Exploring the Heterogeneous Knowledge Spillover Effects from University AI Research on the Creation and Performance of AI Start-Ups

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Exploring the Heterogeneous Knowledge Spillover Effects from University AI Research on the Creation and Performance of AI Start-Ups Exploring the Heterogeneous Knowledge Spillover Effects from University AI Research on the Creation and Performance of AI Start-ups Qi Wang Ke-Wei Huang National University of Singapore National University of Singapore [email protected] [email protected] Abstract This paper investigates whether and which type of AI academic research at universities can create regional knowledge spillover effects that improve the quantity and quality of AI start-ups. Using data of AI start-ups from Crunchbase.com and AI conference publications from CSRankings.com, we find that knowledge spillovers from university AI research indeed contribute to the creation and VC financing performance of local AI start-ups at the MSA level in the United States. Moreover, we find significant heterogeneous effects of knowledge spillovers in different AI subfields. The knowledge spillovers from research published in machine learning conferences, including only ICML and NIPS, have the strongest effects on the creation and performance of AI start-ups. In addition, we find evidence that impactful conferences exhibit stronger spillover effect. At the same time, surprisingly, our results show that knowledge spillovers from theoretical AI research have stronger effects on the creation of start-ups. Keywords: Artificial intelligence, Knowledge Spillovers, Entrepreneurship, Venture Capital, Information Technology 1. Introduction The last two decades have witnessed the rapid advances in artificial intelligence (AI). Recognizing the vital role of AI, more than 17 countries (e.g., the United States, Germany, and China) have implemented policies for promoting AI development at universities. This kind of policy is designed based on the assumption that AI research at universities has positive societal or economic benefits. Academic literature has shown that scientific research in universities has positive spillover effect to the industry R&D because of the public good nature of knowledge (Jaffe 1989). Commercialization of academic research is achieved either by established firms or start-ups. Since only few countries have large established companies with AI R&D capabilities, most governments focused on policy tools to cultivate AI entrepreneurship. At the same time, it is well-known that the start-up failure rate is more than 90%. Therefore, an important question that naturally arises is whether university AI research has positive effect on the creation and survival of AI start-ups. Literature has documented that the accumulation of university knowledge is a key driver of economic growth (Belenzon and Schankerman 2013). Given the importance of university knowledge spillovers, prior literature has focused on the effects of localized knowledge spillovers from universities on regional entrepreneurship. A consistent finding is that university research positively affect local venture creation drawing upon the Knowledge Spillover Theory of Entrepreneurship (Audretsch et al. 2005). However, these studies examined broad spectrum of traditional disciplines (Fritsch and Aamoucke 2017; Jaffe 1989), while AI research has not been the focus of this stream of literature partly due to its nascence. More importantly, the extant literature has provided a limited understanding of which type of AI research has stronger knowledge spillover effects on nearby entrepreneurship. This paper attempts to fill the gaps in the entrepreneurship and innovation literature in the following ways. First, AI is considered as a “general purpose technology” that can drive innovation across sectors (Perrault et al. 2019). In other words, AI is pervasive and can be widely applied in a range of industries. Therefore, AI knowledge is expected to provide unprecedented entrepreneurial opportunities. Although the governments have established the important role of AI research in national AI strategies, there is limited empirical evidence on the relationship between knowledge spillovers from university AI research and entrepreneurship. Second, AI spillover effects deserve special attention also because AI is a broad and interdisciplinary area with many subfields. Existing literature cannot provide information about several important policy questions regarding which type of academic research could create stronger spillover effects. For example, which filed of AI research has the strongest knowledge spillover effects? Whether applied AI research can produce stronger spillover effects than theoretical AI research? A recent study by Akcigit et al. (2021) have shown that over-subsidizing applied research can accentuate the dynamic misallocation in the economy. Thus, we are interested in the differential effects from theoretical and applied AI research. To address these questions, we conduct a nuanced analysis on AI knowledge spillovers and entrepreneurship, and thus providing significant practical implications for policy makers and entrepreneurs. To fill these gaps, this paper investigates whether and which knowledge spillovers from AI research in universities can benefit nearby AI entrepreneurship in terms of the quantity and quality of AI start-ups at the metropolitan statistical areas (MSA) level in the U.S.. In our study, an AI start-up refers to the start-ups that utilize AI-related technologies to develop products or provide services. We will use AI start-ups to refer to the loosely defined AI-related start-ups. Our results indicate that knowledge spillovers from university AI research indeed contribute to the creation and venture capital (VC) financing performance of local