Inflation Over 300 Years

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Inflation Over 300 Years Inflation over 300 years By Helen MacFarlane and Paul Mortimer-Lee of the Bank’s Economics Division. In recent years, there has been a widening acceptance of the view that the primary purpose of monetary policy should be to maintain price stability, and the primary purpose of central banks should be to secure this. But what has been the history of UK inflation over the first 300 years of the Bank’s existence? How has thinking about inflation developed over that period? And how has the workforce of the Old Lady herself withstood the inflationary ravages of time? POLITICAL RAVISHMENT or The Old Lady of Threadneedle Street in danger! Cartoon by James Gillray, published in 1797 What is inflation? example, basic foodstuffs such as eggs, lamb and bread—so their prices can be compared. Potatoes, which had arrived in Calculating how much prices have risen during the last 300 Britain by 1694 but were not widespread until much later years is a difficult task. Part of the reason for this is that the (price data are available only from 1762), can be thought of bundle of goods and services that was available in 1694 and as a close substitute for such foodstuffs. But it is more the bundle consumed now show some important differences. difficult to find seventeenth-century analogues of other Some elements are, of course, common to both—for elements in today’s Retail Price Index (RPI). What can we 156 Inflation over 300 years compare with the price today of a second-hand car—a What goes up can come down second-hand sedan chair? And although we might be able to At a best estimate, prices have risen by a factor of 67 since discover the relation between the ticket prices for a concert the Bank’s foundation in 1694. If the area of the new £50 of Purcell’s music now and in 1694, we cannot compare the note were increased in the same proportion, the result would prices of digital compact disc recordings of his music. be a note some 4 feet by 3 feet, necessitating cash machines the width of double-doors and vans instead of wallets (and To try to overcome these problems, statisticians and giving a rather different meaning to the phrase ‘velocity of economists have spliced together price indices from a circulation’). Looked at another way, if the current size of number of periods. This technique allows—albeit the £50 note were taken to represent the purchasing power imperfectly—the weights of the goods and services included of £50 in 1694, then to reflect its real purchasing power today, it would need to shrink to smaller than a postage ‘Inflation means that your money won’t buy as much stamp. today as it did when you didn’t have any.’ (Anon) Average inflation rates(a) in the price index to evolve over time. But although spliced Per cent indices give some indication of the broad trends in the price 1900 to 1913 1.3 1914 to 1918 15.3 level since 1694, they can never be exact. There is a much 1919 to 1939 -1.2 wider range of goods and services today, reflecting a more 1940 to 1945 4.3 1946 to 1949 2.6 developed structure of production. So food prices comprise 1950 to 1959 4.3 1960 to 1969 3.5 only a fifth of today’s RPI compared with two thirds in 1970 to 1979 12.5 1694, implying that the index is now much less sensitive to 1980 to 1989 7.4 1990 to 1993 5.1 certain shocks, such as the failure of the grain harvest. (a) Geometric averages. There are similar problems—including difficulties over the Experience of the general trend in prices since the Second availability of comparisons and over changes in quality— World War might suggest that inflation is always with us. when trying to see how wages have evolved over the period. In fact, the history of the last three centuries is not one of an The standard of education in the population as a whole is unbroken rise in prices, but rather of periods in which prices much higher now than in 1694. And the range of skills increased, others when they fell, and little tendency for available in the workforce is very different (there were no sustained rises or falls. Indeed prices have risen more computer programmers in seventeenth-century England). quickly in the last 50 years than in any similar period since Even over shorter periods, comparison is difficult. Would it 1694; the index of prices tripled between 1694 and 1948, be fair to compare the £30,000 paid to Aston Villa for their but has risen almost 20-fold since. Even