Robust Market Design: Information and Computation

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Robust Market Design: Information and Computation ROBUST MARKET DESIGN: INFORMATION AND COMPUTATION A DISSERTATION SUBMITTED TO THE DEPARTMENT OF COMPUTER SCIENCE AND THE COMMITTEE ON GRADUATE STUDIES OF STANFORD UNIVERSITY IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Inbal Talgam-Cohen December 2015 Abstract A fundamental problem in economics is how to allocate precious and scarce resources, such as radio spectrum or the attention of online consumers, to the benefit of society. The vibrant research area of market design, recognized by the 2012 Nobel Prize in economics, aims to develop an engineering science of allocation mechanisms based on sound theoretical foundations. Two central assumptions are at the heart of much of the classic theory on resource allocation: the common knowledge and substitutability assumptions. Relaxing these is a prerequisite for many real-life applications, but involves significant informational and computational challenges. The starting point of this dissertation is that the computational paradigm offers an ideal toolbox for overcoming these challenges in order to achieve a robust and applicable theory of market design. We use tools and techniques from combinatorial optimization, randomized algo- rithms and computational complexity to make contributions on both the informa- tional and computational fronts: 1. We design simple mechanisms for maximizing seller revenue that do not rely on common knowledge of buyers' willingness to pay. First we show that across many different markets { including notoriously challenging ones in which the goods are heterogeneous { the optimal revenue benchmark can be surpassed or approximated by adding buyers or limiting supplies, and then applying the standard Vickrey (second-price) mechanism. We also show how, by removing the common knowledge assumption, the classic theory of revenue maximiza- tion expands to encompass the realistic but complex case in which buyers are interdependent in their willingness to pay. iv 2. We prove positive and negative results for maximizing social welfare without substitutability, i.e., without the convexity property known to drive economic efficiency. On the positive side, we design natural greedy mechanisms for two- sided markets with strong incentive properties, whose welfare performance de- pends on the market's \distance" from substitutability. On the negative side, we show how computational challenges related to complementarity lead to the economic failure of competitive markets, in the sense that there do not exist simple prices that guide such a market to an efficient allocation. These results carry implications for the practice of market design, both for revenue- maximizing sellers such as Internet companies running online auctions, and for welfare- maximizing policy makers such as governments running spectrum auctions. v In loving memory of Daphna Talgam Acknowledgements Although I spent many hours of solitary work towards this dissertation, the most meaningful and memorable parts were the interaction and collaboration with my advisors, mentors, colleagues and friends. First and foremost I would like to thank my advisor Tim Roughgarden. Working under his guidance has been an enormous privilege, and he will always be an inspi- ration for me in the depth and breadth of his knowledge and insight, his passion for teaching and mentoring, his integrity, curiosity and daring intellectual, his leadership and generosity to his students. I also wish to thank my mentor Paul Milgrom. Taking his course my second year at Stanford was a turning point in my life, and like so many others I have been profoundly influenced by his genius (as is apparent throughout this dissertation). I am deeply grateful for his support and for all that I have learned through our conversations. I thank Ramesh Johari for kindly serving on my reading committee and for his excellent guidance in writing this dissertation, Robert Wilson for doing me the honor of chairing my dissertation committee, and Ashish Goel for kindly serving on the committee. Thanks to my wonderful co-authors Qiqi Yan and Paul Duetting, without whom parts of this dissertation would not have come to existence. I was fortunate to learn from Qiqi's originality and modesty, and Paul's clarity of thought and productivity. I thank the Hsieh family for honoring me with the title of Hsieh Fellow and for generously funding my research. vii I wish to acknowledge those without whom I would not have begun my PhD stud- ies: Special thanks to Uriel Feige, my MSc advisor at the Weizmann Institute, whose profound wisdom and concise, on-spot advice have guided me throughout my PhD studies. I thank Justice Esther Hayut for allowing me the honor and privilege of in- terning with her; witnessing firsthand how her deep thinking and economic reasoning drove fairness and justice inspired me to pursue this PhD. I owe a great deal to many researchers at Stanford who were always available to provide invaluable advice and guidance: Itai Ashlagi, Yonatan Gur, Fuhito Kojima, Uri Nadav, Serge Plotkin, Al Roth, Amin Saberi, Yoav Shoham, Gregory Valiant, Ryan Williams and Virginia Vassilevska Williams. Special thanks to Vasilis Gkatzelis for his generosity and encouragement. Heartfelt thanks to the mentors, collaborators and co-authors with whom I was fortunate to connect through my internships and research projects: Noga Alon, Moshe Babaioff, Shahar Dobzinski, Michal Feldman, Prabhakar Krishnamurthy, Mohammad Mahdian, Yishai Mansour, Mukund