The Practical Reason for Both Antitrust and Consumer Protection Law

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Practical Reason for Both Antitrust and Consumer Protection Law University of Baltimore Law ScholarWorks@University of Baltimore School of Law All Faculty Scholarship Faculty Scholarship 1997 Consumer Choice: The rP actical Reason for Both Antitrust and Consumer Protection Law Neil W. Averitt Bureau of Competition, Federal Trade Commission Robert H. Lande University of Baltimore School of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarworks.law.ubalt.edu/all_fac Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, and the Consumer Protection Law Commons Recommended Citation Consumer Choice: The rP actical Reason for Both Antitrust and Consumer Protection Law, 10 Loy. Consumer L. Rev. 44 (1997-1998) This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at ScholarWorks@University of Baltimore School of Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in All Faculty Scholarship by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks@University of Baltimore School of Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. FEATURE ARTICLES Consumer Choice: The Practical Reason for Both Antitrust and Consumer Protection Law Neil W. Averitt, B.A. Harvard, M.Sc. London School of Economics, J.D. By Neil W. Averitt and Robert H. Lande Harvard, is an attorney in the Office of Policy & Evaluation, Bureau of Competi­ tion, Federal Trade Commission. Mr. Averitt can be reached at <[email protected]>. This article is about the relationship between Robert H. Lande, B.A. Northwestern, antitrust and consumer protection law. Its M.P.P. Harvard, J.D. Harvard, is Professor purpose is to define each area of law, to delin­ of Law, University of Baltimore School of Law. Mr. Lande can be reached at eate the boundary between them, to show how <[email protected]>. they interact with each other, and to show how Both authors have practiced in the area they ultimately support one another as the two of trade regulation law for twenty years and components of a single overarching unity. That have made a specialty of Federal Trade overarching unity is consumer choice. Antitrust Commission law. They have made a particular study of the relationship between and consumer protection law share a common the FTC's competition and consumer purpose in that both are intended to facilitate protection missions, believing that, if this the exercise of consumer sovereignty or effec­ relationship was better understood, it tive consumer choice. Such consumer choice would lead to more rigorous legal prin­ exists when two fundamental conditions are ciples and stronger public support for each mission. The authors have explored present: (l) there must be a range of consumer aspects of this thesis in a number of options made possible through competition; and forums over the years, including presenta­ (2) consumers must be able to select freely tions to international conferences and among these options. conSUltations with overseas national law­ The boundary between antitrust and con­ revision committees. The present article is a condensation, adaptation, and update of sumer protection is best defmed by reference to Neil W. Averitt & Robert H. Lande, Con­ these two elements of consumer choice. The sumer Sovereignty: A Unified Theory of antitrust laws are intended to ensure that the Antitrist and Consumer Protection Law, 65 marketplace remains competitive, so that a ANTITRUST L.J. 713 (1997). Portions of that meaningful range of options is made available article are incorporated with the permission ofthe American Bar Association. The to consumers, unimpaired by practices such as opinions expressed in this article are solely price fixing or anticompetitive mergers. I The the authors' own, and do not necessarily consumer protection laws are intended to reflect the views of their colleagues, the ensure that consumers can select effectively Bureau of Competition, the Federal Trade from among those options with their critical Commission, or any individual Commis­ sioner. faculties unimpaired by such violations as 44 • Loyola Consumer Law Review Volume 10, number 1 deception or the withholding of material infor­ price competition. In certain sectors of the mation. Protection by both the antitrust and economy, such as high-tech or media-related consumer protection laws is needed to ensure industries, diversity of options may be far more that a market economy can continue to operate important to consumers than price competition. effectively. Third, because consumer choice is important, This protection is needed when "market consumer protection actions should be limited failures" arise, which may create or permit to conduct that has a reasonably clear effect on competition or consumer protection problems. consumers' ability to select, and such actions This article will demonstrate that antitrust should not be brought against conduct that is violations (which impair the menu of options) objectionable on less clearly defmed moral or stem from market failures in the general mar­ equitable grounds. Finally, our framework ketplace external to consumers, whereas