The Taxation of Land Value

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Taxation of Land Value The Taxation of Land Value George E. Lent * T} CONOMIC DEVELOPMENT is frequently accompanied by the JC/ growth of population and its increased concentration in urban areas, which imposes greater demands on the government for the provision of essential services, sometimes at a considerable cost. A real problem arises in financing this cost and equitably apportioning it among the members of the community. Because population growth and higher standards of living inevitably enhance the value of land, many govern- ments have sought ways of allocating this cost among the landowners who benefit directly and indirectly from rising land values. The philosophy that landowners should bear this cost originated partly in the classical theory of land rent as an unearned increment, arising either from the location of land or from the differential bounties of nature as to fertility of soil and deposits of natural resources. Accord- ing to Ricardo, rent from land is essentially a private expropriation of its natural productivity or site value (location) which does not originate in human effort or skill.1 A tax on such unearned increases in land value therefore does not impair use of the land or deter production. This view was supported by J.S. Mill, who remarked: . Suppose that there is a kind of income which constantly tends to increase without any exertion or sacrifice on the part of the owners: those owners constituting a class in the community, whom the natural course of things progressively enriches, consistently with complete passiveness on their own part. In such a case it would be no violation of the principles on which private property is grounded, if the state should appropriate this increase of wealth, or part of it, as it arises. This would not properly be taking anything from anybody; it would merely be applying an accession of wealth, created by circumstances, to the benefit of society, instead of allowing it to become an unearned appendage to the riches of a particular class.2 This principle underlies the theory of the "single tax" on land, developed by Henry George,8 which has considerably influenced property tax policies, especially in English-speaking countries. * Mr. Lent, Chief of the Tax Policy Division, formerly served as assistant director of the tax analysis staff, U.S. Treasury Department; consultant, Organiza- tion of American States; and research associate, National Bureau of Economic Research, New York. He was on the faculty of the University of North Carolina and Dartmouth College. 1 David Ricardo, Principles of Political Economy and Taxation (first published 1817). 2 John Stuart Mill, Principles of Political Economy (Toronto, 1965), p. 819 (first published 1848). 8 Progress and Poverty, Book VIII, Ch. Ill (first published 1879). 89 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 90 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND STAFF PAPERS Although few if any fiscal experts now believe that a single tax on rents would meet the requirements of modern government, persons still defend the taxation of increments in land value as a valid principle. These persons hold that the substantial increases in value accruing to holders of urban as well as suburban and agricultural land represent a reservoir of value which can properly be tapped to meet the social needs of developing communities without adverse effects on incentives. This paper describes the major applications of this principle in different countries; it also discusses the problems encountered and the necessary conditions of the successful application of this principle. The principal applications may be summarized as follows: (1) Recurrent (annual) tax on land values under a property-tax system based on capital values. (This tax may take the form of a property tax limited to urban and rural land values, as in Jamaica, New Zealand, and some Australian jurisdictions, or to agricultural land values, as in some Latin American countries; or it may take the form of a differentially higher rate on land, as in parts of Canada, East Africa, South Africa, and Denmark.) (2) Periodic tax on increments in land value. (This tax may be based on increases in land value between valuation dates even though not "realized" by sale, as in the United Kingdom and Germany early in this century, and more recently in Denmark and Italy; or it may be based on capital gains realized from the sale of land and other property, as a special tax limited to gains realized on the subdivision of urban land, or as a tax embraced by capital-gains taxes of more general applica- tion.) (3) Special assessment, or land betterment tax, which apportions the costs of publicly created improvements among the benefiting prop- erty owners. (Such special assessments, justified by the direct bene- fit theory, have a long history in the United States, Canada, the United Kingdom, and many other countries. ) Annual Taxes on Unimproved Land Values Annual taxes on the value of property—including land and improve- ments—are widely employed. When assessed