within the post-war striker Trevor Ford in 1950 (that year’s record transfer) with period, however, the rate of inflation has varied markedly, as the £2.3 million they paid for Dean Saunders in 1992? the table above illustrates. Chart 1 Retail Price Index Logarithmic scale 1694=100 10,000 Nationalisation 6,000 of Bank 1946 3,000 Second World War 1939–45 Great Peel’s Bank Depression Charter Act 1929–32 1,000 1844 First World War 600 Napoleonic wars Crimean War 1914–18 1854–56 Sterling fixed to gold 300 1717 Sterling finally left Gold Standard 100 1931 0 1694 1725 1750 17751800 1825 18501875 1900 1925 1950 1975 157 Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin: May 1994 Wages Chart 3 The profile of nominal wages over the last 300 years has Real wages been similar to that for retail prices, as a comparison of Logarithmic scale 1694=100 Charts 1 and 2 shows. It is notable, however, that real wages 1,000 appear to have been considerably more variable in earlier 600 Chart 2 Nominal wages Logarithmic scale 300 1694=100 100,000 40,000 150 10,000 100 3,000 0 1694 1750 1800 1850 1900 1950 1,000 staff were again complaining of hardship, suffering ‘much 300 difficulty in meeting their unavoidable expenses and maintaining social respectability’.(5) 100 0 1694 1750 1800 1850 1900 1950 Bank clerks—and indeed the Bank’s Chief Cashier—were paid £50 a year in 1694. Increasing this in line with the centuries than they have been in this one (Chart 3)—though 400-fold rise in the overall nominal wage index since then precise comparisons are difficult from the available data.(1) would suggest a figure of £20,000 today. In fact graduate It is clear also that nominal wages have risen by much more entrants into the Bank currently start on a salary around 25% than prices. An index showing movements in builders’ less than this. The Chief Cashier has done rather better. wages relative to a basket of consumables,(2) set at 100 for 1694, had fallen to a low of 62 by 1801. This was in the In 1694, the Bank was cleaned by one person, period of the war with France, when the cost of living rose Susan Bennett. The only woman employed by the Bank at sharply (the price of the basket rose over 30% in 1800). But the time, she was paid £10 a year. Today, the Bank employs by 1993, the index had risen to over 600. a staff of 59 ‘housekeepers’, whose annual salary is around 500 times that in 1694. Bank of England staff also appeared to feel the pinch in the Napoleonic era. According to W Marston Acres: ‘the Swings and roundabouts increase in salaries granted by the Directors in 1800 was not commensurate with the rise in the cost of living, and it was The general trend in the price index masks some very large only because of the money earned by extra work that more changes in relative prices. Even over short periods, relative clerks were not in difficulties’.(3) prices can change substantially, reflecting changes in supply and demand conditions. Since January 1987, for example, ‘When I first started working, I used to dream of the day the RPI sub-index for audio-visual equipment has fallen by when I might be earning the salary I’m starving on around 20%, while that for water charges has doubled. Over today.’ (Anon) the same period, coffee prices have fallen by 1%, while soft-drink prices have risen by over 50%. In 1821, following five years of peace, clerks’ annual Looking at the prices of three essentials, the average price of increments and maximum attainable salaries were reduced; bread in London in 1694 was 5.6d (about 2.3p) per 4lb.(6) In at the time, prices were falling by over 10% a year. In 1854, 1894, the price was just 5.5d, though it had risen to 1s 5d following the imposition of income tax(4) to finance the war (about 7p) at the time of the Napoleonic wars. In the decade against Russia, clerks were moved to request that the Bank from 1974 to 1984, it tripled; and by 1993, it had risen a pay their tax for them. The request was initially refused, but further 60%. The retail price in London of a ton of coal rose clerks were later granted a 10% rise because of the ‘high by around 70% between 1700 and 1830, to 20 shillings. It prices of provisions concurring with the pressure of income was much the same price in 1900, rose to around 30 shillings tax’—prices rose by around 16% in 1854. But by 1865 the in the 1914–18 period, dropped back to 20 shillings after the (1) See, for example, Crafts, N F R, British Economic Growth during the Industrial Revolution, 1991.
