Privatization and the Transition to a Market Economy

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Privatization and the Transition to a Market Economy Chinese President Jiang Zemin announced Privatization and the in late 1997 that his nation would soon privatize thousands of state-owned enterprises. The pre- Transition to a cise meaning of privatization in the Chinese context is open to debate: one deputy minister explained that the state might retain a majority Market Economy stake in the firms, and the editor of a commu- nist newspaper said that expectations of a Jason L. Saving Economist Western-style ownership structure in the firms Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas had arisen from a “misunderstanding” (Lyle 1997). Still, while information is scarce about the details of the Chinese plan, it is clear that any privatization effort in the world’s most pop- ulous country could have a major impact on the global economy. Given the distinct possibility of massive An effective privatization privatization in China, it is natural to reexamine economic reform in the postcommunist nations must transfer ownership in of Eastern Europe and determine what lessons may be drawn for China. The reform process in such a way that the new these nations has been substantial: the private- sector contribution to gross domestic product private-sector owners and (GDP) now exceeds 50 percent in nineteen of the twenty-six states that once formed the Soviet managers have an incentive to empire (European Bank for Reconstruction and Development 1997), including each of the maximize profit, and this Eastern European states outside the volatile Balkan region (Table 1).1 The short-term pain incentive must be reinforced caused by economic reform has generally given way to significant gains in per capita GDP by a legal structure that (Figure 1) and the possibility of membership in multilateral institutions such as the European encourages private-sector Union and NATO.2 But can any lessons from the competition for these firms. Table 1 Share of GDP Derived from Private Sources 1980 1988 1994 1997 Czech Republic <1.0 <1.0 65 75 Hungary 3.5 7.1 55 75 Poland 15.6* 18.8* 55 65 Romania 4.5 — 35 60 Russia <1.0 <1.0 50 70 Slovakia <1.0 <1.0 55 75 United States 79.4 79.6 81.1 82.0 * This is almost exclusively agricultural production (Slay 1993). NOTE: Czechoslovakia dissolved in 1993 and was replaced by Slovakia and the Czech Republic. SOURCES: Patterson 1993; European Bank for Reconstruction and Development 1994, 1997; Bureau of Economic Analysis. FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS 17 ECONOMIC REVIEW FOURTH QUARTER 1998 Figure 1 support” (Bird 1998), and it is estimated that Real GDP Per Capita one-sixth of Albania’s population may become U.S. dollars bankrupt because of investments in pyramid 6,000 Hungary Poland schemes (Percival 1997). Such examples suggest Czech Republic Romania that economic education may be important to 5,000 Slovakia the success of privatization. In addition, formerly communist citizen- 4,000 ries face special problems in attempting to eval- 3,000 uate the net worth of to-be-privatized firms. Balance sheets for such firms were not kept 2,000 according to Western norms, often deliberately, so as to shield the poor performance of high- 1,000 ranking party functionaries who were appointed as managers during the communist era but wish 0 to retain their positions after privatization 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 (Brada 1996, Tirole 1994). Moreover, the divi- sion of assets among such companies is not experiences of these Eastern European nations clearly delineated, so that a potential investor be applied to other countries embarking on the during the transition period could not be certain road of economic reform? Also, was the road to which assets would end up with a company and privatization in these nations paved with serious which would remain with the state (Bolton and mistakes others might be able to avoid? Roland 1992). In addition, the transition to a In discussing these questions, it is impor- market economy would almost certainly cause tant to define precisely what is meant by priva- an enormous reallocation of resources across tization. While privatization occurs whenever sectors of the economy, making it difficult for the ownership of a firm is transferred from the citizens to gauge a firm’s future performance government to the private sector, the purpose even if communist-era balance sheets were of this transfer is to help create a competitive available. economic environment in which firms strive to A final problem relates to communist-era increase efficiency and maximize profit. Thus, informational asymmetries between the ordi- an effective privatization must transfer owner- nary citizen and the party elite. Information is a ship in such a way that the new private-sector closely guarded commodity under communist owners and managers have an incentive to maxi- systems, and government officials commonly mize profit, and this incentive must be rein- possess an enormous