values are kept current with changing values, they provide an appropriate method for allocating the cost of government to property owners who enjoy rising real estate values. If the tax is limited to the site value of land or if land is taxed more heavily than improvements, the property tax can be made an even more effective instrument for taxing increments in value and encourag- ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution THE TAXATION OF LAND VALUE 91 ing more productive use of land. This view is supported by many prominent fiscal experts.4 Professor Shoup and his associates in their re- port on Venezuela declared: "We believe that the theoretical case for a differentiated tax, in a country with rapidly increasing urbanization, is so strong that it merits careful consideration." 5 A tax on site value, resting on an economic surplus, does not impair economic incentives to make more productive use of the land. Indeed, if land is assessed to reflect its most productive use, such taxation can be employed to encourage the use of idle land and to put underutilized land to more effective use. It is argued that if the tax is assessed on the potential output of agricultural land—that is, the output which the land would yield if it were managed with average efficiency—it would give the maximum incentive to improve land and increase its output.6 The justice of such a policy is strongly defended in countries where ownership of land is sought as a refuge from inflation. The diversion of capital to investment in land tends to accentuate the rise in land prices and provides a hedge against erosion of capital values. By effectively taxing such appreciated values under a property tax, a gov- ernment can better apportion its rising costs among those realizing the greatest benefits. APPLICATIONS Taxes on unimproved land value have historically been applied in Australia, New Zealand, Canada, South Africa, and East Africa, and more recently in Jamaica, Trinidad and Tobago, and Barbados. Most Latin American countries limit the tax on agricultural properties to unimproved land values. Similar practices are followed elsewhere, especially in Denmark. 4 For an excellent summary of the principles involved and their application, see Haskell P. Wald, Taxation of Agricultural Land in Underdeveloped Countries (Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1959), pp. 71-126. 5 Commission to Study the Fiscal System of Venezuela, The Fiscal System of Venezuela: A Report (Baltimore, 1959), p. 340, hereafter cited as the Shoup Commission Report. (The Commission consisted of Carl S. Shoup, Director; John F. Due; Lyle C. Fitch; Sir Donald MacDougall; Oliver S. Oldman; and Stanleys. Surrey.) 6 N. Kaldor, "The Role of Taxation in Economic Development," in Problems in Economic Development, E.A.G. Robinson, ed., International Economic Asso- ciation (London, 1965), p. 179, and Haskell P. Wald, "Reform of Agricultural Taxation to Promote Economic Development in Latin America," in Fiscal Policy for Economic Growth in Latin America, papers and proceedings of a conference held in Santiago, Chile, December 1962, and issued by the Joint Tax Program of the Organization of American States, Inter-American Development Bank, and Economic Commission for Latin America (Baltimore, 1965), p. 326. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 92 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND STAFF PAPERS Australia and New Zealand The original Australian federal land tax was levied at steeply graduated rates on "unimproved land value." 7 Federal rates are applied to the total value of land held by one individual anywhere in the Com- monwealth. There is considerable evidence that the tax operated in accordance with the classical theory, by contributing to the breakup of large estates into smaller and more productive units, although the influ- ence of the tax cannot be clearly distinguished from that of government settlement policies, which greatly stimulated this movement. The land tax, never a large revenue producer, gradually deteriorated as large estates were broken up. Finally, in 1952, the Commonwealth relin- quished the land tax to the states. Unimproved land value taxes continue to be employed by the Australian states and by New Zealand, together with taxes on improvements and rental value; but because of exemptions and low rates, they no longer are fiscally important. At present the land tax is a significant factor only in business decisions involving land with a high value—almost exclusively urban land. For this land, however, the tax can be important since industrial and commercial property reaches the maximum rate—about 3 per cent in Queensland and New South Wales—fairly quickly.8 Canada Henry George's philosophy had considerable appeal in western Canada: British Columbia adopted site-value taxation before the turn of the century and the Prairie Provinces during the first decade of this century.9 By 1914, two thirds of the municipalities in British Columbia (including Victoria and Vancouver), all in Alberta, and a quarter in Saskatchewan had fully exempted improvements from property tax.