should be useful to those countries that are consumer protection violations (which impair establishing or reorganizing trade regulation the individual's ability to select) flow from programs for the fIrst time. internal market failures that take place, in a The discussion of our proposed unified sense, "inside the consumer's head."2 While theory will be divided into four principal this formula appears on its face to be of Doric sections. The fIrst section introduces and simplicity, it provides a coherent theoretical defInes the concept of effective consumer framework from which antitrust and consumer choice, which requires both the existence of protection law may be better understood and consumer options and the ability to select applied. among these options. The second section This framework has not only theoretical reviews antitrust and consumer protection case interest, but also at least four significant practi­ law and shows that this law is consistent with cal consequences. First, a unified theory of (and explicable by) an option-oriented model of antitrust and consumer protection law will consumer choice. The third section identifIes assist the enforcement authorities in determin­ and discusses the economic market failures that ing when particular conduct or transactions may tend to impede the exercise of consumer should be pursued on antitrust as opposed to choice by restricting either the menu of options consumer protection grounds. Many concrete or consumers' ability to select among them. aspects and effects of a litigation vary accord­ Finally, the fourth section explores the practical ing to whether it is classified as an antitrust or a implications and consequences of our proposed consumer protection matter. For example, only framework. Among these consequences, the antitrust violations give rise to criminal sanc­ framework suggests that antitrust law should be tions and automatic treble damages, and only in construed somewhat more broadly than in the consumer protection cases is the Federal Trade past, and consumer protection law somewhat Commission ("FTC" or "Commission") re­ more narrOWly. quired to use certain rule making and investiga­ tory procedures. A unified theory will make I. An Option-Oriented Concept clear when antitrust or consumer protection laws should be utilized. Second, the importance of Consumer Choice of marketplace options in consumer choice Simply put, consumer choice or consumer suggests that antitrust should devote more sovereignty is the state of affairs that prevails attention than it now does to the role of non- 1998 Loyola University Chicago Schoolo/Law • 45 or should prevail in a modem free-market Thus, we do not simply require the maxi­ economy. It is the set of societal arrangements mum number of options. Antitrust law does not that cause that economy to act primarily in prevent all conduct or transactions that have the response to the aggregate signals of consumer effect of reducing the number of options avail­ demand, rather than in response to government able to consumers. Nor does the law affirma­ directives or the preferences of individual tively require the creation of options. Rather, it businesses. It is the state of affairs in which the prevents business conduct that artificially limits consumer is truly "sovereign," in the sense of the natural range of options in the market­ having the power to define his or her own place.4 Indeed, the law permits even some wants and the ability to satisfy those wants at artificial reductions, such as some mergers, if prices not greatly in excess of the costs borne the benefits of the action appear to outweigh by the providers of the relevant goods and the costs. Through these means, the antitrust services.3 The concept of consumer sover­ laws aim to preserve a sufficient, although not a eignty goes so far as to embody at least some perfect, array of options for consumers to implicit notions about the proper relationship choose among. between the individual and the state; it is part of Consumer protection laws are similar in the the Western world's answer to the prescriptions sense that they seek to protect the ability of of Marxism. consumers to make rational choices among The essence of consumer sovereignty is the competing options but do not necessarily strive exercise of choice. By choosing some goods or to ensure that consumers have perfect informa­ some options over others, consumers satisfy tion.5 Probably no consumer is a perfect rea­ their own wants and send signals to the soning machine, existentially free from all the economy. It is, therefore, critical that the extraneous influences of early upbringing, exercise of consumer choice be protected. cultural values, or half-remembered advertising We have already seen that effective con­ campaigns from years ago. What we ask of sumer choice requires two things: options in consumer protection law is therefore something the marketplace and the ability to select freely relatively modest. We ask that consumers be among them. To tum this conceptual paradigm enabled to make rational choices to the extent into operational policy, at least some rough that they wish to concentrate on doing so.