amount of information of forced by a legal structure that encourages which ordinary citizens are unaware (Blanchard private-sector competition for these firms. These and Layard 1992). In the aftermath of commu- are the issues this article discusses. nism, then, a citizen’s information about state- run enterprises would be primarily a function of past affiliations with a now-discredited state. INFORMATION AND PRIVATIZATION IN PRACTICE This implies that the group of citizens best able In theory, privatization is a relatively sim- to evaluate the profit potential of state-run firms ple process in which potential investors evalu- is composed of precisely those individuals society ate the profit potential of each firm, choose would least like to prosper. those in which to acquire shares, and then man- Yet there is widespread agreement that age the firms in a way that maximizes their shares in state-owned enterprises should be return.3 In practice, however, this model suffers given to the public whose efforts created the from limitations when applied to the transition enterprises. These “mass privatization” programs from communism to a market economy. In gen- are regarded as the most egalitarian method of eral, formerly communist citizenries are likely privatization because each citizen profits from to be less familiar with market economics than them (Grime and Duke 1993). Also, giving each their capitalist counterparts, and some commen- citizen a stake in privatization increases public tators have suggested that this unfamiliarity support for the program and reduces the gov- could lead them to make bad investment deci- ernment’s ability to renege on its privatization sions (Brada 1992). This perception is not with- commitments (see the box entitled “Credible out foundation. For example, a 1998 Moldovan Commitments and Privatization”). newspaper headline marveled that the “private Is there a socially optimal distribution of sector survives even though it gets no state ownership shares when ordinary citizens are 18 Credible Commitments and Privatization Privatization helps promote economic growth by ensuring that firm owners have unable to evaluate the prospective financial per- an incentive to maximize profit. However, one important aspect of any privatization formance of state-run enterprises but commu- program is the possibility of revocation (Weingast 1995). Unless those who become nist functionaries are capable of making such owners of privatized enterprises believe the government will allow them to keep the evaluations? Perhaps surprisingly, there are fruits of their labors, there is little reason to believe these owners will invest time and effort in their enterprises. some conditions under which this question can The importance of political commitment to the privatization process can be illus- be answered in the affirmative. For example, trated through an examination of Russia’s New Economic Policy.* Shortly after the suppose that shares are to be divided among communist takeover of 1917, Bolshevik leaders confiscated private farmland in what the citizenry subject to three conditions: they called the “crusade for bread.” Though the peasantry was ordered to continue 1. Every share must be distributed to a cit- working the fields, all farm output would go to the state rather than the workers. This policy reduced peasant effort to such an extent that mass starvation ensued, fol- izen. lowed by peasant riots that began to threaten the survival of the Bolshevik regime. In 2. The expected profit of each citizen response, Lenin introduced a partial privatization of farmland and a partial restora- must be equal. tion of farmers’ right to sell excess produce to ordinary Russians, arguing that peas- 3. The risk (variance) borne by each citi- ants would not work at maximum efficiency unless they were able to reap the zen must be equal and must be as low rewards of their labors. But would the communist regime—which had previously viewed private prop- as possible, subject to all other condi- erty as anathema—be willing to commit to the New Economic Policy for the foresee- tions. able future? Nove (1992) recounts the words of a communist official who complained Only one portfolio of shares meets these New Economic Policy supporters “demand of us a promise that we will never, i.e. not three criteria: a distribution in which each citi- in 15 or 20 years, confiscate or expropriate” farmland, to encourage peasant farmers zen receives an equal percentage of each enter- to work without fear that the state would seize their crops and confiscate their land. This the official refused to do: in his words, expropriation of farmland by the state 4 prise. Moreover, such a distribution can be would occur “when the time comes for so doing.” implemented even if those in charge of privati- The productivity gains from the New Economic Policy were short-lived, partly zation cannot evaluate the financial viability of because of these fears. Farmland was then reconfiscated in a new effort to abolish state-owned firms—an important consideration private farming.