AI start-ups. Moreover, we find significant heterogeneous effects in different AI subfields. For example, research published in ICML and NIPS have the strongest effects on the creation and performance of AI start-ups even those “machine learning” papers are considered more theoretical than applied research published in conferences such as KDD or AAAI. Furthermore, we also find the higher the research impact factor of AI research, the stronger the regional spillover effect in terms of the creation of AI start-ups. Our study adds to existing literature in the following aspects. First, our empirical analyses could be the first study that investigates which type of AI research produces stronger knowledge spillover effects on the regional entrepreneurship by providing a more nuanced analysis than the extant knowledge spillovers literature, which mostly focus on whether general academic research in university has localized spillover effects on entrepreneurial activity. Second, we respond to the call of scholars to examine whether knowledge spillovers from university research has any impact not just on the quantity but also on the quality of new ventures (Rosa and Mohnen 2007). Third, although there is an emerging stream of AI literature studied the impacts of AI on the labor market (Frey and Osborne 2017), there exists limited literature about AI entrepreneurship. Therefore, our study adds to the growing IS literature on economics impact of AI and technology entrepreneurship. 2. Data and measures We draw on several data sources to conduct our analyses. First, information on university-level AI academic publications is collected from CSRankings.com, which covers the ranking of all universities by top CS conference publications. We classified AI fields into six subfields including general AI (AAAI and IJCAI), Computer Vision (CV), Machine Learning (ML), Data Mining (DM), Natural Language Processing (NLP), and the Web and Information Retrieval (IR) based on CSRankings.com. Only very top conferences are counted in the ranking system on this website. For example, only three conferences (CVPR, ICCV, and ECCV) are counted in the CV area. As for the subfields of general AI, only AAAI and IJCAI are counted. Similarly, the field of NLP contains only ACL, EMNLP, and NAACL. Only SIGIR and WWW are included in IR. Since ML includes three conferences, two theoretical-oriented conferences (ICML and NIPS) and more applied data mining conference KDD (Jordan and Mitchell 2015; Yang and Wu 2006). In the meantime, we include ICDE into the DM field because ICDE is considered as the other premier data mining conference. As a result, we have six AI subfields covering 14 conferences (AAAI, IJCAI, CVPR, ECCV, ICCV, ICML, NIPS, KDD, ICDE, ACL, EMNLP, NAACL, SIGIR, and WWW) in our analysis. In total, there are 175 U.S. universities that published at least one paper from 2000 to 2018. Second, we collected the information on AI start-ups from Crunchbase.com. Crunchbase.com includes the basic information of start-ups (such as the founding date, headquarter location, etc.) and VC funding information. We collected employment and unemployment data from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. In addition, we obtained the number of graduates of all universities from the Survey of Graduate Students and Postdoctorates in Science and Engineering (GSS) in the U.S. ranging from 2000 to 2018. After merging these datasets, our final dataset covers 153 MSAs from 2000 to 2018. Dependent variables. We construct two dependent variables to measure the creation and performance of AI start-ups at the MSA-level. Specifically, we firstly construct the yearly total number of AI start-ups (Firm) at MSA level to capture the creation of AI start-ups. In addition, we use the VC financing performance of start-ups to measure the early-stage performance of AI start-ups. We construct the average amount of VC investment (VCAmount) in millions of the U.S. dollars of all AI start-ups received at each MSA. Independent
Recommended publications
  • Knowledge Spillovers and Future Jobs
    DAVID B. AUDRETSCH Indiana University, USA, and Max Planck Institute of Economics, Germany Knowledge spillovers and future jobs In the future, jobs will be created by those bold enough to transform new ideas and knowledge into innovations Keywords: innovation, entrepreneurship, competitiveness, globalization ELEVATOR PITCH R&D investment as a percentage of GDP (2012) Globalization brings both good and bad job news. The 5 3.93 bad news is that jobs will be outsourced from high-cost 3.55 3.41 developed countries into lower-cost locations as soon as 4 2.98 2.92 the associated economic activity becomes mechanized 3 and predictable. The good news is that globalization creates opportunities that can be realized by people 2 bold enough to transform new ideas and knowledge into innovations. In that way, entrepreneurs will play a vital role 1 in creating the jobs of the future by transforming ideas 0 and knowledge into new products and services, which will US Germany France UK Canada be the competitive advantage of the advanced economies. Source: Based on Figure 1. KEY FINDINGS Pros Cons Innovative activity is the result of investments in Investments in new knowledge do not new knowledge, such as human capital, research automatically generate innovative activity and and development (R&D), and creativity. new jobs, but require conduits for the spillover of There are positive correlations between R&D knowledge to innovative activities. investment and innovation performance and The spillover propensity for investments in between R&D investment and productivity. knowledge is strongly influenced by contextual Knowledge investments exploit the opportunities factors, such as institutions specific to an of globalization through their spillover potential, industry, region, or country.