Recommended publications
  • The Politics of Inflation Management
    University of Warwick institutional repository This paper is made available online in accordance with publisher policies. Please scroll down to view the document itself. Please refer to the repository record for this item and our policy information available from the repository home page for further information. To see the final version of this paper please visit the publisher’s website. Access to the published version may require a subscription. Author(s): Watson, Matthew Article Title: The Politics of Inflation Management Year of publication: 2003 Link to published version: http://dx.doi.org/ 10.1111/1467-923X.00538 Publisher statement: The definitive version is available at www.blackwell-synergy.com The Politics of Inflation Management Matthew Watson Published in the Political Quarterly, 74 (3), 2003, 285-297. The Politics of Inflation Management I. Introduction An unanticipated and almost wholly unexpected coincidence of economic events occurred in Britain in July 2002. Taken together, these raise serious questions about the stated rationale that has guided the conduct of British macroeconomic policy for at least a generation. Yet they remained entirely unremarked upon in the financial and broadsheet press. On Monday, 15th July, the FTSE 100 index fell below 4,000 for the first time in 5½ years, a full 43% below its peak of 6,950.6 reached on 30th December 1999. Before the London Stock Exchange opened for trading the next morning on Tuesday 16th July, the Treasury announced the latest figures for the Retail Price Index measure of underlying inflation in Britain, which had fallen to an annual equivalent of 1.5%.
    [Show full text]
  • The Pound Sterling
    ESSAYS IN INTERNATIONAL FINANCE No. 13, February 1952 THE POUND STERLING ROY F. HARROD INTERNATIONAL FINANCE SECTION DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND SOCIAL INSTITUTIONS PRINCETON UNIVERSITY Princeton, New Jersey The present essay is the thirteenth in the series ESSAYS IN INTERNATIONAL FINANCE published by the International Finance Section of the Department of Economics and Social Institutions in Princeton University. The author, R. F. Harrod, is joint editor of the ECONOMIC JOURNAL, Lecturer in economics at Christ Church, Oxford, Fellow of the British Academy, and• Member of the Council of the Royal Economic So- ciety. He served in the Prime Minister's Office dur- ing most of World War II and from 1947 to 1950 was a member of the United Nations Sub-Committee on Employment and Economic Stability. While the Section sponsors the essays in this series, it takes no further responsibility for the opinions therein expressed. The writer's are free to develop their topics as they will and their ideas may or may - • v not be shared by the editorial committee of the Sec- tion or the members of the Department. The Section welcomes the submission of manu- scripts for this series and will assume responsibility for a careful reading of them and for returning to the authors those found unacceptable for publication. GARDNER PATTERSON, Director International Finance Section THE POUND STERLING ROY F. HARROD Christ Church, Oxford I. PRESUPPOSITIONS OF EARLY POLICY S' TERLING was at its heyday before 1914. It was. something ' more than the British currency; it was universally accepted as the most satisfactory medium for international transactions and might be regarded as a world currency, even indeed as the world cur- rency: Its special position waS,no doubt connected with the widespread ramifications of Britain's foreign trade and investment.
    [Show full text]
  • The Exchange Rate and Inflation in the UK
    p External UNIT time Discussion Paper No.11 The Exchange Rate and Inflation in the UK by Amit Kara and Edward Nelson External MPC Unit Discussion Paper No. 11* The Exchange Rate and Inflation in the UK By Amit Kara and Edward Nelson September 2002 ISSN: 1748 – 6203 Copyright Bank of England 2002 (*) Disclaimer: These Discussion Papers report on research carried out by, or under supervision of the External Members of the Monetary Policy Committee and their dedicated economic staff. Papers are made available as soon as practicable in order to share research and stimulate further discussion of key policy issues. However, the views expressed are those of the authors and do not represent the views of the Bank of England or necessarily the views of External Members of the Monetary Policy Committee. The Exchange Rate and Inflation in the UK Amit Kara* and Edward Nelson** External Monetary Policy Committee Unit Bank of England September 2002 Abstract The United Kingdom is a highly open economy, and has a monetary policy strategy of targeting inflation in consumer prices. In this paper, we look at the evidence from the UK on inflation behaviour, and examine the propositions from several theoretical models about inflation dynamics in an open economy, focussing in particular on the hypothesised connections between the exchange rate and consumer price inflation. Theoretical open-economy macroeconomic models ‘cover the waterfront’ on this issue, ranging from ‘exchange rate disconnect’ to a rigid link between nominal exchange rate changes and inflation. We estimate on UK data the open-economy Phillips curves implied by the alternative explanations.