Recommended publications
  • Chinese Privatization: Between Plan and Market
    CHINESE PRIVATIZATION: BETWEEN PLAN AND MARKET LAN CAO* I INTRODUCTION Since 1978, when China adopted its open-door policy and allowed its economy to be exposed to the international market, it has adhered to what Deng Xiaoping called "socialism with Chinese characteristics."1 As a result, it has produced an economy with one of the most rapid growth rates in the world by steadfastly embarking on a developmental strategy of gradual, market-oriented measures while simultaneously remaining nominally socialistic. As I discuss in this article, this strategy of reformthe mere adoption of a market economy while retaining a socialist ownership baseshould similarly be characterized as "privatization with Chinese characteristics,"2 even though it departs markedly from the more orthodox strategy most commonly associated with the term "privatization," at least as that term has been conventionally understood in the context of emerging market or transitional economies. The Russian experience of privatization, for example, represents the more dominant and more favored approach to privatizationcertainly from the point of view of the West and its advisersand is characterized by immediate privatization of the state sector, including the swift and unequivocal transfer of assets from the publicly owned state enterprises to private hands. On the other hand, "privatization with Chinese characteristics" emphasizes not the immediate privatization of the state sector but rather the retention of the state sector with the Copyright © 2001 by Lan Cao This article is also available at http://www.law.duke.edu/journals/63LCPCao. * Professor of Law, College of William and Mary Marshall-Wythe School of Law. At the time the article was written, the author was Professor of Law at Brooklyn Law School.
    [Show full text]
  • Public Choice: Substance Depends Upon Process
    Rural Development, Privatization and Public Choice: Substance Depends upon Process James Hite’ Abstract Whether or not privatization facilitates rural development depends upon what rural development means. In practice, rural development often is the result of a struggle between rent defenders and rent seekers. A positivist concept of rural development is proposed, and the institutions of public choice are examined to determine how they might influence privatization decisions. The conclusion is that whether or not privatization improves efficiencyof adjustmentin rural economies depends upon the specifics of political deals required to achieve a particular act of privatization. Key words: privatization, rural development, public choice, rent-seeking Introduction development itself. In attempting to do so, privatization, which is a topic worthy of Privatization is a term applied to a political considerable discussion on its own, receives process whereby local and even state governments somewhat secondary treatment. across the United States spin off certain services to private sector operatives. This term is also applied Summarized briefly, the argument advanced to the process by which the Thatcher government in in this paper is as follows: rural development can the United Kingdom devolved to private investors be thought of positivistically, as well as certain industries previously nationalized by Labor normatively. Positivistically, rural development is an governments, and it is the popular term applied to observable, potentially predictable process of the process of transforming Russia and its former adjustment on the part of rural economies to satellite nations into market economies (Vickers and Schumpeterian change in a market system. It is in Yarrow 1988; 1991). Ostensibly this paper is about the material interest of society that this process of privatization and rural development.
    [Show full text]
  • Econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Schrader, Jörg-Volker Working Paper — Digitized Version Agricultural finance in Central and Eastern European Countries (CEEC): The case of Poland Kiel Working Paper, No. 735 Provided in Cooperation with: Kiel Institute for the World Economy (IfW) Suggested Citation: Schrader, Jörg-Volker (1996) : Agricultural finance in Central and Eastern European Countries (CEEC): The case of Poland, Kiel Working Paper, No. 735, Kiel Institute of World Economics (IfW), Kiel This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/47197 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort
    [Show full text]
  • The Neoliberal Privatization in Kosovë: a Deconstructed Myth
    Rochester Institute of Technology RIT Scholar Works Theses 2-13-2015 The Neoliberal Privatization in Kosovë: A Deconstructed Myth Edison Jakurti Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.rit.edu/theses Recommended Citation Jakurti, Edison, "The Neoliberal Privatization in Kosovë: A Deconstructed Myth" (2015). Thesis. Rochester Institute of Technology. Accessed from This Senior Project is brought to you for free and open access by RIT Scholar Works. It has been accepted for inclusion in Theses by an authorized administrator of RIT Scholar Works. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Student: Edison Jakurti Supervisor: Michele Pomberg Title: The Neoliberal Privatization in Kosovë: A Deconstructed Myth Date of Submission: February 2015 Keywords: 1. Kosovë 2. Privatization 3. Neoliberalism 4. Post and Telecommunications of Kosovo (PTK) 5. Kosovo Electricity Distribution and Supply (KEDS) Submitted to A.U.K. as part of requirement for graduation The Neoliberal Privatization in Kosovë: A Deconstructed Myth Honors Society Project Presented to The Academic Faculty By Edison Jakurti In Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for Membership in the Honors Society of the American University in Kosovo Acknowledgments I want to thank and acknowledge everyone who has helped me to complete this project. Specifically, I want to thank my professor and my project supervisor, Michele Pomberg, PhD, whose patience and advice have greatly contributed to the improvement and successful completion of this work. Each passing day enforced my belief that choosing Professor Pomberg as my project adviser was the right decision. This work would have not been at this state without the professional advice and motivation by my professor and technical advisor, Mrika Kotorri, PhD.