Recommended publications
  • The Physiocrats Six Lectures on the French Économistes of the 18Th Century
    The Physiocrats Six Lectures on the French Économistes of the 18th Century Henry Higgs Batoche Books Kitchener 2001 First Edition: The Macmillan Company, 1897 This Edition: Batoche Books Limited 52 Eby Street South Kitchener, Ontario N2G 3L1 Canada email: [email protected] ISBN: 1-55273-064-6 Contents Preface ............................................................................................... 5 I: Rise of the School. .......................................................................... 6 II: The School and Its Doctrines. ..................................................... 17 III: The School and Its Doctrines (contd.) ....................................... 29 IV: Activities of the School. ............................................................. 43 V: Opponents of the School. ............................................................ 55 VI: Influence of the School. ............................................................. 66 Appendix .......................................................................................... 77 Authorities ....................................................................................... 80 Notes ................................................................................................ 82 Preface This little volume consists of lectures delivered before the London School of Economics in May and June of the present year. Impossible though it was found to give a truly adequate account of the Physiocrats in these six lectures, it has been thought that they may perhaps furnish
    [Show full text]
  • Working Paper No. 40, the Rise and Fall of Georgist Economic Thinking
    Portland State University PDXScholar Working Papers in Economics Economics 12-15-2019 Working Paper No. 40, The Rise and Fall of Georgist Economic Thinking Justin Pilarski Portland State University Follow this and additional works at: https://pdxscholar.library.pdx.edu/econ_workingpapers Part of the Economic History Commons, and the Economic Theory Commons Let us know how access to this document benefits ou.y Citation Details Pilarski, Justin "The Rise and Fall of Georgist Economic Thinking, Working Paper No. 40", Portland State University Economics Working Papers. 40. (15 December 2019) i + 16 pages. This Working Paper is brought to you for free and open access. It has been accepted for inclusion in Working Papers in Economics by an authorized administrator of PDXScholar. Please contact us if we can make this document more accessible: [email protected]. The Rise and Fall of Georgist Economic Thinking Working Paper No. 40 Authored by: Justin Pilarski A Contribution to the Working Papers of the Department of Economics, Portland State University Submitted for: EC456 “American Economic History” 15 December 2019; i + 16 pages Prepared for Professor John Hall Abstract: This inquiry seeks to establish that Henry George’s writings advanced a distinct theory of political economy that benefited from a meteoric rise in popularity followed by a fall to irrelevance with the turn of the 20th century. During the depression decade of the 1870s, the efficacy of the laissez-faire economic system came into question, during this same timeframe neoclassical economics supplanted classical political economy. This inquiry considers both of George’s key works: Progress and Poverty [1879] and The Science of Political Economy [1898], establishing the distinct components of Georgist economic thought.
    [Show full text]
  • Taxation of Capital Gains in Developing Countries
    Taxation of Capital Gains in Developing Countries Juanita D. Amatong * ECONOMISTS GENERALLY AGREE that gains from capital JC/ are a proper source of taxation in developing countries. This view was expressed in the Technical Assistance Conference on Comparative Fiscal Administration in Geneva in 1951 and more recently in the Santiago Conference on Fiscal Policy for Economic Growth in Latin America.1 A capital gains tax is on the appreciation of capital assets and is commonly imposed only when the increase in value is realized through sale or exchange. It should be distinguished from net wealth tax, death duties, and other capital taxes in that these are assessed on the total value of assets. Capital gains in developing countries differ from those in developed countries. In the former, capital gains are mainly from the sale or exchange of real estate, and in the latter, chiefly from the sale of securi- ties. Three reasons account for the preponderance of capital gains from real estate in developing countries: the concentration of wealth held in real estate; the dominance in the corporate sector of foreign corporations whose shares are owned by nonresidents who are taxed abroad; and the widespread use of bearer shares, which limits the effectiveness of taxa- tion of capital gains from shares. Because capital gains in developing countries result largely from investments in land, the taxation of these gains is justifiable in that such investments are not socially productive and are highly speculative. Therefore, a capital gains tax discourages investments that are not in line with the social and economic objectives of developing economies.
    [Show full text]
  • Federal Legislation to Encourage US Enterprises to Invest in Arab-Israeli
    Michigan Journal of International Law Volume 15 Issue 2 1994 Incentives for Peace and Profits: ederF al Legislation to Encourage U.S. Enterprises to Invest in Arab-Israeli Joint Ventures Daniel Lubetzky Begin-Sadat Center for Strategic Studies Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.law.umich.edu/mjil Part of the Banking and Finance Law Commons, Business Organizations Law Commons, and the Comparative and Foreign Law Commons Recommended Citation Daniel Lubetzky, Incentives for Peace and Profits: ederF al Legislation to Encourage U.S. Enterprises to Invest in Arab-Israeli Joint Ventures, 15 MICH. J. INT'L L. 405 (1994). Available at: https://repository.law.umich.edu/mjil/vol15/iss2/2 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Michigan Journal of International Law at University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Michigan Journal of International Law by an authorized editor of University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. INCENTIVES FOR PEACE AND PROFITS: FEDERAL LEGISLATION TO ENCOURAGE U.S. ENTERPRISES TO INVEST IN ARAB- ISRAELI JOINT VENTURES Daniel Lubetzky* INTRODUCTION ................................................. 406 I. THE RATIONALE: WHY ENACT SUCH LEGISLATION? . 407 A. Recent Developments in the Middle East .............. 408 B. Using,Economics to Advance Peace ................... 409 C. The Role of the United States ......................... 411 D. Advantages of Investing in the Middle East ............ 413 E. Advantages of Investment Incentives as Foreign Policy Tools ................................. 417 II. THE MECHANICS: How WOULD THE INCENTIVES WORK?.. 419 A . Tax Incentives ........................................ 419 B. Government Investment Guarantees and Government Investm ent Grants ...................................