    [Show full text]
  • Knowledge Spillovers: an Evidence from the European Regions
    Journal of Open Innovation: Technology, Market, and Complexity Article Knowledge Spillovers: An Evidence from The European Regions Arkadiusz Kijek * and Tomasz Kijek Institute of Economics and Finance, Maria Curie-Sklodowska University, 20-031 Lublin, Poland; [email protected] * Correspondence: [email protected] Received: 15 July 2019; Accepted: 4 September 2019; Published: 6 September 2019 Abstract: The article deals with the issue of knowledge spillovers in the European regions. For this purpose, a standard Knowledge Production Function (KPF) approach was extended by the application of spatial econometrics methods. Our analysis started from the construction of the alternative structures of the spatial weight matrices. These matrices were based on technological and institutional proximities, which represent compelling alternatives to geographic proximity regarded as a kind of all-encompassing connectivity measure. The next step in our analysis was the modeling of regional knowledge generation processes. We treated R&D expenditures and human resources in science and technology as the input measures and patent applications to the European Patent Office as the output measure in our basic and extended models. The results show that the scope and direction of knowledge spillovers are sensitive to the type of knowledge (tacit vs. codified) and proximity dimension engaged. These findings contribute to the current debate in the geography of innovation and economics of knowledge literature. Keywords: region; knowledge spillovers; innovation; R&D; patent; human capital 1. Introduction Initially, the geographical proximity between firms or regions has been considered as a main transmission channel of innovation and knowledge. This idea assumes that knowledge and innovation spillovers are bounded in space and the economic entities may benefit from close location to other economic entities generating innovations [1].
    [Show full text]
  • R&D Spillovers and Productivity: Evidence from US
    Empirical Eeonomics (2000) 25:127-148 ~Z _ _ _ EMPIRICAL ECONOMICS © Springer-Verlag 2000 R&D spillovers and productivity: Evidence from U.S. manufacturing microdata* Bart Los\ Bart Verspagen^-^ ' University of Groningen, Econometric Institute, Faculty of Economics, P,0. Box 800, 9700 AV Groningen, The Netherlands (e-mail: [email protected]]) ^ECIS, Eindhoven University of Technology ^ MERIT, University of Maastricht, P.O. Box 616, 6200 MD Maastricht, The Netherlands (e-mail: [email protected]) First version received: April 1997/final version received: April 1999 Abstract. This paper deals with the estimation of the impact of technology spillovers on productivity at the firm level. Panel data for American manu- facturing firms on sales, physical capital inputs, employment and R&D in- vestments are linked to R&D data by industry. The latter data are used to construct four different sets of 'indirect' R&D stocks, representing technology obtained through spillovers. The differences between two distinct kinds of spillovers are stressed. Cointegration analysis is introduced into production function estimation. Spillovers are found to have significant positive effects on productivity, although their magnitudes differ between high-tech, medium- tech and low-tech firms. Key words: R&D spillovers, productivity, production functions, enterprise data JEL classifications: D24, O30, O31, O34 1. Introduction In many of the recent so-called 'endogenous growth models' (e.g. Romer, 1986, 1990 and Grossman and Helpman, 1991a), as well as the 'non- mainstream' literature on growth and technology (e.g.. Nelson and Winter, 1982), the generation of technology is the main driving force of economic growth.