    [Show full text]
  • Notes on British Money of Adam Smith's Time
    K.D. Hoover Adam Smith and the System of Natural Liberty Revised, 15 November 2020 Notes on British Money of Adam Smith’s Time The official British monetary unit in Adam Smith’s time, as today, is the pound sterling. As its name implies it was originally a silver currency, but by the 1750s, Britain had adopted the gold standard. Until 1971, the pound was divided into 20 shillings, and each shilling was worth 12 pence, so that the pound was worth 240 pence. The standard symbol for pounds is £, usually written before the numerals (e.g., £130). Frequently, when subparts of pounds are included, pounds/shillings/pence are written l/s/d, usually written after the numerals (e.g., 4 pounds, 7 shillings, and 9 pence is written 4 l. 7s. 9d). While this seems like a complicated system to us who are used to the decimal system, it was a commonplace system in early modern Europe. Decimalization began with the French Revolution. Britain had little use for France, and so resisted longer than most other countries. In fact, the prime factors of 12 and 20 are more numerous than those of 10, so that, once one is used to it, the old system is not so hard for mental arithmetic. th In Smith’s time and through most of the 19 century, the pound sterling was defined by its gold value: 1 Troy ounce of gold = 3 l. 17s 10½d (the most common way of stating it) or, put 1 inversely, £1 = 0.2242 (i.e., 1 pound was worth between /5 and ¼) Troy ounce of gold.
    [Show full text]
  • How Much Is That in Real Money? a Historical Price Index for Use As a Deflator of Money Values in the Economy of the United States
    How Much Is That in Real Money? A Historical Price Index for Use as a Deflator of Money Values in the Economy of the United States JOHNJ.McCUSKER UT how much is that in real money? It is a question that lurks behind the mention of the price of anything in the past, B from the cost of George Washington's false teeth to the worth of the gold doubloon that Herman Melville's Captain Ahab nailed to his ship's mast as the reward to the first of his crew to sight Moby Dick. Teachers of history mention prices or wages at their peril, certain in the knowledge that someone will ask the question and equally certain that they will have a hard time answer- ing it. We who study economic history in departments of history are expected to be able to pronounce immediately on the modem equivalent of the Biblical shekel, of medieval Venetian money, and of World War I reparations — for students and for colleagues both. Economic historians in departments of economics presumably have it easier because economists are supposed to be able to find out such things for themselves, however difficult the exercise may turn out to be. What follows is intended as a guide to all who would like to compare the changing value of things over time in real terms, at least with regard to the American economy' I. I wish to acknowledge with thanks the help of several people who have read and commented on this paper. JOHN MCCUSKER, currently professor of history at the University of Maryland, College Park, will become Halsell Distinguished professor of history and professor oí economics at Trinity University in fall 1992.
    [Show full text]
  • What Accounts for the Bias in the Inflation Targeting Performance of the Bank of England?
    LSE Research Online Monograph Willem H. Buiter What accounts for the bias in the inflation targeting performance of the Bank of England? Mimeo, Universiteit van Amsterdam. Copyright © 2005 Willem H. Buiter, LSE, CEPR and NBER. Original available at http://www.nber.org/~wbuiter/public.htm You may cite this version as: Buiter, Willem H. (2005). What accounts for the bias in the inflation targeting performance of the Bank of England? [online] London: LSE Research Online. Available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/archive/00000713 Available online: April 2006 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright © and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. http://eprints.lse.ac.uk Contact LSE Research Online at: [email protected] What accounts for the bias in the inflation targeting performance of the Bank of England? Willem H. Buiter1 European Bank for Reconstruction and Development2, Universiteit van Amsterdam, LSE, CEPR and NBER 19 February 2005 version On 6 May 1997, the government granted the Bank of England operational autonomy; the government would set a target inflation rate and the Bank would implement this with an independently chosen interest rate.