    [Show full text]
  • Doing Business in Israel 2016
    Doing business in Israel 2016 In association with: 1 Contents Introduction ................................................................................................................................................................................ 3 – Country profile ................................................................................................................................................................... 4 Legal overview ........................................................................................................................................................................... 5 Conducting business in Israel ..................................................................................................................................................... 9 Tax system ................................................................................................................................................................................11 Labour ...................................................................................................................................................................................... 18 Audit ......................................................................................................................................................................................... 21 Trade ........................................................................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Professionals Contribution to the Legislative Process: Between Self
    Journal of bs_bs_banner Law & the American Social Inquiry Bar Foundation Law & Social Inquiry Volume 39, Issue 1, 96–126, Winter 2014 Professionals’ Contribution to the Legislative Process: Between Self, Client, and the Public Adam S. Hofri-Winogradow How may professionals be made to contribute to legislative processes so that their expertise redounds to the public interest, despite the legislative product being likely to have a negative impact on their clients’ wealth? Drawing on a case study of the legislative process that gave birth to Israel’s recent (2002–2008) trusts taxation regime, based on five years of participant observation among the trust professional community, I find that to obtain the benefit of private-sector professionals’ expertise under such circumstances, government should have legislation drafted in a dispassionate, exclusive environment of experts rather than in the political arena; it should build professionals’ trust in government by adopting an explicitly collegial approach; it should focus reform efforts on elements of the existing law so clearly inequitable as to make a refusal to contribute difficult to justify; and take care that the new regime creates a compliance practice lucrative enough to compensate for any loss to professionals consequent on its enactment. Once professionals’ interests are suitably safeguarded, their loyalty to clients appears surprisingly brittle and government can successfully combine with them in the public interest. INTRODUCTION Professionals, such as lawyers, accountants, and bankers,
    [Show full text]
  • The U.S.-Israel Tax Treaty, Bearing Two Protocols, Moves Toward Ratification
    digitalcommons.nyls.edu Faculty Scholarship Articles & Chapters 7-1-1993 The .SU .-Israel Tax Treaty, Bearing Two Protocols, Moves Toward Ratification Alan Appel New York Law School, [email protected] Zeev Holender Shiboleth, Yisraeli, Roberts, Yerushalmi & Zisman Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.nyls.edu/fac_articles_chapters Recommended Citation 4 J. Int'l Tax'n 292 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at DigitalCommons@NYLS. It has been accepted for inclusion in Articles & Chapters by an authorized administrator of DigitalCommons@NYLS. THE U.S.-ISRAEL TAX TREATY, BEARING TWO PROTOCOLS,..., 4 J. Int’l. Tax’n 292 4 J. Int’l. Tax’n 292 Journal of International Taxation Volume 4, Number 7 July, 1993 U.S.-Israel Treaty Electronic Version Copyright 1993 Warren Gorham Lamont *292 Zeev Holender and Alan I. Appela THE U.S.-ISRAEL TAX TREATY, BEARING TWO PROTOCOLS, MOVES TOWARD RATIFICATION Due to the Lack of A Tax-Sparing Provision, the Treaty Does Not Reduce Taxes For U.S. Investors, and For Many, Operating Through A Branch Will Continue to be the Best Option. Israel and the U.S. began negotiations on a tax treaty almost 30 years ago. Two treaties signed in the 1960s never entered into force, however, since they were not ratified. The current Treaty finds its roots in 1975, when its first version was signed, though again not ratified.1 Five years later, the U.S. and Israel signed a protocol amending the original draft, which again was not ratified. One of the main reasons for this long process was Israel’s fear that signing a treaty with a disclosure of information clause might deter U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • The Unearned Increment: Property and the Capture of Betterment Value in Britain and France 74 Philip A
