The NAIRU in Theory and Practice

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The NAIRU in Theory and Practice Journalof Economic Perspectives—Volume 16,Number 4—Fall 2002—Pages 115– 136 TheNAIRU inTheory and Practice LaurenceBall and N.Gregory Mankiw AIRU stands forthe nonaccelerating in ation rateof unemployment.It isbeyond disputethat this acronym isan uglyaddition tothe English N language. Thereare, however, two issues that failto command consensus among economists, which weaddress inthis essay. The rstissue is whetherthe concept ofthe NAIRU isa usefulpiece of business cycletheory. We believeit is, and webegin this paperby attempting to explain why. In ourview, the NAIRU isapproximately a synonym forthe natural rateof unemployment.This concept followsnaturally from any theorythat says that changes inmonetarypolicy, and aggregatedemand moregenerally, push ination and unemploymentin opposite directions in the short run. Once this short-run tradeoffis admitted, there must besome level of unemployment consistent with stablein ation. Thesecond issueis why the NAIRU changes overtime and, inparticular,why itfellin thesecond half ofthe1990s. This questionis more dif cult, and theanswer isopen todebate. Most likely,various factors areat work,including demographics and governmentpolicies. Yet one hypothesis stands out as particularlypromising: uctuations inthe NAIRU appear relatedto uctuations inproductivity. In the 1970s,the NAIRU rosewhen productivitygrowth slowed. In the1990s, the NAIRU fellwhen productivitygrowth sped up. Developingand testingmodels that explain thelinks among ination, unemploymentand productivityremains a challengefor students ofbusiness cycletheory. y Laurence Ball isProfessorof Economics,Johns Hopkins University, Baltimore, Maryland. N.Gregory Mankiwis Professor of Economics, Harvard University, Cambridge, Massachusetts. 116Journal of Economic Perspectives The Role of NAIRU The word “NAIRU” enteredthe language of macroeconomicsin the1970s, a periodof rapid and risingin ation. Yet,in a deepersense, theconcept has been thereall along. ABuildingBlock of Macroeconomic Theory Alongtradition in economicsemphasizes that thesupply ofmoney in uences both in ation and unemployment.In his classic 1752essay “Of Money,” David Humewrote about theeffects of monetary injections, such as golddiscoveries: “It iseasyto tracethe money in itsprogress through thewhole commonwealth; where we shall nd that itmust rstquicken the diligence of every individual, before it increasesthe price of labour. ” This insighthas motivatedmuch ofmodern macro- economictheory. Two prominent examples are Milton Friedman ’s(1968)presi- dentialaddress tothe American Economic Association and RobertLucas ’s (1996) Nobelprize lecture. Lucas quotesexactly these words from Hume. Attimes,some economists have questionedHume ’sinsight. Thereal business cycletheorists of the 1980s, for example, suggested that business cycleswere technologicallydriven and that moneyhad no rolein explaining production and employment uctuations (Prescott,1986; Long and Plosser,1983). But this viewis aminorityposition, both historicallyand today. Thereis wideagreement about the fundamental insightthat monetary uctuations push in ation and unemployment inopposite directions. That is, societyfaces atradeoff,at leastin the short run, between in ation and unemployment. Accordingto conventional macroeconomic theory, the in ation-unemployment tradeoffis centralto understanding not onlythe effects of monetary policy but also otherpolicies and eventsthat in uencethe aggregate demand forgoods and services.But most of these other events and policiescan potentiallyhave effects through otherchannels as well.For example, tax policy in uences both aggregate demand through disposableincome and aggregatesupply through workincentives. Bycontrast, beliefthat monetarypolicy has employmenteffects is inextricably tied tobelief in the in ation-unemploymenttradeoff. Twocenturies have passed sinceHume penned thewise words quoted above, but theeconomics profession has yetto reacha consensus about whythis tradeoff arises.In classical theory,money is neutral. It isonlythe numeraire in which prices arequoted. Changes inits quantity should affectthe overall price level, but not relativeprices, production oremployment. The key question facing business cycle theoristsis why this classical theoremof monetary neutrality fails to hold inthe world. Many answers have beenproposed. Short-run nonneutralityhas beenblamed on imperfectionsof information (Friedman, 1968; Lucas, 1973;Mankiw and Reis, 2001);long-term labor contracts (Fischer,1977; Gray, 1976; Taylor, 1980); the costs ofprice adjustment (Rotemberg,1982; Mankiw, 1985;Blanchard and Kiyotaki, Laurence Ball andN. Gregory Mankiw117 1987;Ball and Romer,1990); or departures from full rationality (Akerlof and Yellen,1985). Each ofthese approaches raisesits own setof dif culttheoretical and empiricalquestions, which arebeyond thescope ofthis essay. Thereis, however,a common theme:because ofsome market imperfection absent fromthe classical model,changes inthe value of the unit ofaccount matter.Monetary neutrality breaksdown, and at leastin theshort run, monetarychanges have oppositeeffects on in ation and unemployment. Without much loss ofgenerality, we can writethe short-run tradeoffbetween in ation and unemployment U as follows: 5 k 2 aU, where k and a . 