Sundararajan, Moshe Tennenholtz, Sergei Vas- silvitskii, L´aszl´oV´eghand Omri Weinstein. Thanks to those who made Stanford such a wonderful place for me: Tim's group members (Peerapong, Shaddin, Rishi, Zhiyi, Anthony, Kostas, Jamie, Okke and Joshua), the members of the market design coffee, and admins Lynda Harris and Ruth Harris. I am grateful to the folks at ACM for entrusting me with co-leading XRDS maga- zine, an experience which introduced me to many brilliant peers, enriched my knowl- edge of the computer science community and made me a better community member. Thanks to my dear friends in the Bay Area, for helping me get through the difficult times and celebrate the good ones: Ayelet, Elinor, Gili, Ifat, Neta and Shiri, as well as Ankita, Erika, Kahye, Kshipra, Irene and Leor, Keren and Orit, and finally Dana. I am grateful beyond words to my parents Yoav and Daphna, brothers Erez and Tomer and family members Ruti, Efrat, Avi and Dorit for their love and support. And to Noy, thank you for standing by me always and for sharing this incredible journey with me, which you and Dory have made so special. viii Contents Abstract iv vi Acknowledgements vii 1 Introduction 2 1.1 Overview ..................................................................... 2 1.2 Model......................................................................... 6 1.2.1 Basic Model .......................................................... 6 1.2.2 Revenue: Bayesian Model and Interdependence ................... 9 1.2.3 Welfare: Substitutes ................................................. 11 1.2.4 Solution Concepts ................................................... 12 1.3 Motivating Examples and Related Literature ............................. 15 1.3.1 Motivating Examples ................................................ 15 1.3.2 Market Design State-of-the-Art .................................... 17 1.4 Research Goals ............................................................... 20 1.4.1 Goal 1: Revenue without Common Knowledge.................... 20 1.4.2 Goal 2: Welfare without Substitution .............................. 24 1.4.3 Meta-Goal: Simplicity............................................... 29 1.5 Contributions ................................................................ 31 1.5.1 Informational Contributions in Revenue Maximization ........... 31 1.5.2 Computational Contributions in Welfare Maximization .......... 36 1.6 Bibliographic Notes .......................................................... 42 ix 2 Preliminaries 43 2.1 Auction Environments....................................................... 43 2.1.1 Single-Parameter Bayesian Environments ......................... 43 2.1.2 Multi-Parameter Matching Environments ......................... 45 2.2 Optimal Mechanism Design ................................................. 46 2.2.1 Mechanisms .......................................................... 46 2.2.2 Maximizing Welfare and the Vickrey Auction ..................... 47 2.2.3 Maximizing Revenue and Myerson's Mechanism .................. 48 2.2.4 Regularity ............................................................ 49 2.3 Prior-Independent Robustness .............................................. 49 2.3.1 Definition............................................................. 49 2.3.2 Rationales ............................................................ 51 2.3.3 Robustness in the Literature........................................ 52 I Informational Challenges in Revenue Maximization 54 3 Robust Revenue Maximization in Matching Markets 55 3.1 Chapter Introduction ........................................................ 55 3.1.1 Overview ............................................................. 55 3.1.2 The Problem ......................................................... 56 3.1.3 Motivating Example: Multi-Unit Markets ......................... 58 3.1.4 Our Contribution .................................................... 62 3.1.5 Related Work ........................................................ 65 3.1.6
Recommended publications
  • Loss Aversion and Sunk Cost Sensitivity in All-Pay Auctions for Charity: Experimental Evidence∗
    Loss Aversion and Sunk Cost Sensitivity in All-pay Auctions for Charity: Experimental Evidence∗ Joshua Fostery Economics Department University of Wisconsin - Oshkosh August 30, 2017 Abstract All-pay auctions have demonstrated an extraordinary ability at raising money for charity. One mechanism in particular is the war of attrition, which frequently generates revenue well beyond what is theoretically predicted with rational bidders. However, what motivates the behavioral response in bidders remains unclear. By imposing charity auction incentives in the laboratory, this paper uses controlled experiments to consider the effects of loss aversion and sunk cost sensitivity on bidders’ willingness to contribute. The results indicate that revenues in incremental bidding mechanisms, such as the war of attrition, rely heavily on bidders who are sunk cost sensitive. It is shown this behavioral response can be easily curbed with a commitment device which drastically lowers contributions below theoretical predictions. A separate behavioral response due to loss aversion is found in the sealed-bid first-price all-pay auction, which reduces bidders’ willingness to contribute. These findings help explain the inconsistencies in revenues from previous all-pay auction studies and indicate a mechanism preference based on the distribution of these behavioral characteristics. Keywords: Auctions, Market Design, Charitable Giving JEL Classification: C92, D03, D44, D64 ∗I would like to thank Cary Deck, Amy Farmer, Jeffrey Carpenter, Salar Jahedi, Li Hao, and seminar participants at the University of Arkansas, ESA World Meetings, ESA North America Meetings, and the SEA Annual Meetings for their helpful comments at various stages of the development of this project. yContact the author at [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • Auction Theory