    [Show full text]
  • A Developmental Approach to the Patent-Antitrust Interface Thomas K
    Northwestern Journal of International Law & Business Volume 33 | Issue 1 Fall 2012 A Developmental Approach to the Patent-Antitrust Interface Thomas K. Cheng Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarlycommons.law.northwestern.edu/njilb Recommended Citation Thomas K. Cheng, A Developmental Approach to the Patent-Antitrust Interface, 33 Nw. J. Int'l L. & Bus. 1 (2012). http://scholarlycommons.law.northwestern.edu/njilb/vol33/iss1/1 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Northwestern University School of Law Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Northwestern Journal of International Law & Business by an authorized administrator of Northwestern University School of Law Scholarly Commons. A Developmental Approach to the Patent-Antitrust Interface By Thomas K. Cheng* Abstract: This Article proposes a set of guiding principles for approaching the patent-antitrust interface in developing countries. Based on the notion that antitrust doctrines need to be adjusted to reflect the local economic circumstances, this Article argues that any credible approach to the patent- antitrust interface in developing countries must incorporate development considerations. It proposes a set of guiding principles that takes into account a wide range of factors, including the need to provide innovation incentives, the need to facilitate domestic imitation, the need to protect domestic consumer welfare, and the need to safeguard access to basic necessities. With the support of a considerable body of theoretical and empirical economic literature, this Article challenges the widely held belief that patent protection is necessary for securing innovations. Rather, this Article argues that developing countries need to be skeptical about innovation-based justifications for restrictive patent exploitation practices, as many of them do not possess the capacity to take advantage of innovation incentives and can ill-afford to sacrifice consumer welfare.
    [Show full text]
  • Zbwleibniz-Informationszentrum
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Franz, Peter Working Paper Knowledge Spillovers as a Central Element in Theories about Knowledge-Based Regional Development: Advancement in Theory and Obstacles for Empirical Research IWH Discussion Papers, No. 5/2010 Provided in Cooperation with: Halle Institute for Economic Research (IWH) – Member of the Leibniz Association Suggested Citation: Franz, Peter (2010) : Knowledge Spillovers as a Central Element in Theories about Knowledge-Based Regional Development: Advancement in Theory and Obstacles for Empirical Research, IWH Discussion Papers, No. 5/2010, Leibniz-Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung Halle (IWH), Halle (Saale), http://nbn-resolving.de/urn:nbn:de:101:1-2010070629 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/37063 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte.
    [Show full text]
  • Jacobs Externalities.Docx
    Jacobs’ Externalities: Where We Have Been and Where We Might Go in Studying How Urbanization Externalities Affect Innovation Innovation is key to firms’ sustainable competitive advantage. When deciding where to locate the firms’ innovation activities, managers must consider the locational factors that affect firms’ innovation performance. Understanding what the most important factors are and how they come into play is important. Existing literature on agglomeration and clusters emphasizes one important factor: externalities. Externalities originate from the co-location of firms and relevant institutions. Organizations are like leaking containers whose resources constantly spill over to their immediate environment. The spillovers can be information, knowledge, talent, customers, etc. As a result, co-located firms spontaneously create common goods shared by all neighbors. The existence of externalities means when deciding where to locate their firms, managers must pay attention to their neighbors. Depending on the nature of externalities, researchers have differentiated two kinds of externalities (Gleaser et al., 1992). One is the Marshall-Arrow-Romer externalities, or the MAR externalities. The MAR externalities root its theoretical foundation in the works of Alfred Marshall (1890), Kenneth Arrow (1962), and Paul Romer (1986). In his seminal book Principles of Economics (Book IV, Chapter X), Marshall’s (1890) listed four forces that drive agglomeration: 1. Access to natural resources and transportation; 2. Labor pooling; 3. Knowledge spillover; 4. Share of middle suppliers. Aside from access to resources and transportation, all three other forces are externalities endogenously generated by lo-located firms. Marshall’s externalities are complemented later by Arrow (1962) and Romer (1986), both of whom emphasize the role of knowledge in fostering endogenous growth.
    [Show full text]
  • What Drives Productivity Growth?
    Kevin J. Stiroh What Drives Productivity Growth? • Neoclassical and “new growth” theories offer n 1995, the U.S. economy started to experience a strong alternative explanations for productivity and Iresurgence in labor productivity growth. After growing only output growth. 1.3 percent per year from 1973 to 1995, labor productivity growth jumped to 2.5 percent from 1995 to 1999 (see chart).1 • In the neoclassical view, exogenous This striking revival has hardly gone unnoticed, with technical progress drives long-run productivity academics, policymakers, and the financial press hotly debating growth since broadly defined capital competing explanations. Some commentators emphasize rapid suffers from diminishing returns. In contrast, capital accumulation and the recent investment boom, others the new growth models yield long-run point to deeper factors like fundamental technological change in high-tech industries, and still others argue that cyclical growth endogenously, either by avoiding 2 diminishing returns to capital or by forces provide the primary explanation. explaining technical progress This debate about the forces driving the U.S. economy mirrors a larger debate between the neoclassical and new internally. growth theories regarding the sources of economic growth. Economists have long disagreed about this vital question, and • Despite their differences, both views help the recent U.S. productivity revival presents an opportune to explain the recent rise in U.S. productivity backdrop to review this debate. growth. The methodological tools In the neoclassical view, broadly defined capital developed by neoclassical economists accumulation drives growth in the short run, but capital provide a means to measure the rate of eventually succumbs to diminishing returns, so long-run technical progress, while the models of productivity growth is entirely due to exogenous technical the new growth economists can provide progress.
