghedsGruppen SMBA Hummeltoftevej 49 2830 Virum Denmark (the "Foundation", "us", "we") Date: 18 November 2020 1 RECOMMENDED CASH OFFER TO ACQUIRE RSA INSURANCE GROUP PLC AND RIGHTS ISSUE IN TRYG A/S 1.1 We understand that Tryg together with Regent Bidco Limited (“Bidco”) and Intact Financial Corporation ("Intact") contemplate an acquisition by Bidco of the entire issued and to be issued share capital of RSA Insurance Group plc ("RSA") (the "Acquisition") by way of court-sanctioned scheme of arrangement under Part 26 of the UK Companies Act 2006 (including any new, increased, renewed or revised scheme of arrangement) (the ''Scheme''). In connection with the Acquisition, 1 Intact and Tryg have entered into a Separation Agreement with respect to the Scandinavia Sepa- ration, on the terms and conditions as summarised in the draft announcement attached to this irrevocable undertaking as Appendix 1.1 (the ''Rule 2.7 Announcement''), together with such additional terms and conditions as may be required by the Applicable Requirements (as defined in Clause 1.3 below) or as may be agreed in writing between Tryg, Intact, Bidco and RSA provided that such additional terms shall not increase Foundation's payment obligations under this irrevoca- ble undertaking or change the consideration contributed by Tryg to the Acquisition as indicated in the Rule 2.7 Announcement without the Foundation's prior consent.
    [Show full text]
  • The SEC and the Failure of Federal, Takeover Regulation
    Florida State University Law Review Volume 34 Issue 2 Article 2 2007 The SEC and the Failure of Federal, Takeover Regulation Steven M. Davidoff [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://ir.law.fsu.edu/lr Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Steven M. Davidoff, The SEC and the Failure of Federal, Takeover Regulation, 34 Fla. St. U. L. Rev. (2007) . https://ir.law.fsu.edu/lr/vol34/iss2/2 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Florida State University Law Review by an authorized editor of Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. FLORIDA STATE UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW THE SEC AND THE FAILURE OF FEDERAL TAKEOVER REGULATION Steven M. Davidoff VOLUME 34 WINTER 2007 NUMBER 2 Recommended citation: Steven M. Davidoff, The SEC and the Failure of Federal Takeover Regulation, 34 FLA. ST. U. L. REV. 211 (2007). THE SEC AND THE FAILURE OF FEDERAL TAKEOVER REGULATION STEVEN M. DAVIDOFF* I. INTRODUCTION.................................................................................................. 211 II. THE GOLDEN AGE OF FEDERAL TAKEOVER REGULATION.................................. 215 A. The Williams Act (the 1960s) ..................................................................... 215 B. Going-Privates (the 1970s)......................................................................... 219 C. Hostile Takeovers (the 1980s)..................................................................... 224 1. SEC Legislative
    [Show full text]
  • Investor Bulletin: Reverse Mergers
    e Investor Bulletin: Reverse Mergers Introduction merger surviving public company are primarily, if not solely, those of the former private operating company. Many private companies, including some whose operations are located in foreign countries, seek to ac- cess the U.S. capital markets by merging with existing Why Pursue a Reverse Merger? public companies. These transactions are commonly referred to as “reverse mergers” or “reverse takeovers A private operating company may pursue a reverse (RTOs).” merger in order to facilitate its access to the capi- tal markets, including the liquidity that comes with having its stock quoted on a market or listed on an What is a Reverse Merger? exchange. Private operating companies generally have access only to private forms of equity, while public In a reverse merger transaction, an existing public companies potentially have access to funding from a “shell company,” which is a public reporting company broader pool of public investors. A reverse merger with few or no operations,1 acquires a private oper- often is perceived to be a quicker and cheaper method ating company—usually one that is seeking access of “going public” than an initial public offering (IPO). to funding in the U.S. capital markets. Typically, the The legal and accounting fees associated with a reverse shareholders of the private operating company ex- merger tend to be lower than for an IPO. And while change their shares for a large majority of the shares the public shell company is required to report the of the public company. Although the public shell reverse merger in a Form 8-K filing with the SEC, company survives the merger, the private operating there are no registration requirements under the company’s shareholders gain a controlling interest in Securities Act of 1933 as there would be for an IPO.