    Auction Theory Jonathan Levin October 2004 Our next topic is auctions. Our objective will be to cover a few of the main ideas and highlights. Auction theory can be approached from different angles – from the perspective of game theory (auctions are bayesian games of incomplete information), contract or mechanism design theory (auctions are allocation mechanisms), market microstructure (auctions are models of price formation), as well as in the context of different applications (procure- ment, patent licensing, public finance, etc.). We’re going to take a relatively game-theoretic approach, but some of this richness should be evident. 1 The Independent Private Value (IPV) Model 1.1 A Model The basic auction environment consists of: Bidders i =1,...,n • Oneobjecttobesold • Bidder i observes a “signal” Si F ( ), with typical realization si • [s, s], and assume F is continuous.∼ · ∈ Bidders’ signals S1,...,Sn are independent. • Bidder i’s value vi(si)=si. • Given this basic set-up, specifying a set of auction rules will give rise to a game between the bidders. Before going on, observe two features of the model that turn out to be important. First, bidder i’s information (her signal) is independent of bidder j’s information. Second, bidder i’s value is independent of bidder j’s information – so bidder j’s information is private in the sense that it doesn’t affect anyone else’s valuation. 1 1.2 Vickrey (Second-Price) Auction In a Vickrey, or second price, auction, bidders are asked to submit sealed bids b1,...,bn. The bidder who submits the highest bid is awarded the object, and pays the amount of the second highest bid.
    [Show full text]
  • Should First-Price Auctions Be Transparent?∗
    Should First-Price Auctions be Transparent?∗ Dirk Bergemann† Johannes H¨orner‡ April 7, 2017 Abstract We investigate the role of market transparency in repeated first-price auctions. We consider a setting with independent private and persistent values. We analyze three distinct disclosure regimes regarding the bid and award history. In the minimal disclosure regime each bidder only learns privately whether he won or lost the auction. In equilibrium the allocation is efficient and the minimal disclosure regime does not give rise to pooling equilibria. In contrast, in disclosure settings where either all or only the winner’s bids are public, an inefficient pooling equilibrium with low revenues exists. ∗We gratefully acknowledge financial support from NSF SES 0851200 and ICES 1215808. We thank the co- editor, Phil Reny, and two anonymous referees, for helpful comments and suggestions. We are grateful to seminar participants at the NBER Market Design Meeting, University of Mannheim, University of Munich and the University of Pennsylvania for their constructive comments. Lastly, thanks to Yi Chen for excellent research assistance. †Department of Economics, Yale University, New Haven, CT 06511, [email protected] ‡Department of Economics, Yale University, New Haven, CT 06511, [email protected] 1 1 Introduction 1.1 Motivation Information revelation policies vary widely across auction formats. In the U.S. procurement context, as a consequence of the “Freedom of Information Act,” the public sector is generally subject to strict transparency requirements that require full disclosure of the identity of the bidders and the terms of each bid. In auctions of mineral rights to U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Is the `Linkage Principle' Valid?: Evidence from the Field
    Center for Economic Institutions Working Paper Series No. 2010-4 “Is the ’Linkage Principle’ Valid?: Evidence from the Field” Sung-Jin Cho, Harry J. Paarsch and John Rust November 2010 Center for Economic Institutions Working Paper Series Institute of Economic Research Hitotsubashi University 2-1 Naka, Kunitachi, Tokyo, 186-8603 JAPAN http://cei.ier.hit-u.ac.jp/English/index.html Tel:+81-42-580-8405/Fax:+81-42-580-8333 Paper for Discussion: first draft, 19 December 2009; this draft, November 27, 2010. IS THE `LINKAGE PRINCIPLE' VALID?: EVIDENCE FROM THE FIELD BY SUNG-JIN CHO, HARRY J. PAARSCH, AND JOHN RUST Seoul National University, University of Melbourne, and University of Maryland We present field evidence involving experienced bidders that supports the link- age principle—specifically, the prediction that in affiliated-values auction environments the expected revenues generated at open-outcry, ascending-bid (English) auctions are higher than those under other auction formats that reveal less information to partic- ipants. Using field data from a large seller of automobiles which experimented with different selling formats, we find that the seller’s average revenues were significantly higher under an English auction than under a dynamic Internet auction that revealed far less information to bidders. 1. Introduction and Motivation. In an influential and classic paper, Milgrom and Weber [1982] de- rived a powerful result, and coined the term linkage principle to describe it. Simply put, in auction environ- ments having affiliated values, the linkage principle states that a seller can expect to increase revenues by providing more information to bidders, both before and during the auction.