    [Show full text]
  • A Critique of John Stuart Mill Chris Daly
    Southern Illinois University Carbondale OpenSIUC Honors Theses University Honors Program 5-2002 The Boundaries of Liberalism in a Global Era: A Critique of John Stuart Mill Chris Daly Follow this and additional works at: http://opensiuc.lib.siu.edu/uhp_theses Recommended Citation Daly, Chris, "The Boundaries of Liberalism in a Global Era: A Critique of John Stuart Mill" (2002). Honors Theses. Paper 131. This Dissertation/Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the University Honors Program at OpenSIUC. It has been accepted for inclusion in Honors Theses by an authorized administrator of OpenSIUC. For more information, please contact [email protected]. r The Boundaries of Liberalism in a Global Era: A Critique of John Stuart Mill Chris Daly May 8, 2002 r ABSTRACT The following study exanunes three works of John Stuart Mill, On Liberty, Utilitarianism, and Three Essays on Religion, and their subsequent effects on liberalism. Comparing the notion on individual freedom espoused in On Liberty to the notion of the social welfare in Utilitarianism, this analysis posits that it is impossible for a political philosophy to have two ultimate ends. Thus, Mill's liberalism is inherently flawed. As this philosophy was the foundation of Mill's progressive vision for humanity that he discusses in his Three Essays on Religion, this vision becomes paradoxical as well. Contending that the neo-liberalist global economic order is the contemporary parallel for Mill's religion of humanity, this work further demonstrates how these philosophical flaws have spread to infect the core of globalization in the 21 st century as well as their implications for future international relations.
    [Show full text]
  • Some Worries About the Coherence of Left-Libertarianism Mathias Risse
    John F. Kennedy School of Government Harvard University Faculty Research Working Papers Series Can There be “Libertarianism without Inequality”? Some Worries About the Coherence of Left-Libertarianism Mathias Risse Nov 2003 RWP03-044 The views expressed in the KSG Faculty Research Working Paper Series are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect those of the John F. Kennedy School of Government or Harvard University. All works posted here are owned and copyrighted by the author(s). Papers may be downloaded for personal use only. Can There be “Libertarianism without Inequality”? Some Worries About the Coherence of Left-Libertarianism1 Mathias Risse John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University October 25, 2003 1. Left-libertarianism is not a new star on the sky of political philosophy, but it was through the recent publication of Peter Vallentyne and Hillel Steiner’s anthologies that it became clearly visible as a contemporary movement with distinct historical roots. “Left- libertarian theories of justice,” says Vallentyne, “hold that agents are full self-owners and that natural resources are owned in some egalitarian manner. Unlike most versions of egalitarianism, left-libertarianism endorses full self-ownership, and thus places specific limits on what others may do to one’s person without one’s permission. Unlike right- libertarianism, it holds that natural resources may be privately appropriated only with the permission of, or with a significant payment to, the members of society. Like right- libertarianism, left-libertarianism holds that the basic rights of individuals are ownership rights. Left-libertarianism is promising because it coherently underwrites both some demands of material equality and some limits on the permissible means of promoting this equality” (Vallentyne and Steiner (2000a), p 1; emphasis added).
    [Show full text]
  • Privatization of Public Social Services a Background Paper Demetra Smith Nightingale, Nancy M
    Privatization of Public Social Services A Background Paper Demetra Smith Nightingale, Nancy M. Pindus This paper was prepared at the Urban Institute for U.S. Department of Labor, Office of the Assistant Secretary for Document date: October 15, 1997 Policy, under DOL Contract No. J-9-M-5-0048, #15. Released online: October 15, 1997 Opinions expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the positions of DOL, the Urban Institute or its sponsors. The views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of the Urban Institute, its board, its sponsors, or other authors in the series 1. Introduction The purposes of the paper are to provide a general overview of the extent of privatization of public services in the areas of social services, welfare, and employment; rationales for privatizing service delivery, and evidence of effectiveness or problems. Examples are included to highlight specific types of privatization and actual operational experience. The paper is not intended to be a comprehensive treatment of the overall subject of privatization, but rather a brief review of issues and experiences specifically related to the delivery of employment and training, welfare, and social services. The key points that are drawn from a review of the literature are: There is no single definition of privatization. Privatization covers a broad range of methods and models, including contracting out for services, voucher programs, and even the sale of public assets to the private sector. But for the purposes of this paper, privatization refers to the provision of publicly-funded services and activities by non-governmental entities.