    [Show full text]
  • Earnings Management Around the Seasoned Equity Offerings (Seos) by Australian Firms: a Multivariate Analysis
    Journal of Business Studies, Vol. XXXVI, No. 2, August 2015 Earnings Management around the Seasoned Equity Offerings (SEOs) by Australian Firms: A Multivariate Analysis Dr. Md. Hamid U Bhuiyan1 Abstract: Extant research indicates that managers engage in earnings manipulation to manage reported earnings and value of the firm to maximize specific private benefits and to mislead some of firm’s investors. This study examines whether the managers of Australian firms engage in earnings manipulation in the form of real earnings management (REM) and accrual earnings management (AEM) around the seasoned equity offerings (SEOs). These research questions are particularly relevant to Australia as a result of introduction of regulatory reform in Australia, which is Corporate Law Economic Reform Program (CLERP 9) to protect investors’ interest after a series high profile corporate collapses in Australia. Using a 4287 firm-year observations (excluding Financial and Utility Industry Sectors) over the 9 years from 2002 to 2010, cross-sectional REM models developed by Dechow et al. (1998) and implemented by Roychowdhury (2006) are used to estimate the proxies for REM (abnormal cash flow from operations, abnormal production costs, and abnormal discretionary expenses) and the modified Jones (1991) model is used to measure the proxy for AEM (abnormal accruals). Using a sample of 829 SEOs over the 7 years from 2004 to 2010, and controlling for other determinants of REM and AEM activities, this study finds that managers of Australian SEO firms tend to engage in REM and AEM activities around SEO-years, and earnings management activity is greater in these years relative to the rest of the sample.
    [Show full text]
  • A Theory of Merger-Driven Ipos
    JOURNAL OF FINANCIAL AND QUANTITATIVE ANALYSIS Vol. 46, No. 5, Oct. 2011, pp. 1367–1405 COPYRIGHT 2011, MICHAEL G. FOSTER SCHOOL OF BUSINESS, UNIVERSITY OF WASHINGTON, SEATTLE, WA 98195 doi:10.1017/S0022109011000421 A Theory of Merger-Driven IPOs Jim Hsieh, Evgeny Lyandres, and Alexei Zhdanov∗ Abstract We propose a model that links a firm’s decision to go public with its subsequent takeover strategy. A private bidder does not know a firm’s true valuation, which affects its gain from a potential takeover. Consequently, a private bidder pursues a suboptimal restructur- ing policy. An alternative route is to complete an initial public offering (IPO) first. An IPO reduces valuation uncertainty, leading to a more efficient acquisition strategy, therefore enhancing firm value. We calibrate the model using data on IPOs and mergers and acqui- sitions (M&As). The resulting comparative statics generate several novel qualitative and quantitative predictions, which complement the predictions of other theories linking IPOs and M&As. For example, the time it takes a newly public firm to attempt an acquisition of another firm is expected to increase in the degree of valuation uncertainty prior to the firm’s IPO and in the cost of going public, and it is expected to decrease in the valuation surprise realized at the time of the IPO. We find strong empirical support for the model’s predictions. I. Introduction Recent empirical studies suggest that firms’ initial public offerings (IPOs) and mergers and acquisitions (M&As) are not unrelated. According to a survey of ∗Hsieh, [email protected], School of Management, George Mason University, 4400 University Dr., Fairfax, VA 22030; Lyandres, [email protected], School of Management, Boston University, 595 Commonwealth Ave., Boston, MA 02445; and Zhdanov, [email protected], University of Lausanne, Extranef 237, Lausanne 1007, Switzerland and Swiss Finance Institute.