    [Show full text]
  • Design of a Multi-Unit Double Auction E-Market
    Design of a Multi-unit Double Auction E-Market Pu Huang Center for Automated Learning and Discovery School of Computer Science Carnegie Mellon University Pittsburgh, PA 15213 [email protected] Alan Scheller-Wolf Graduate School of Industrial Administration Carnegie Mellon University Pittsburgh, PA 15213 [email protected] Katia Sycara The Robotics Institute Carnegie Mellon University Pittsburgh, PA 15213 [email protected] ¡ This paper has been accepted for publication in Computational Intelligence. 1 Abstract We envision a future economy where e-markets will play an essential role as exchange hubs for commodities and services. Future e-markets should be designed to be robust to manipu- lation, flexible, and sufficiently efficient in facilitating exchanges. One of the most important aspects of designing an e-market is market mechanism design. A market mechanism defines the organization, information exchange process, trading procedure and clearance rules of a market. If we view an e-market as a multi-agent system, the market mechanism also defines the structure and rules of the environment in which agents (buyers and sellers) play the market game. We design an e-market mechanism that is strategy-proof with respect to reservation price, weakly budget-balanced and individually rational. Our mechanism also makes sellers unlikely to under-report the supply volume to drive up the market price. In addition, by bound- ing our market’s efficiency loss, we provide fairly unrestrictive sufficient conditions for the efficiency of our mechanism to converge in a strong sense when (1) the number of agents who successfully trade is large, or (2) the number of agents, trading and not, is large.
    [Show full text]
  • Experiments in Market Design This (Still-Missing-A-Few-Parts, Put Readable Through P61) Draft: January 2012
    Experiments in Market Design This (still-missing-a-few-parts, put readable through p61) draft: January 2012 Design: Noun: the arrangement of elements or details Verb: to create or construct 1. Introduction The phrase ―market design‖ has come to include the design not only of marketplaces but also of other economic environments, institutions and allocation rules. And it includes not only the design of new institutions ("design" as a verb) but also renewed attention to how the design of economic institutions ("design" as a noun) influences their performance. It is both one of the oldest and one of the newest areas of experimental economics. It is one of the oldest because every economic experiment involves the design of an economic environment, and many experiments compare the effects of different designs. And it is one of the newest because only since the 1990‘s have economists become regularly involved in the detailed design of marketplaces and other economic institutions in ways that have led from the initial conception all the way to the adoption and implementation of practical new designs (and to the beginnings of a new scientific literature of market design). This new usefulness of market design has brought new uses for experiments. To see that market design has always played a role in experimental economics, note that when Chamberlain (1948) sought to investigate competitive equilibrium, he designed not only the kind of marketplace (pairwise negotiation) that he wished to investigate; he also developed the technique that has since been widely used to induce particular supply and demand conditions, by giving each buyer and seller the prices and quantities at which they could in effect sell to or buy from the experimenter to fulfill any trades they made.1 1 Thus e.g.