    Value Capture and Land Policies Edited by Gregory K. Ingram and Yu-Hung Hong © 2012 by the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy All rights reserved. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Value capture and land policies / edited by Gregory K. Ingram and Yu-Hung Hong. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 978-1-55844-227-6 1. Public lands—Valuation. 2. Real estate development— Finance. 3. Land use, Urban. 4. Public investments. I. Ingram, Gregory K. II. Hong, Yu-Hung. HD216.V33 2012 333.10973—dc23 2012008363 Designed by Vern Associates Composed in Sabon by Achorn International in Bolton, Massachusetts. Printed and bound by Puritan Press Inc., in Hollis, New Hampshire. The paper is Rolland Enviro100, an acid-free, 100 percent PCW recycled sheet. manufactured in the united states of america CONTENTS List of Illustrations ix Preface xiii Introduction 1 1. Land Value Capture: Types and Outcomes 3 Gregory K. Ingram and Yu-Hung Hong Conceptual Frameworks and Historical Experiences of Land Value Capture 19 2. Land Value Capture and Justice 21 Susan S. Fainstein 3. Takings and Givings: The Analytics of Land Value Capture and Its Symmetries with Takings Compensation 41 Perry Shapiro commentary 69 Henry E. Smith 4. The Unearned Increment: Property and the Capture of Betterment Value in Britain and France 74 Philip A. Booth commentary 94 Louis G. H. Albrechts 5. Special Assessments in California: 35 Years of Expansion and Restriction 97 Dean J. Misczynski commentary 116 Carol E. Heim vi Contents Land Value Capture Instruments 121 6. Collecting Land Value Through Public Land Leasing 123 John E.
    [Show full text]
  • Land Reform and Popular Political Economy in Victorian Britain
    Donald Winch Land Reform and Popular Political Economy in Victorian Britain Paper for a conference on ‘Worlds of Political Economy’ held at Churchill College, Cambridge, 6-7 September, 2002 I ‘In my lectures upon Political Economy about the country, I have found in almost every centre a certain little knot of men of the lower-middle or upper-working class, men of grit and character, largely self-educated, keen citizens, mostly nonconformists in religion, to whom Land Nationalisation, taxation of unearned increment, or other radical reforms of land tenure, are doctrines resting upon a plain moral sanction. These free-trading Radical dissenters regard common ownership and equal access to the land as a “natural right”, essential to individual freedom.’ J. A. Hobson’s description of the opinions of the kind of men he encountered in his university extension classes in the English provinces in the 1880s and 90s accords with everything we know about the revival of the movement for land reform during this period. For this was when Henry George’s Progress and Poverty (1879) was selling 100,000 copies, when George was addressing large audiences, and when Land Restoration Leagues, based on his ‘single tax’ proposals, were being formed throughout Britain. In 1897 Hobson thought that George had ‘exercised a more directly powerful formative and educative influence over English radicalism of the last fifteen years than any other man’.1 He acknowledged that George, through personal magnetism and with the aid of a drastically over-simplified economic message, was tapping into a ‘real, deep-grounded passion or conviction’, a ‘genuine need or aspiration’.
    [Show full text]
  • Doing Business in Israel This Document Describes Some of the Key Commercial and Taxation Factors That Are Relevant on Setting up a Business in Israel
    Doing Business in Israel This document describes some of the key commercial and taxation factors that are relevant on setting up a business in Israel. dfk.com Prepared by Mualem Glezer Inbar Junio & Co. +44 (0)20 7436 6722 2 Doing Business in Israel Background Country overview In the last 10 years large reserves of offshore gas have been discovered but Israel known also as SUN – Start Up Nation Israel still depends on imports of crude oil. is a 20,770 square km middle east country Other imports are raw materials, grains with a population of 8.8 million people. and military equipment. The Shekel is 80% are Jews, 19% Arabs and 1% others. considered to be a stable currency and in The official languages are Hebrew Arabic the last years Israel has a budget surplus. and English and after the big immigration Approximately half of Israel’s foreign debt from Russia in the 90’s Russian is also is owed to the US which is its major source very common. military and economic aid. Israel is highly urbanized and economically SUN – Start UP Nation – Israel is one of developed country. The main sea ports are the most important technologies centers Eilat in the south, Ashdod in the center and in the world. With highly army trained and Haifa in the North. Ben Gurion Airport is highly motivated work force, supportive the main airport in Israel and is located in government programs, active venture Lod – in the center of Israel. capital funds Israel has fertile environment for innovations. Almost every multinational Israel’s parliament – the Knesset is elected company has a development center and every four years at general election where investments in Israel.