    [Show full text]
  • Investment Banker Directors and Seasoned Equity Offerings*
    Investment Banker Directors and Seasoned Equity Offerings* Qianqian Huang College of Business City University of Hong Kong Kowloon Tong, HK [email protected] Kai Li Sauder School of Business University of British Columbia 2053 Main Mall, Vancouver, BC V6T 1Z2 [email protected] Ting Xu Sauder School of Business University of British Columbia 2053 Main Mall, Vancouver, BC V6T 1Z2 [email protected] This version: December, 2016 * We are grateful for helpful comments from Xueping Wu. Li acknowledges financial support from the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada. All errors are ours. Investment Banker Directors and Seasoned Equity Offerings Abstract We examine how directors with investment banking experience affect firms’ capital raising activities. We find that firms with investment bankers on their boards have a higher probability of making seasoned equity offerings (SEOs), and that these offerings are associated with higher announcement returns, lower underpricing, and lower underwriter spreads. These results are consistent with the idea that investment banker directors reduce information asymmetry between issuers and the equity market. We find a limited role of investment banker directors in firms issuing bonds or obtaining loans, which are less information-sensitive than equity. Overall, our results highlight the advisory role of specialist directors in shaping corporate policies. Keywords: Seasoned equity offerings; board of directors; investment banking experience; information asymmetry; advisory role of directors JEL Classification: G14, G24, G32 I. Introduction Much of the discussions on corporate boards has centered on their monitoring role, yet boards spend a significant portion of their time advising rather than monitoring (Adams and Ferreira (2007) and Adams, Hermalin, and Weisbach (2010)).
    [Show full text]
  • Equity Issuances and Agency Costs: the Telling Story of Shareholder Approval Around the World
    Equity Issuances and Agency Costs: The Telling Story of Shareholder Approval around the World Clifford G. Holderness∗ January 2016 Shareholder approval of equity issuances varies considerably. When shareholders must approve issuances, average announcement returns are positive. When managers unilaterally issue stock, returns are 4% lower and negative. The closer the vote is to the issuance or the greater is the required plurality, the higher are the returns for public offers, rights offers, and private placements. Shareholders favor rights offers and seldom approve public offers. Managers favor public offers and seldom choose rights offers. These findings hold across and within 23 countries, including the United States, suggesting that agency problems affect equity issuances and that shareholder approval reduces these costs. (JEL G32, G14, G15) Keywords: Equity offerings, agency costs, mandatory shareholder voting, corporate governance. © Copyright 2015. Clifford G. Holderness. All rights reserved. * Boston College, Carroll School of Management ([email protected]). I thank Vladimir Atanasov, David Chapman, Alex Edmans, Rainer Gawlick, Stuart Gillan, Edith Ginglinger, Dirk Jenter, Michael Klausner, Nadya Malenko, William Mann, David McLean, Jeffrey Pontiff, Jonathan Reuter, Stefano Rossi, Dennis Sheehan, Philip Strahan, David Yermack, and seminar participants at the BI Conference on Corporate Governance, Boston College, ESCP Paris, the Frontiers in Finance Conference, and the University of Pittsburgh for comments. John Bagamery
    [Show full text]
  • Earnings Management and the Long-Run Market Performance of Initial Public Offerings
    THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE • VOL. LIII, NO. 6 • DECEMBER 1998 Earnings Management and the Long-Run Market Performance of Initial Public Offerings SIEW HONG TEOH, IVO WELCH, and T. J. WONG* ABSTRACT Issuers of initial public offerings ~IPOs! can report earnings in excess of cash flows by taking positive accruals. This paper provides evidence that issuers with unusu- ally high accruals in the IPO year experience poor stock return performance in the three years thereafter. IPO issuers in the most “aggressive” quartile of earnings managers have a three-year aftermarket stock return of approximately 20 percent less than IPO issuers in the most “conservative” quartile. They also issue about 20 percent fewer seasoned equity offerings. These differences are statistically and economically significant in a variety of specifications. SEVERAL STUDIES FIND THAT INITIAL public offerings ~IPOs! underperform after the issue.1 Over a three-year holding period after the offering, Ritter ~1991! reports substantially lower stock returns ~mean of 227 percent and median of 255 percent! for a sample of 1,526 IPOs going public between 1975 and *Teoh is at the University of Michigan, Welch is at the University of California, Los Angeles, and Wong is at the University of Science and Technology, Hong Kong. We thank Andrew Alford, Joe Aharony, John Barber, Vic Bernard, Shlomo Bernartzi, Robert Bowen, Laura Field, Steve Hansen, David Hirshleifer, Michael Kirschenheiter, Charles Lee, Tim Loughran, Susan Moyer, Gita Rao, Jay Ritter, Jake Thomas, Dan Tinkelman, Sheridan Titman, and workshop partici- pants at the University of British Columbia, Columbia University, New York University, and the University of Washington for helpful comments.