Recommended publications
  • Antitrust Enforcement and the Consumer
    Many consumers have never heard of antitrust laws, but when these laws are effectively and responsibly enforced, they can save consumers millions and even billions of dollars a year in illegal overcharges. Most States have antitrust laws, and so does the Federal Government. Essentially, these laws prohibit business practices that unreasonably deprive consumers of the benefits of competition, U.S. Department of Justice resulting in higher prices for inferior Washington, DC 20530 products and services. This pamphlet was prepared to alert consumers to the existence and importance of antitrust laws and to explain what you can do for antitrust enforcement and for yourself. 1. What Do the Antitrust Laws Do for the Consumer? Antitrust Antitrust laws protect competition. Free and open competition benefits consumers Enforcement by ensuring lower prices and new and better products. In a freely competitive and the market, each competing business generally Consumer will try to attract consumers by cutting its prices and increasing the quality of its products or services. Competition and the profit opportunities it brings also stimulate businesses to find new, innovative, and more efficient methods of production. Consumers benefit from competition through lower prices and better products and services. Companies that fail to understand or react to consumer needs may soon find themselves losing out in the competitive battle. When competitors agree to fix prices, rig bids, or allocate (divide up) customers, consumers lose the benefits of competition. The prices that result when competitors agree in these ways are artificially high; such prices do not accurately reflect cost and therefore distort the allocation of society’s resources.
    [Show full text]
  • The Three Types of Collusion: Fixing Prices, Rivals, and Rules Robert H
    University of Baltimore Law ScholarWorks@University of Baltimore School of Law All Faculty Scholarship Faculty Scholarship 2000 The Three Types of Collusion: Fixing Prices, Rivals, and Rules Robert H. Lande University of Baltimore School of Law, [email protected] Howard P. Marvel Ohio State University, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarworks.law.ubalt.edu/all_fac Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, and the Law and Economics Commons Recommended Citation The Three Types of Collusion: Fixing Prices, Rivals, and Rules, 2000 Wis. L. Rev. 941 (2000) This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at ScholarWorks@University of Baltimore School of Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in All Faculty Scholarship by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks@University of Baltimore School of Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. ARTICLES THE THREE TYPES OF COLLUSION: FIXING PRICES, RIVALS, AND RULES ROBERTH. LANDE * & HOWARDP. MARVEL** Antitrust law has long held collusion to be paramount among the offenses that it is charged with prohibiting. The reason for this prohibition is simple----collusion typically leads to monopoly-like outcomes, including monopoly profits that are shared by the colluding parties. Most collusion cases can be classified into two established general categories.) Classic, or "Type I" collusion involves collective action to raise price directly? Firms can also collude to disadvantage rivals in a manner that causes the rivals' output to diminish or causes their behavior to become chastened. This "Type 11" collusion in turn allows the colluding firms to raise prices.3 Many important collusion cases, however, do not fit into either of these categories.
    [Show full text]
  • Price Fixing and Repeated Games
    9781405176323_4_014.qxd 10/19/07 8:12 PM Page 323 14 Price Fixing and Repeated Games In February 2007, the European Union Competition Directorate imposed their largest-ever fines on companies found guilty of colluding to fix prices. Five elevator manufacturers were fined a total of a992 million (approximately $1.4 billion) for operating a cartel that con- trolled prices in Germany, Belgium, Luxembourg and the Netherlands. ThuysenKrupp received the heaviest fine, of more than a479 million since it was judged to be a “repeat offender” by the Commission. Otis was fined a225 million, Schindler a144 million, Kone a142 million, and Mitsubishi’s Dutch subsidiary a1.8 million.1 The elevator case came just one month after another case involving gas insulated switch- gear projects in which the Commission imposed fines totally a750 million on 11 companies for their parts in a price-fixing cartel. In this case, the largest fine of a396.5 million was imposed on Siemens, Germany. This case is particularly interesting because it was broken open largely as a result of the Commission’s leniency policy. Under that policy, the first firm in a conspiracy to confess and “fink” on its co-conspirators gets a much reduced penalty. In fact, the finking firm in the switch-gear case, ABB Switzerland, was granted full immu- nity and paid no penalties in return for its confession and provision of information to the authorities. That reflects a considerable savings from the a215 million it would otherwise have had to pay as a repeat offender. Action to curb the activities of cartels has been equally active in the United States.2 The Department of Justice has recently imposed a total of more than $732 million on companies operating a cartel to control the pricing of dynamic random access memory (DRAM).