    [Show full text]
  • Technological Externalities and Economic Distance: a Case of the Japanese Automobile Suppliers
    DPRIETI Discussion Paper Series 09-E-051 Technological Externalities and Economic Distance: A case of the Japanese automobile suppliers TAKEDA Yosuke Sophia University UCHIDA Ichihiro Aichi University The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry http://www.rieti.go.jp/en/ RIETI Discussion Paper Series 09-E-051 October 2009 Technological Externalities and Economic Distance: A case of the Japanese automobile suppliers Yosuke TAKEDA and Ichihiro UCHIDA Faculty of Economics, Sophia University and Faculty of Economics, Aichi University Abstract This paper is in the spirit of Marshall (1920), who raised the question of how economic distance affects a firm’s productivity, focusing upon the role of idea sharing in relation to technological knowledge or information between firms. In order to quantify the degree of knowledge spillover or information sharing, we take the production function approach. Assuming core-periphery structure around automobile assemblies surrounded with auto-parts suppliers, we estimate plant-level production functions of the Japanese auto-parts suppliers, where productivity function depends upon the degree of information sharing measured by both geographic plant location and membership of technological cooperation associations. We take econometric issues of cross-sectional dependence of productivity and a simultaneity problem between inputs, applying methods to the standard OLS and GMM estimators. Positive technological externalities are seen in general and for independent plants, the fact which is robust to specifications of the production functions. Agglomeration effects are however rarely observed for relation-specific or cooperative plants. Some of them cost substantial negative externalities. Once a simultaneity problem is econometrically considered, instead of increasing returns, decreasing returns to scale emerge in cases of total materials.
    [Show full text]
  • Knowledge Spillover and Globalization
    Globalization and Knowledge Spillover: International Direct Investment, Exports and Patents Chia-Lin Chang Department of Applied Economics Department of Finance National Chung Hsing University Taichung, Taiwan Sung-Po Chen Department of Applied Economics National Chung Hsing University Taichung, Taiwan Michael McAleer Econometric Institute Erasmus School of Economics Erasmus University Rotterdam and Tinbergen Institute The Netherlands and Institute of Economic Research Kyoto University and Department of Quantitative Economics Complutense University of Madrid Revised: June 2012 ----------------------------------- The authors are most grateful to the Editor and two referees for helpful comments and suggestions. For financial support, the first author acknowledges the National Science Council, Taiwan; and the third author acknowledges the Australian Research Council, National Science Council, Taiwan, and the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science. 1 Abstract This paper examines the impact of the three main channels of international trade on domestic innovation, namely outward direct investment (ODI), inward direct investment (IDI), and exports. The number of Triadic patents serves as a proxy for innovation. The data set contains 37 countries that are considered to be highly competitive in the world market, covering the period 1994 to 2005. The empirical results show that increased exports and outward direct investment are able to stimulate an increase in patent output. In contrast, IDI exhibits a negative relationship with domestic patents. The paper shows that the impact of IDI on domestic innovation is characterized by two forces, and the positive effects of cross-border mergers and acquisitions by foreigners is less than the negative effect of the remaining IDI. Keywords: International direct investment, Exports, Imports, Triadic Patent, Outward direct investment, Inward direct investment, R&D, negative binomial model.
    [Show full text]
  • Intangibles and Innovation-Labor- Biased Technical Change
    The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available on Emerald Insight at: https://www.emerald.com/insight/1469-1930.htm Intangibles Intangibles and innovation-labor- and IBTC biased technical change Hannu Piekkola Department of Economics, University of Vaasa, Vaasa, Finland Abstract – Received 21 October 2019 Purpose This paper analyzes the productivity effects of structural capital such as research and development Revised 17 December 2019 (R&D) and organizational capital (OC). Innovation work also produces innovation-labor-biased technical 1 February 2020 change (IBTC) and knowledge spillovers. Analyses use full register-based dataset of Finnish firms for the 24 March 2020 period 1994–2014 from Statistics Finland. Accepted 20 April 2020 Design/methodology/approach – Intangibles are derived from the labor costs of innovation-type occupations using linked employer-employee data. The approach is consistent with National Accounting and offered as one method in OECD (2010) and applied in statistical offices, e.g. in measuring software. The EU 7th framework Innodrive project 2008–2011 extended this method to cover R&D and OC. Findings – Methodology is implementable at firm-level and offers way to link personnel reporting to intangible assets. The OC-IBTC as well as total resources allocated to OC are relevant for productivity growth. The R&D stock is relatively higher but R&D-IBTC is smaller than OC-IBTC. Public policy should, besides technology policy, account for OC and OC-IBTC and related knowledge spillovers in the industries that are most important among the SMEs (low market-share-firms). Research limitations/implications – The data are based on remote access to Statistics Finland; the data cannot be disseminated.