    [Show full text]
  • Accounting Quality, Corporate Acquisition, and Financing Decisions*
    Accounting Quality, Corporate Acquisition, and Financing Decisions* Sangwan Kim Kenan-Flagler Business School University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill 300 Kenan Center Drive, Campus Box 3490, McColl Building Chapel Hill, NC 27599 [email protected] January 2013 Abstract This paper examines the extent to which the quality of financial accounting information disciplines manager interests to align with stockholder interests in corporate acquisition and financing decisions. I find that, after controlling for financing constraints, recent performance, and payout policy, the tendency of firm managers to time the market is significantly constrained for firms with high-quality financial accounting information. Further, I find that the disciplining impact of accounting information is mostly driven by firms that bid for acquisitions financed with stock issuance. I also provide corroborating evidence by examining a similar disciplining role of financial accounting information in the seasoned public offering markets. I find no such effect for potential acquisitions financed through cash. The evidence suggests that high-quality accounting information allows stockholders to discipline firm managers that are motivated to take advantage of the misevaluation. Further, the results suggest the effectiveness of accounting information as a control mechanism is pronounced for firms that pursue more value-decreasing investment projects. JEL Classification: G02, G32, G34, M41 Keywords: Accounting quality, corporate governance, market timing, mergers and
    [Show full text]
  • Nguyen Quang Diep
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Waseda University Repository AY 2011 SEASONED EQUITY OFFERINGS IN VIETNAM Examining investors’ capability in assessing long-run operating performance of the issuers NGUYEN QUANG DIEP Major in Business Administration 35092313-7 GRADUATE SCHOOL OF COMMERCE WASEDA UNIVERSITY PROF.NAGAI TAKESHI C.E. PROF.HIGASHIDE HIRONORI D.E. PROF.TAKIGUCHI TADASHI Table of Contents CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION................................................................................... 1 1.1 The concept of Seasoned equity offering ............................................................................ 1 1.2 Overview of Seasoned equity offerings in Vietnam............................................................ 3 1.3 Scope of Objectives........................................................................................................... 10 1.4 Outline of research methodology ...................................................................................... 10 1.5 Thesis structure.................................................................................................................. 11 CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW..................................................................... 13 2. 1 Capital structure theories and implications on SEO......................................................... 13 2.2 SEOs and long-run post-issue operating performance of the issuers ................................ 22 2.3 The twenty SEOs-assessing criteria
    [Show full text]
  • Public and Private Takeover Markets: an Empirical Analysis
    PUBLIC AND PRIVATE TAKEOVER MARKETS: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS by MICHAEL A. STEGEMOLLER (Under the direction of Annette B. Poulsen) ABSTRACT An unparalleled $2.7 trillion worth of merger and acquisition activity occurred in the 1990s. These mergers resulted in the combination of firms that were able to combine rapidly changing technologies in new ways. Despite the large amount of merger activity in this period, there is relatively little research studying these mergers and the financial markets that facilitated them. My research addresses the following basic questions about takeovers. The first is whether mergers and acquisitions facilitate economic growth, and the second examines why private firms sell-out to public companies instead of undertaking an initial public offering. I find that acquisitions create tremendous value for those firms utilizing them as a means of corporate change. Frequent acquirers outperform non-frequent acquirers using both economic and accounting measures of performance. Additionally, the level of over-performance is positively influenced by the relative size of the acquisition program of the acquirer. I also examine the transition from private to public ownership by private owners selling their business to a public corporation. I compare these transactions to initial public offerings to better compare the characteristics that influence the decision to be acquired versus “go public.” My results suggest that private firms seeking to transition to public ownership choose an acquisition as the means of transition based on firm-specific characteristics such as growth rates, insider ownership, leverage, and profitability. INDEX WORDS: Takeovers, Mergers, Acquisitions, Long-run performance, Private, IPO, Corporate governance, Ownership PUBLIC AND PRIVATE TAKEOVER MARKETS: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS by MICHAEL A.
    [Show full text]