    [Show full text]
  • On Framework and Hybrid Auction Approach to the Spectrum
    On Framework and Hybrid Auction Approach to the Spectrum Licensing Procedure Devansh Dikshit Y. Narahari Electronic Commerce Laboratory, Dept. of Computer Science and Automation, Indian Institute Science, Bangalore, India. Email: {devansh},{hari}@csa.iisc.ernet.in November 13, 2018 Abstract few years, many private parties have entered in the field of telecommunications. And as expected they require a slice Inspired by the recent developments in the field of Spec- of spectrum for that purpose. This also provides a wonder- trum Auctions, we have tried to provide a comprehensive ful opportunityfor the governmentas there is useable spec- framework for the complete procedure of Spectrum trum which is left unused with the government, with only Licensing. We have identified the various issues the a fraction of it being used for military and civil purposes Governments need to decide upon while designing the by the governments. The amount of this spectrum is usu- licensing procedure and what are the various options ally scarce hence the greater demand-supply gap. Along available in each issue. We also provide an in depth study with generating revenues, privatization of spectrum will of how each of this options impact the overall procedure also lead to a faster pace of developmentby the private par- along with theoretical and practical results from the past. ties which may not be always possible to do by the govern- Lastly we argue as to how we can combine the positives ment. This has lead to the sale/licensing of the spectrums two most widely used Spectrum Auctions mechanisms by various countries across the globe, using methods like into the Hybrid Multiple Round Auction mechanism being lotteries, auctions, tenders etc.
    [Show full text]
  • Making Auctions Work: the Winning Ideas Behind This Year's Nobel Prize
    Making auctions work: the winning ideas behind this year’s Nobel Prize in economics October 13, 2020 10.20am AEDT Author John Hawkins Senior Lecturer, Canberra School of Politics, Economics and Society, University of Canberra More than ever before, auctions shape the economy. Sites such as eBay have made them an everyday transaction. The placement of every Google ad is priced by an instantaneous mini-auction. Governments use them to allocate radio spectrum and to run emissions trading schemes. The 2020 Nobel Prize in economics has been awarded to two Americans, Paul Milgrom and Robert Wilson, for their work in analysing auctions and how to make them more efficient. The two professors are close collaborators. They both work at Stanford University in California and also live on the same street. The economics prize is not one of the original categories endowed from Alfred Nobel’s will. Its formal name is the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in memory of Alfred Nobel. The winners are selected by the same Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences that awards the prizes for physics and chemistry. Milgrom and Wilson work in various areas of economics (notably game theory) but are best known for their work in market design. Milgrom was awarded his PhD from Stanford in 1978, where he was one of Wilson’s students. The American Economics Association has described Milgrom as the world’s leading auction designer. His work has been cited more than 100,000 times. The winner’s curse The Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences has emphasised that Milgrom and Wilson have won the award for both their theoretical work and its practical application in auctions.
    [Show full text]
  • Tacit Collusion in Oligopolies and Regulated Industries That Underlie This Thesis
    TACIT COLLUSION IN OLIGOPOLIES AND REGULATED INDUSTRIES Zur Erlangung des akademischen Grades eines Doktors der Wirtschaftswissenschaften (Dr. rer. pol.) von der Fakultät für Wirtschaftswissenschaften am Karlsruher Institut für Technologie (KIT) genehmigte DISSERTATION von Niklas Horstmann B. Sc. Tag der mündlichen Prüfung: 20. Mai 2016 Referent: Prof. Dr. Jan Krämer Korreferent: Prof. Dr. Karl-Martin Ehrhart Karlsruhe, 2016 Acknowledgements I am deeply grateful to my advisor Prof. Dr. Jan Krämer who always knew when to encourage and when to challenge me. He has not only been my mentor but also has become a dear friend. I am also indebted to Prof. Dr. Christof Weinhardt for the opportunity to pursue my scientific ambitions. My sincere thanks go to my co-advisor Prof. Dr. Karl-Martin Ehrhart for inspiring comments as well as to Prof. Dr. Kay Mitusch and Prof. Dr. Martin Ruckes for serving on the board of examiners. My sincere appreciation goes to all my colleagues. In particular, I thank Marc Adam for satirical references, Christoph Flath for informative exchanges on politics, Felix Fritz for working weekend chats, Johannes Gärttner for entertaining conversations, Anuja Hari- haran for exciting insights into Indian culture, Philip Köhler for his infectious cheerful- ness, Tobias Kranz for passionate debates, Ewa Lux for making my time at the institute even more memorable and for proofreading this thesis, Marius Müller for diverting discussions, Claudia Niemeyer for her joviality, Thomas Setzer for his dry sense of hu- mor, Daniel Schnurr for close and long-term collaboration, Alexander Schuller for his cooperative nature, Philipp Ströhle for brief glimpses into other research areas, Timm Teubner for constructive feedback, and Lukas Wiewiorra for helpful advice.