    [Show full text]
  • Transforming Government Through Privatization
    20th Anniversary Edition Annual Privatization Report 2006 Transforming Government Through Privatization Reflections from Pioneers in Government Reform Prime Minister Margaret Thatcher Governor Mitch Daniels Governor Mark Sanford Robert W. Poole, Jr. Reason Foundation Reason Foundation’s mission is to advance a free society by developing, apply- ing, and promoting libertarian principles, including individual liberty, free markets, and the rule of law. We use journalism and public policy research to influence the frameworks and actions of policymakers, journalists, and opin- ion leaders. Reason Foundation’s nonpartisan public policy research promotes choice, competition, and a dynamic market economy as the foundation for human dignity and prog- ress. Reason produces rigorous, peer-reviewed research and directly engages the policy pro- cess, seeking strategies that emphasize cooperation, flexibility, local knowledge, and results. Through practical and innovative approaches to complex problems, Reason seeks to change the way people think about issues, and promote policies that allow and encourage individuals and voluntary institutions to flourish. Reason Foundation is a tax-exempt research and education organization as defined under IRS code 501(c)(3). Reason Foundation is supported by voluntary contributions from individuals, foundations, and corporations. The views expressed in these essays are those of the individual author, not necessarily those of Reason Foundation or its trustees. Copyright © 2006 Reason Foundation. Photos used in this publication are copyright © 1996 Photodisc, Inc. All rights reserved. Authors Editor the Association of Private Correctional & Treatment Organizations • Leonard C. Gilroy • Chris Edwards is the director of Tax Principal Authors Policy Studies at the Cato Institute • Ted Balaker • William D. Eggers is the global director • Shikha Dalmia for Deloitte Research—Public Sector • Leonard C.
    [Show full text]
  • Privatization and Property in Biology Joan E
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Washington University St. Louis: Open Scholarship Washington University in St. Louis Washington University Open Scholarship Biology Faculty Publications & Presentations Biology 6-2014 Privatization and Property in Biology Joan E. Strassmann Washington University in St Louis, [email protected] David C. Queller Washington University in St Louis, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://openscholarship.wustl.edu/bio_facpubs Part of the Behavior and Ethology Commons, and the Biology Commons Recommended Citation Strassmann, Joan E. and Queller, David C., "Privatization and Property in Biology" (2014). Biology Faculty Publications & Presentations. 49. https://openscholarship.wustl.edu/bio_facpubs/49 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Biology at Washington University Open Scholarship. It has been accepted for inclusion in Biology Faculty Publications & Presentations by an authorized administrator of Washington University Open Scholarship. For more information, please contact [email protected]. 1 Privatization and property in biology 2 3 Joan E. Strassmann & David C. Queller 4 5 Department of Biology, Campus Box 1137 6 WasHington University in St. Louis 7 One Brookings Drive 8 St. Louis MO 63130 9 10 Corresponding autHor: Joan E. Strassmann 11 phone: 01-832-978-5961 12 email: [email protected] 13 14 6191 words 1 15 ABSTRACT 16 17 Organisms evolve to control, preserve, protect and invest in their own bodies. When 18 they do likewise with external resources they privatize those resources and convert 19 tHem into tHeir own property. Property is a neglected topic in biology, though 20 examples include territories, domiciles and nest structures, food cacHing, mate 21 guarding, and the resources and partners in mutualisms.