    [Show full text]
  • Interest Rates, Trade, and Deficit and Debt
    Public Understanding of Economics and Economic Statistics Johnny Runge and Nathan Hudson Advisory team: Amy Sippitt Mike Hughes Jonathan Portes ESCoE Occasional Paper 03 November 2020 ISSN 2515-4664 OCCASIONAL PAPER Public Understanding of Economics and Economic Statistics Johnny Runge and Nathan Hudson ESCoE Occasional Paper No. 03 November 2020 Abstract This study explores the public understanding of economics and economics statistics, through mixed-methods research with the UK public, including 12 focus groups with 130 participants and a nationally representative survey with 1,665 respondents. It shows that people generally understand economic issues through the lens of their familiar personal economy rather than the abstract national economy. The research shows that large parts of the UK public have misperceptions about how economic figures, such as the unemployment and inflation rate, are collected and measured, and who they are produced and published by. This sometimes affected participants’ subsequent views of the perceived accuracy and reliability of economic statistics. Broadly, the focus groups demonstrated suggested that people are often sceptical and cynical about any data they see, and that official economic data are subject to the same public scrutiny as any other data. In line with other research, the survey found consistent and substantial differences in economic knowledge and interest across different groups of the UK population. This report will be followed up with an engagement exercise to discuss findings with stakeholders, in order to draw out recommendations on how to improve the communication of economics and economic figures statistics to the public. Keywords: public understanding, public perceptions, communication, economic statistics JEL classification: Z00, D83 Johnny Runge, National Institute of Economic and Social Research and ESCoE, [email protected] and Nathan Hudson, National Institute of Economic and Social Research and ESCoE.
    [Show full text]
  • Measurement Bias in Price Indices: an Application to the UK's RPI Opens in a New Window
    MEASUREMENT BIAS IN PRICE INDICES: AN APPLICATION TO THE UK'S RPI Alastair W F Cunningham The views expressed in this paper are those of the author and should not be attributed to the Bank. of England. I would like to thank several colleagues who helped in the preparation of this paper, including Paul Fisher and Anthony Yates. I am also indebted to the participants in a short conference on price measurement held at the Bank of England in June 1995, including Marta Haworth, Danny Quah and Mick Silver. Issued by the Monetary Analysis Division, Bank of England, London, EC2R gAH to which requests fo r individual copies should be addressed: envelopes should be marked for the attention of the Publications Group. (Telephone: 0171-601-4030.) Bankof England 1996 ISSN 0142-6573 Contents Abstract 5 1 Introduction 7 2 Sources of bias 12 Compositional bias 12 Substitution bias 17 3 Compositional bias - quality bias 23 Application to the UK 30 4 Compositional bias - new goods bias 32 Application to the UK 37 5 Substitution bias - product bias 40 Application to the UK 41 6 Substitution bias - outlet bias 44 Application to the UK 48 7 Variance of bias across time and state 54 8 Conclusion 57 Appendix 1 - simulation techniques 59 Appendix 2 - inputs to the outlet bias simulations 61 References 66 Abstract This paper assesses the potential for systematic discrepancies between inflation as measured by consumer (or retail) price indices and one possible hypothetical ideal for monetary policymaking. It has long been suggested that measured price indices overstate the macroeconomist's view of inflation - as a result of both the weights used and the composition of the prices sampled.
    [Show full text]
  • U.K. Inflation Targeting and the Exchange Rate
    Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series U. K. Inflation Targeting and the Exchange Rate Christopher Allsopp Amit Kara and Edward Nelson Working Paper 2006-030A http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2006/2006-030.pdf May 2006 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS Research Division P.O. Box 442 St. Louis, MO 63166 ______________________________________________________________________________________ The views expressed are those of the individual authors and do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, the Federal Reserve System, or the Board of Governors. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References in publications to Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors. U.K. inflation targeting and the exchange rate Christopher Allsoppa Amit Karab Edward Nelsonc New College, UBS Federal Reserve Bank of St. London, U.K. Oxford University, Louis, USA, and CEPR, Oxford, U.K. London, U.K. May 2006 Abstract The United Kingdom’s monetary policy strategy is one of floating exchange rates and inflation forecast targeting, with the targeted measure referring to consumer prices. We consider whether it is welfare-reducing to target inflation in the CPI rather than in a narrower index; and the role of the exchange rate in the transmission of monetary policy actions to CPI inflation. We argue that it is appropriate to model imports as intermediate goods rather than as goods consumed directly by households.