    [Show full text]
  • Optimal and Near-Optimal Mechanism Design with Interdependent Values
    Proceedings Article Optimal and Near-Optimal Mechanism Design with Interdependent Values TIM ROUGHGARDEN, Stanford University INBAL TALGAM-COHEN, Stanford University We study optimal and approximately-optimal mechanism design questions in the interdependent values model, which generalizes the standard setting of independent and private values. We focus our attention on ex post incentive compatible and individually rational mechanisms, and develop an analog of Myerson's optimal auction theory that applies to many interdependent settings of interest. We demonstrate two ap- plications for specific interdependent settings: First, a parallel result to the well-known optimality of the second-price auction with reserve for i.i.d. bidders, where the English auction replaces the second-price one. Second, we identify good prior-independent auctions | auctions with near-optimal expected revenue across a wide range of priors | for certain interdependent value settings. Categories and Subject Descriptors: [Theory of Computation]: Algorithmic game theory and mechanism design Additional Key Words and Phrases: interdependence; optimal auctions; prior-independence 1. INTRODUCTION The subject of this paper is optimal and approximately-optimal mechanism design, where bidders have interdependent values, and the mechanism has ex post incentive compatibility and individual rationality guarantees. Economic research on auctions has explored different valuation models over the past decades, which can roughly be divided into private versus interdependent values (for exam- ple, see [Krishna 2010, Chapters 2-5] versus [Krishna 2010, Chapters 6-10]). The more nacent research effort in theoretical computer science has focused largely on the restricted setting of independent private values, recently also venturing into the realm of correlated private values [Papadimitriou and Pierrakos 2011; Dobzinski et al.
    [Show full text]
  • Pilot Auction Facility for Methane and Climate Change Mitigation: Relevant Environmental Auctions
    PILOT AUCTION FACILITY FOR METHANE AND CLIMATE CHANGE MITIGATION: RELEVANT ENVIRONMENTAL AUCTIONS Lawrence M. Ausubel, Peter Cramton, Christina Aperjis and Daniel N. Hauser 14 July 2014 Pilot Auction Facility for Methane and Climate Change Mitigation Contents 1. Introduction ............................................................................................................................. 1 2. Carbon Auctions ...................................................................................................................... 2 2.1 UK Emission Trading Scheme Auction ............................................................................ 2 2.2 Carbon Markets .............................................................................................................. 2 2.3 Auction Format ............................................................................................................... 4 2.4 Experimental Work ......................................................................................................... 4 2.5 Auction Results ............................................................................................................... 5 2.6 Carbon Trading ................................................................................................................ 7 2.7 Lessons Learned .............................................................................................................. 7 3. Other Auctions ........................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Seller Cheap Talk in Common Value Auctions∗
    Seller cheap talk in common value auctions∗ Archishman Chakraborty† Nandini Gupta‡ Rick Harbaugh§ April 2003 Abstract Sellers benefit on average from revealing information about their goods to buyers, but the incentive to exaggerate undermines the credibility of seller statements. When multiple goods are being auctioned, we show that revealing a complete or partial ordering of the different goods by value can be credible. Ordinal cheap talk of this form is not susceptible to exaggeration because it simultaneously reveals favorable information about some goods and unfavorable information about other goods. Any informative ordering increases revenues in accordance with the linkage principle, and the complete ordering is asymptotically revenue- equivalent to full revelation as the number of goods becomes large. These results provide a new explanation in addition to bundling, complementarities, and versioning for how a seller benefitsfromthesaleofmultiplegoods. JEL Classification: D44, D82, L15. Key Words: linkage principle; winner’s curse; cheap talk; common value auction ∗We thank Esther Gal-Or, Ron Harstad, and Timothy Van Zandt for helpful comments. Earlier versions of this paper benefited from presentations at the SED 2000 Conference and the 2000 World Congress of the Econometric Society. †Corresponding author. Baruch College, CUNY, arch [email protected] ‡William Davidson Institute at the University of Michigan Business School, [email protected] §Claremont McKenna College, [email protected] 1Introduction When can a seller credibly reveal information to buyers? The linkage principle (Milgrom and Weber, 1982) shows that such revelation strengthens competition and, on average, increases seller revenues by narrowing information differences among buyers. But the importance of the linkage principle would seem limited by the seller’s incentive to only reveal good information or even lie about bad information.
    [Show full text]