    [Show full text]
  • Corporation Involvement in Prison Labor and the Privatization of the Prison System Alythea S
    The University of San Francisco USF Scholarship: a digital repository @ Gleeson Library | Geschke Center Master's Projects and Capstones Theses, Dissertations, Capstones and Projects 12-2015 Incentives to Incarcerate: Corporation Involvement in Prison Labor and the Privatization of the Prison System Alythea S. Morrell University of San Francisco, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.usfca.edu/capstone Part of the Civil Rights and Discrimination Commons, Human Rights Law Commons, Law and Race Commons, Political Science Commons, Sociology Commons, and the United States History Commons Recommended Citation Morrell, Alythea S., "Incentives to Incarcerate: Corporation Involvement in Prison Labor and the Privatization of the Prison System" (2015). Master's Projects and Capstones. 263. https://repository.usfca.edu/capstone/263 This Project/Capstone is brought to you for free and open access by the Theses, Dissertations, Capstones and Projects at USF Scholarship: a digital repository @ Gleeson Library | Geschke Center. It has been accepted for inclusion in Master's Projects and Capstones by an authorized administrator of USF Scholarship: a digital repository @ Gleeson Library | Geschke Center. For more information, please contact [email protected]. University of San Francisco Incentives to Incarcerate: Corporation Involvement in Prison Labor and the Privatization of the Prison System A Field Project Presented to The Faculty of the School of Education International and Multicultural Education Department
    [Show full text]
  • War Markets: the Neoliberal Theory
    WAR MARKETS: THE NEOLIBERAL THEORY AND THE UNITED STATES MILITARY ___________________________________ A Thesis Presented to The College of Arts and Sciences Ohio University ____________________________________ In Partial Fulfillment Of the Requirements for Graduation with Honors in Political Science ____________________________________ by Kiersten Lynn Arnoni June 2011 This thesis has been approved by the Department of Political Science and the College of Arts and Sciences ____________________________________ Professor of Political Science ____________________________________ Dean, College of Arts and Sciences Acknowledgements I would like to thank Dr. Barry Tadlock for his support and guidance as my thesis advisor. Dr. Tadlock’s suggestions were valuable assets to this thesis. Abstract The neoliberal theory threatens permanent damage to American democracy. One guiding principle of theory is that the political marketplace is guided by market rationality. Also concentration of power resets with business and governing elites. As business norms begin to dominate politically, democratic ideals and laws equate only to tools and hurdles. Can the neoliberal theory help explain the situation of privatization and our military? Since the end of the Cold War, military size has been reduced, however, the need for military presence has not. The private war industry has begun to pick up the slack and private contractors have increased in areas needing military support. In Iraq, contractors make up the second largest contingent force, behind the U.S. military. Blackwater, or currently Xe Services LLC, is a powerful organization within the private war industry. Blackwater has accumulated over one billion dollars in contracts with the U.S. government. With the expanding use of private war contractors, their constitutionality comes into question.
    [Show full text]
  • Balcanica Xlii
    BALCANICA XLII BALCANICA XLII, Belgrade 2011, 1– 240 UDC 930.85(4–12) ISSN 0350–7653 SERBIAN ACADEMY OF SCIENCES AND ARTS INSTITUTE FOR BALKAN STUDIES BALCANICA XLII ANNUAL OF THE INSTITUTE FOR BALKAN STUDIES Editor DUŠAN T. BATAKOVIĆ Editorial Board FRANCIS CONTE (Paris), DJORDJE S. KOSTIĆ, LJUBOMIR MAKSIMOVIĆ, DANICA POPOVIĆ, GABRIELLA SCHUBERT (Jena), BILJANA SIKIMIĆ, ANTHONY-EMIL TACHIAOS (Thessaloniki), NIKOLA TASIĆ (Director of the Institute for Balkan Studies), SVETLANA M. TOLSTAJA (Moscow) BELGRADE 2011 Publisher Institute for Balkan Studies Serbian Academy of Sciences and Arts Belgrade, Knez Mihailova 35/IV www.balkaninstitut.com e-mail: [email protected] The origin of the Institute goes back to the Institut des Études balkaniques founded in Belgrade in 1934 as the only of the kind in the Balkans. The initiative came from King Alexander I Karadjordjević, while the Institute’s scholarly profile was created by Ratko Parežanin and Svetozar Spanaćević. The Institute published Revue internationale des Études balkaniques, which assembled most prominent European experts on the Balkans in various disciplines. Its work was banned by the Nazi occupation authorities in 1941. The Institute was not re-established until 1969, under its present-day name and under the auspices of the Serbian Academy of Sciences and Arts. It assembled a team of scholars to cover the Balkans from prehistory to the modern age and in a range of different fields of study, such as archaeology, ethnography, anthropology, history, culture, art, literature, law. This multidisciplinary approach remains its long-term orientation. Director of the Institute for Balkan Studies Nikola Tasić Volume XLII of the annual Balcanica is printed with financial support from the Ministry of Education and Science of the Republic of Serbia CONTENTS ARTICLES HISTORY.
    [Show full text]