    [Show full text]
  • GILAT SATELLITE NETWORKS LTD. (Exact Name of Registrant As Specified in Its Charter)
    SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION WASHINGTON, D.C. 20549 FORM 20-F ☐ REGISTRATION STATEMENT PURSUANT TO SECTION 12(b) OR (g) OF THE SECURITIES EXCHANGE ACT OF 1934 or ☒ ANNUAL REPORT PURSUANT TO SECTION 13 OR 15(d) OF THE SECURITIES EXCHANGE ACT OF 1934 For the fiscal year ended December 31, 2020 or ☐ TRANSITION REPORT PURSUANT TO SECTION 13 OR 15(d) OF THE SECURITIES EXCHANGE ACT OF 1934 For the transition period from ___________ to ___________ or ☐ SHELL COMPANY REPORT PURSUANT TO SECTION 13 OR 15(d) OF THE SECURITIES EXCHANGE ACT OF 1934 Date of event requiring this shell company report ___________ Commission file number: 0-21218 GILAT SATELLITE NETWORKS LTD. (Exact name of Registrant as specified in its charter) ISRAEL (Jurisdiction of incorporation or organization) Gilat House, 21 Yegia Kapayim Street, Kiryat Arye, Petah Tikva, 4913020 Israel (Address of principal executive offices) Yael Shofar, Adv. General Counsel Gilat Satellite Networks Ltd. Gilat House, 21 Yegia Kapayim Street, Kiryat Arye, Petah Tikva, 4913020 Israel Tel: +972 3 929 3020 Fax: +972 3 925 2945 (Name, telephone, e-mail and/or facsimile number and address of company contact person) Securities registered or to be registered pursuant to Section 12(b) of the Act: Title of each class Trading Symbol Name of each exchange on which registered Ordinary Shares, NIS 0.20 nominal value GILT NASDAQ Global Select Market Securities registered or to be registered pursuant of Section 12(g) of the Act: None Securities for which there is a reporting obligation pursuant to Section 15(d) of the Act: None Indicate the number of outstanding shares of each of the issuer’s classes of capital or common stock at the close of the period covered by the annual report: 55,559,638 Ordinary Shares, NIS 0.20 nominal value per share (as of December 31, 2020) Indicate by check mark if the registrant is a well-known seasoned issuer, as defined in Rule 405 of the Securities Act.
    [Show full text]
  • The Single Tax: Economic and Moral Implications
    The Single Tax: Economic and Moral Implications and A Reply to Georgist Criticisms by Murray N. Rothbard The Logic of Action One: Applications and Criticisms from the Austrian School London: Edward Elgar, 1997 pp. 294-310 © The Mises Institute, 1997 19 The Single Tax: Economic and Moral Implications eventy-five years ago, Henry George spelled out his “single tax” program Progress and Poverty, one of the best-selling Seconomic works of all time. According to E.R. Pease, social- ist historian and long-time Secretary of the Fabian Society, this volume “beyond all question had more to do with the socialist revival of that period in England than any other book.” Most present-day economists ignore the land question and Henry George altogether. Land is treated as simply capital, with no special features or problems. Yet there is a land question, and ignor- ing it does not lay the matter to rest. The Georgists have raised, and continue to raise, questions that need answering. A point-by-point examination of single tax theory is long overdue. According to the single tax theory, individuals have the natural right to own themselves and the property they create. Hence they have the right to own the capital and consumer goods they produce. Land, however (meaning all original gifts of nature), is a different matter, they say. Land is God-given. Being God-given, none can justly belong to any individual; all land properly belongs to society as a whole. Single taxers do not deny that land is improved by man; forests are cleared, soil is tilled, houses and factories are built.
    [Show full text]