    [Show full text]
  • A Structured Outline for the Analysis of Horizontal Agreements
    A STRUCTURED OUTLINE FOR THE ANALYSIS OF HORIZONTAL AGREEMENTS by Thomas B. Leary* The antitrust principles applied to “horizontal” arrangements are difficult to summarize. The principles have evolved over an extended period of time and have been shaped by decisions that are often hard to reconcile. I do not claim that the structure outlined below is the only way to read cases or frame issues, but it is one that I believe is consistent with the most recent precedent and learning. I. Introduction An agreement between actual or potential competitors to restrain their rivalry in some respect is commonly called a “horizontal restraint.” This kind of agreement should be distinguished from so-called “vertical” restraints that govern the interface between supplier and customers (who may also be competitors in another capacity). The distinction is fundamental because horizontal and vertical restraints are analyzed in different ways.1 The most significant difference is that horizontal restraints are more likely to be deemed illegal per se and vertical restraints are more likely to be subject to the “rule of reason.” * Commissioner, Federal Trade Commission. This revision of a paper first presented a year ago has been prepared for distribution at The Conference Board 2004 Antitrust Conference (Mar. 3-4, 2004). I have benefitted from discussions with FTC Chairman Timothy Muris, General Counsel William Kovacic, and attorney advisors Thomas Klotz, Lisa Kopchik and Holly Vedova in the preparation of this outline, but it does not necessarily reflect their views or the views of anyone else in the Commission. 1 See, e.g., discussion in ABA SECTION OF ANTITRUST LAW, ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS 79-82 (5th ed.
    [Show full text]
  • When Does Buyer Power Become Monopsony Pricing?
    Antitrust , Vol. 27, No. 1, Fall 2012. © 2012 by the American Bar Association. Reproduced with permission. All rights reserved. This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or stored in an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association. X+Y Company has a large percentage of purchases in the market; and X+Y Company has sufficient buyer When Does Buyer power to drive hard bargains and pay “low” prices to Power Become the farmers. X+Y Company’s downstream, sell-side market is nation - al, includes many competitors, and includes products Monopsony Pricing? beyond those made by X+Y Company. Competition is strong, and X+Y Company has a low market share and BY JOHN D. SHIVELY no ability to increase consumer prices or decrease qual - ity. Any harm from the price X+Y Company pays for inputs is felt directly by the farmers whose profits are HE STRUCTURE OF AGRICULTURAL depressed, but there is no increase in price, or decrease industries breeds monopsony claims, and conse - in quality, to consumers who ultimately buy X+Y quently, those industries are a major arena for Company’s product. conflicting schools of thought on monopsony pric - Ting. The 2 01 0 USDA-DOJ Agriculture Industry The key issue is how to determine whether X+Y Com - Work shops raised issues of buyer power and monopsony pany’s power to pay “low” prices to farmers is (1) buyer pricing by concentrated agribusiness to new prominence power that exists in all competitive markets 1 or (2) anticom - and encouraged the DOJ’s Antitrust Division to take more petitive monopsony power.
    [Show full text]
  • Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborations Among Competitors
    Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborations Among Competitors Issued by the Federal Trade Commission and the U.S. Department of Justice April 2000 ANTITRUST GUIDELINES FOR COLLABORATIONS AMONG COMPETITORS TABLE OF CONTENTS PREAMBLE ................................................................................................................................ 1 SECTION 1: PURPOSE, DEFINITIONS, AND OVERVIEW ............................................... 2 1.1 Purpose and Definitions .................................................................................................... 2 1.2 Overview of Analytical Framework ................................................................................ 3 1.3 Competitor Collaborations Distinguished from Mergers .............................................. 5 SECTION 2: GENERAL PRINCIPLES FOR EVALUATING AGREEMENTS AMONG COMPETITORS .................................................................................. 6 2.1 Potential Procompetitive Benefits .................................................................................. 6 2.2 Potential Anticompetitive Harms .................................................................................... 6 2.3 Analysis of the Overall Collaboration and the Agreements of Which It Consists ......................................................................................................... 7 2.4 Competitive Effects Are Assessed as of the Time of Possible Harm to Competition ..................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Regression Estimates of Damages in Price-Fixing Cases
    REGRESSION ESTIMATES OF DAMAGES IN PRICE-FIXING CASES MICHAEL 0. FINKELSTEIN* AND HANS LEVENBACHt In an antitrust price-fixing case, damages are measured by the difference between the prices paid by the plaintiff purchasers and the prices they would have paid in the absence of defendants' conspiracy. Even small variations in the deter- mination of these differences may become significant because plaintiffs are entitled by statute to receive three times their actual damages.' Moreover, in a class action there may be thousands of purchasers whose recoveries are based on an industry- wide overcharge formula. The difficulty of course lies in estimating the "but for" prices. An obvious idea is to assume that competitive prices during the conspiracy period would have been the same as they were before or after the conspiracy or in interludes of competition within the conspiracy period. Thus, the difference between the conspiratorial price and the actual price from other periods measures the damage. This estimate, however, meets the immediate objection that it is likely to be incorrect because changes in factors affecting price other than the conspiracy would have produced changes in competitive prices if there had been competition during the conspiracy period. These arguments may be illustrated by Ohio Valley Electric Corp. v. Genera/ Elecric 2 Co., one of the well-known antitrust cases involving electrical equipment manu- facturers. Plaintiffs contended that the purpose and effect of the manufacturers' conspiracy was to keep transaction prices for large steam turbines close to book prices; they proposed to measure damages by the difference between the average 11% discount during the conspiracy period and the average 25.33% discount that prevailed after the conspiracy had been terminated.