    [Show full text]
  • Eprospects in Association with Volterra Consulting Q2 2010
    eProspects In association with Volterra Consulting Q2 2010 Economy Update Property Update Post budget assessment House Price Outlook Financial Markets in Downturn Commercial Property Overview Inflation So where do we see the commercial China frees up its currency market going from here? Economy Update Post budget assessment The main focus of the Budget was to bring the public nances under control. There are three aspects to this. First, the amount the government is borrowing in any given year. Second, the outstanding stock of debt. Third, the more esoteric but important concept of the ‘structural decit’. In the 2009/10 nancial year, net government borrowing was a massive 11 per cent of GDP, getting on for £200 billion. The assessment by the independent Ofce for Budget “History suggest Responsibility (OBR) is that this will be reduced to just 1.1 per cent of GDP by 2015/16, with that once condence a greater than 50 per cent chance of this being met earlier in 2014/15. returns and recovery Net borrowing in any one year is the addition to the existing stock of outstanding debt, which was also giving cause for concern. From a level of 53 per cent of GDP in 2009/10, the level of gets under way, GDP borrowing inherited from Labour will inevitably mean that this will rise in the short-term. The OBR estimate it will rise to a peak of 70 per cent in 2013/14, falling to 67 per cent by 2015/16. growth can easily A key criticism of Gordon Brown’s time as Chancellor is that he was in practice not prudent exceed 3 per cent but proigate.
    [Show full text]
  • The Stock Market Under Labour
    THE STOCK MARKET UNDER LABOUR THE STOCK The London stock market has always performed poorly under Labour Governments, But its performance under this Labour Government has been worse than ever before, falling by 26% in real terms since 1 May 1997. This is (barring Japan) the worst performance of any of the world’s major stock markets over the period. The Stock Market under Labour John Littlewood shows how, in 1997, Gordon Brown benefi ted from a The legacy of Gordon Brown golden inheritance. But in 2007, he passed on a poisoned chalice. For his Government’s policies have created unsustainable government JOHN LITTLEWOOD defi cits, undermined UK competitiveness, allowed asset bubbles to develop and permitted irresponsible risk-taking by banks to go unchecked. The prospects for the economy, and the stock market, are bleak. Price £10.00 JOHN LITTLEWOOD Centre Centre for Policy for Policy Studies Studies The Stock Market under Labour The legacy of Gordon Brown JOHN LITTLEWOOD THE AUTHOR John Littlewood is a graduate of New College, Oxford. He enjoyed a City career of 32 years, as an investment analyst and later in a senior management role. He was a Partner in stockbrokers Rowe & Pitman and later a Group Director at S G Warburg. He is the author of a history of the post-war London stock market, The Stock Market: 50 years of capitalism at work (Financial Times Pitman Publishing, 1998); Labour and the Stock Market: is New Labour really any different? (Centre for Policy Studies, 2002); and The Stock under Labour: for New read Old (CPS, 2004).
    [Show full text]
  • Lessons from the Past
    marketwatch WHAT NEXT? Lessons from the past HOW FAR DOES THIS RECESSION HAVE TO GO, AND WHAT SHOULD DOMINATE THE UK’S POST- RECESSION AGENDA? HSBC ECONOMIST DENNIS TURNER WAS IN OPTIMISTIC MOOD WHEN HE RECENTLY SET OUT HIS THOUGHTS, REPORTS GRAHAM BUCK. and only began to rally when UK economic recovery was evidently Executive summary under way in the mid 1990s. Since Labour regained office in 1997, a strong pound for most of the period has made imports cheap but I Labour had avoided the boom/bust economic cycle over much of created problems for exporters; a situation that only improved with the last 12 years, but credit-fuelled growth ended this prolonged the pound’s sharp depreciation against the euro and dollar last year. period of stability. Dennis Turner sees a long slow climb back to Turner points out that Labour can also boast of sustained prosperity in 2010, with either public spending cuts or higher taxes inevitable, and a boost to manufacturing vital. As the economic growth. The rate of 0.4% recorded for the first quarter of election looms, the main parties must set out their stalls. 2008 was the 63rd consecutive quarter in which the figure was positive. Nor was there any repetition of the Thatcher-Lawson boom of the late 1980s, which was marked by economic growth of 6% in 1988 accompanied by a rise in inflation to 10% and a jump from ow should the government be judged on its economic 7.5% to 15% in the Bank of England’s base rate.
    [Show full text]