    [Show full text]
  • A Spatial Competition Model of Knowledge Spillover Entrepreneurship
    A Spatial Competition Model of Knowledge Spillover Entrepreneurship Zoltan J. Acs School of Public Policy George Mason University November 13, 2009 Outline • Introduction • Knowledge Spillover Entrepreneurship • Competition for knowledge • Hypothesis • Results • Conclusion Introduction • Role of entrepreneurial process and knowledge spillover in the economic growth and prosperity • Explores the paradox of incumbent firms as both a cause and constraint of knowledge spillover entrepreneurship Knowledge spillover entrepreneurship Competition for knowledge • Spatial competition model – Distinction between knowledge creation and knowledge application, and R&D – Disagreements between the agents over new idea and approach • Knowledge created Local stock of generic knowledge • Spatial proximity Knowledge available to all • Would-be entrepreneurs Exploit new knowledge Hypotheses • Hypothesis 1: Ceteris paribus, the rate of KSE in a region increases with expansions of the local stock of knowledge. • Hypothesis 2: Ceteris paribus, because industry and university research contribute to the pool of would-be entrepreneurs as well as the stock of new knowledge, the rate of KSE increases with the number of incumbents and the number of universities conducting research in the region. • Hypothesis 3: Ceteris paribus, because employment is a necessary pre-condition for individuals to become would-be entrepreneurs, the rate of knowledge spillover entrepreneurship decreases with higher rates of unemployment in the region. • Hypothesis 4: Ceteris paribus, the increase in KSE following the expansion of the local stock of generic knowledge is negatively moderated by an increase in the number of incumbent organizations. Research Design: Colorado • HT new firm Birth Rate (per 1000 workers) 0.16 • Establishment size # workers/ # establishments (-) • Per Capita Income Growth annual change (+) • Density, population per sq.
    [Show full text]
  • Learning from What Others Have Learned from You: the Effects of Knowledge Spillovers on Originating Firms
    LEARNING FROM WHAT OTHERS HAVE LEARNED FROM YOU: THE EFFECTS OF KNOWLEDGE SPILLOVERS ON ORIGINATING FIRMS Hongyan Yang The Hong Kong Polytechnic University Department of Management and Marketing Hung Hom, Kowloon, Hong Kong Tel: +852 2766 4021 Fax: +852 2765 0611 E-mail: [email protected] H. Kevin Steensma University of Washington Mackenzie Hall Box 353200 Seattle, WA 98195 Tel: (206) 543-4897 Fax: (206) 685-9392 E-mail: [email protected] Corey Phelps University of Washington Mackenzie Hall Box 353200 Seattle, WA 98195 Tel: (206) 543-6579 Fax: (206) 685-3232 E-mail: [email protected] We acknowledge use of the NUS Patent Database. 1 LEARNING FROM WHAT OTHERS HAVE LEARNED FROM YOU: THE EFFECTS OF KNOWLEDGE SPILLOVERS ON ORIGINATING FIRMS Abstract Although research suggests knowledge spillovers benefit imitators often at the expense of originators, we investigate how originating firms may benefit from their own spillovers. When an originating firm’s spillovers are recombined with complementary knowledge by recipient firms, a pool of external knowledge is formed that is inherently related to the originating firm’s knowledge base. This relevant knowledge pool contains valuable opportunities for the originator to learn vicariously from recipients’ recombinatorial activities. In a longitudinal study of 87 telecommunications equipment manufacturers, we find that a firm’s rate of innovation and the extent to which these innovations build on and integrate knowledge from the relevant knowledge pool is greater when its relevant knowledge pool is larger in size and similar to the firm’s existing knowledge base. 2 In the early 1980s, scientists at Eastman Kodak began their pioneering work on a light- emitting molecule that eventually led to Kodak’s core innovation in organic light-emitting diode (OLED) technology in 1985.
    [Show full text]