    [Show full text]
  • Antitrust Policy and Monopsony Roger D
    Cornell Law Review Volume 76 Article 1 Issue 2 January 1991 Antitrust Policy and Monopsony Roger D. Blair Jeffrey L. Harrison Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarship.law.cornell.edu/clr Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Roger D. Blair and Jeffrey L. Harrison, Antitrust Policy and Monopsony , 76 Cornell L. Rev. 297 (1991) Available at: http://scholarship.law.cornell.edu/clr/vol76/iss2/1 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Journals at Scholarship@Cornell Law: A Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Cornell Law Review by an authorized administrator of Scholarship@Cornell Law: A Digital Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. ANTITRUST POLICY AND MONOPSONY Roger D. Blairt &Jeffirey L. Harrison$ I INTRODUCTION The owners of major league baseball teams have colluded in dealing with free agents,' the NCAA regulates both the number of athletic scholarships and the amount of compensation that athletes receive, 2 financial aid officers of the elite colleges and universities meet to avoid a bidding war for the most desirable students,3 tuna canneries in California allegedly fix purchase prices at artificially low levels,4 and antique dealers have rigged bids in public auctions, di- viding the spoils later.5 What do all of these parties have in com- mon? They employ monopsony power: power on the buying side 6 of the market. The classical theory of monopsony envisions a market with only one buyer that uses its power to reduce the quantity purchased, t Huber Hurst Professor of Business and Legal Studies, University of Florida.
    [Show full text]
  • Maximum Price Fixing
    University of Chicago Law School Chicago Unbound Journal Articles Faculty Scholarship 1981 Maximum Price Fixing Frank H. Easterbrook Follow this and additional works at: https://chicagounbound.uchicago.edu/journal_articles Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Frank H. Easterbrook, "Maximum Price Fixing," 48 University of Chicago Law Review 886 (1981). This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at Chicago Unbound. It has been accepted for inclusion in Journal Articles by an authorized administrator of Chicago Unbound. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Maximum Price Fixing Frank H. Easterbrookf If all of the grocers in a city agreed to sell 100-watt light bulbs for no more than fifty cents, that would be maximum price fixing. If a group of optometrists agreed to charge no more than $30 for an eye examination and to display a distinctive symbol on the shops of parties to the agreement, that would be maximum price fixing. And if most of the physicians in a city, acting through a nonprofit association, offered to treat patients for no more than a given price if insurance companies would agree to pay the fee, that agreement would be maximum price fixing too. A maximum price appears to be a boon for consumers. The optometrists' symbol, for example, helps consumers find low-cost suppliers of the service. But the agreement also appears to run afoul of the rule against price fixing, under which "a combination formed for the purpose and with the effect of raising, depressing, fixing, pegging, or stabilizing the price of a commodity ..
    [Show full text]
  • The Resale Price Maintenance Two-Step
    COMMERCIAL LITIGATION Controlling Retail Prices The Resale Price Maintenance By Pat Pascarella, Anne Swoboda Cruz, Two-Step and Stephanie Rzepka Until anti-Leegin states permit companies simply to enter into pro- competitive resale price agreements, properly implemented and monitored policies can In 2007, the U.S. Supreme Court abolished the per se rule provide a fair amount against minimum resale price agreements and held that of price discipline, and they were to be judged instead under the more lenient rule pose marginal risk. of reason standard. Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 877 (2007). ance has placed manufacturers competing But 10 years later, the combined effect in nationwide markets in the unenviable of a disconnect between Leegin and cer- position of weighing the benefits of ratio- tain states’ laws and a lack of dispositive nalizing their retail distribution channels court decisions providing substantive guid- against unpredictable litigation risks. ■ Pat Pascarella is the chair the Tucker Ellis’ Antitrust Group. Before joining Tucker Ellis, he served with the U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division in Washington D.C. and as chief in-house antitrust counsel to a Fortune-10 company. Anne Swoboda Cruz, a partner in Tucker Ellis’ Los Angeles office, is a trial attorney specializing in commercial litigation and antitrust. Ms. Cruz also is an active member of DRI, including the DRI Women in the Law Com- mittee. Stephanie Rzepka is an associate in Tucker Ellis’ Houston office. She represents businesses in antitrust, class action, and complex commercial litigation before state and federal courts and antitrust enforcement agencies.
    [Show full text]
  • Posner's Program for the Antitrust Division: a Twenty-Five Year Perspective
    SMU Law Review Volume 48 Issue 5 Article 5 1995 Posner's Program for the Antitrust Division: A Twenty-Five Year Perspective John E. Lopatka William H. Page Follow this and additional works at: https://scholar.smu.edu/smulr Recommended Citation John E. Lopatka & William H. Page, Posner's Program for the Antitrust Division: A Twenty-Five Year Perspective, 48 SMU L. REV. 1713 (1995) https://scholar.smu.edu/smulr/vol48/iss5/5 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Journals at SMU Scholar. It has been accepted for inclusion in SMU Law Review by an authorized administrator of SMU Scholar. For more information, please visit http://digitalrepository.smu.edu. POSNER'S PROGRAM FOR THE ANTITRUST DzvIsioN: A TWENTY-FIVE YEAR PERSPECTIVE John E. Lopatka* William H. Page** TABLE OF CONTENTS I. INTRODUCTION .......................................... 1713 II. CA RTELS ................................................... 1716 A. TACIT COLLUSION ....................................... 1717 B. EXPRESS COLLUSION AND INVITATIONS TO COLLUDE .... 1720 C. RESALE PRICE MAINTENANCE ........................... 1723 III. M ERG ERS ................................................. 1725 IV. SINGLE-FIRM EXCLUSIONARY CONDUCT ............ 1728 A. THE "ACCIDENTAL" MONOPOLY ......................... 1730 B. RAISING RIVALS' COSTS ................................. 1731 C. NETWORK EXTERNALITIES ............................... 1738 D. PREDATORY PRICING .................................... 1745 V. CONCLUSION ............................................
    [Show full text]
  • The Rule of Reason
    University of Pennsylvania Carey Law School Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law 2018 The Rule of Reason Herbert J. Hovenkamp University of Pennsylvania Carey Law School Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, Business Law, Public Responsibility, and Ethics Commons, Courts Commons, Economic History Commons, Industrial Organization Commons, Intellectual Property Law Commons, Law and Economics Commons, Law and Society Commons, Legal History Commons, Legal Remedies Commons, Litigation Commons, Public Economics Commons, and the Social Welfare Law Commons Repository Citation Hovenkamp, Herbert J., "The Rule of Reason" (2018). Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law. 1778. https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship/1778 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law by an authorized administrator of Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. THE RULE OF REASON Herbert Hovenkamp* Abstract Antitrust’s rule of reason was born out of a thirty-year Supreme Court debate concerning the legality of multi-firm restraints on competition. By the late 1920s the basic contours of the rule for restraints among competitors was roughly established. Antitrust policy toward vertical restraints remained much more unstable, however, largely because their effects were so poorly understood. This Article provides a litigation field guide for antitrust claims under the rule of reason—or more precisely, for situations when application of the rule of reason is likely.
    [Show full text]