0areparameters. This equationdoes not reallysay much, other than that and U arenegatively related. One fact about this relationshipis clear: itcannot beconstant overtime. If itwere,the data onin ation and unemployment wouldtrace a nice,stable, downward-sloping Phillipscurve. There once was atime when someeconomists took this possibilityseriously, but data sincethe early 1970s have madethis simpleview untenable. Theinstability of this relationshipis hardly a surprise.Even Samuelson and Solow’s(1960)classic discussion ofthe Phillips curve suggested that theshort-run menu of in ation-unemploymentcombinations wouldlikely shift over time. Skep- ticsare sometimes tempted to use theshifting Phillips curve as evidenceto denythe existenceof a short-run tradeoff.This ispuresophistry. It wouldbe like observing that theUnited States has moreconsumption and investmentthan does India to denythat societyfaces atradeoffbetween consumption and investment.The situation isnot hard tounderstand and, infact, arisesfrequently in economics. At any point intime,society faces atradeoff,but thetradeoff changes overtime. The nextquestion is what factors cause thetradeoff to shift. Expectations,the Natural Rate and SupplyShocks SinceFriedman (1968) and Phelps ’s(1967,1968) seminal contributions, one variablehas playedcenter stage in explainingshifts inthe in ation-unemployment tradeoff:expected in ation. Otherthings equal,an increasein expectedin ation isassociated withan equalincrease in actual in ation. Thereason why expected in ation plays such aroledepends on thetheory of short-run nonneutrality. Moreover,the choice of theorywill in uencethe timing of when expectationsare formed.But from a bird ’s-eyeview, the similarity of thetheories is moresigni cant than theirdifferences. In moststandard theories,we can writethe in ation- unemploymenttradeoff as 5 e 2 a~U 2 U*!, where e isexpected in ation and U*isa parametercalled the “natural rateof 118Journal of Economic Perspectives unemployment. ” Thenatural rateis the rate of unemploymentthat prevailswhen in ation expectationsare con rmed.Seen in another light,the parameter U* embedsall shifts inthein ation-unemploymenttradeoff previously represented by theparameter k,otherthan shifts arisingfrom expected in ation. Thenatural ratecan beviewed as theunemployment rate that theeconomy reachesin the long run. This interpretationarises from imposing a modicumof rationalityto expectations. Over any longinterval of time,the average of expected in ation should equalthe average of actual in ation; otherwise,forecasts are systematicallybiased. Thus, overthe same long interval, average unemployment should equalthe average natural rate.In thelong run, U cannot deviatefrom U*. Noneof this means that thenatural rateof unemployment is immutable, or eventhat itmoves only slowly over time. In principle, U*can exhibitsubstantial high- frequencyvariation, so any othershift in thein ation-unemploymenttradeoff can bedescribed as ashiftin U*.As apracticalmatter, however, the literature on in ation-unemploymentdynamics has traditionallyused an amendedversion of the aboveequation: 5 e 2 a~U 2 U*! 1 v, where v isdubbed the “supply shock. ” Tosomeextent, the distinction between U* and v isarbitrary:both thenatural rate U*and thesupply shock v representshifts inthe in ation-unemployment tradeoff.But many economistsview these two variables as measuringdifferent kinds ofshifts. Thenatural rate U*isthought tore ecthow wellthe labor market matches workersand jobs. It isaltered,for instance, bychanges indemographicsor labor-marketinstitutions and isthought tomove slowly over time. By contrast, the supply shock v re ectsdisruptions inthe normal in ation process, such as that caused byan oilembargo or a change inthe exchange rate. The supply shock is thought toexhibit more high-frequency variation than thenatural rate. 1 Toimplementthis equation, somethinghas tobe said about how expectations areformed. One approach istoassume adaptiveexpectations, according towhich expected in ation isaweightedaverage of past in ation. Thesimplest version is to e positthat expectedin ation equalslast period ’s in ation: 5 2 1 . The in ation- unemploymenttradeoff then becomes 5 21 2 a~U 2 U*! 1 v. Therational expectations
Recommended publications
  • Total and Short-Term Unemployment and the Recent Behavior of Prices and Wages
    Total and Short-term Unemployment and the Recent Behavior of Prices and Wages Background Background (cont.) • FRBNY staff analysis: considerable slack remains • Motivation to explore these issues: “missing in the economy deflation puzzle” • Labor market flows • “Standard” Phillips Curve models → very low inflation or deflation in the aftermath of the Great Recession • This assessment is an important factor in FRBNY • Compensation growth also should have been lower staff outlook • A restraining factor for price- and wage-inflation • One proposed explanation: Short-term/long-term unemployment distinction • However, recent research has focused on two • Long-term unemployed (unemployment duration > 27 issues: weeks): limited impact on price/wage inflation • Extent of slack in labor market • Short-term unemployment near historical average: less • Magnitude of restraining effect on inflation from slack than implied by conventional measures conventional measure(s) of labor market slack Unemployment Rates by Duration Illustration of “Standard” Approach: Gordon (2013) Percent Percent 12 12 • Price-inflation (PCE deflator) Phillips curve model: Correlation Between Short- • Lagged inflation terms term and Long-term 10 Unemployment 10 • Unemployment gap based on: 1976—2007 0.63 • Total unemployment rate 1976—2013 0.28 8 8 • Short-term unemployment rate Total Unemployment • Supply shocks: 6 6 • Food and energy inflation • Relative import price inflation 4 Short-term 4 • Trend productivity acceleration/deceleration variable Unemployment Long-term • Other features: 2 Unemployment 2 • 1960:Q1-2013:Q1 sample period 0 0 • Joint estimation of time-varying NAIRU 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009 2012 4 Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics Total and Short-term Unemployment and the Recent Behavior of Prices and Wages Evaluation of Short-term vs.
    [Show full text]
  • Publishing and Promotion in Economics: the Curse of the Top Five
    Publishing and Promotion in Economics: The Curse of the Top Five James J. Heckman 2017 AEA Annual Meeting Chicago, IL January 7th, 2017 Heckman Curse of the Top Five Top 5 Influential, But Far From Sole Source of Influence or Outlet for Creativity Heckman Curse of the Top Five Table 1: Ranking of 2, 5 and 10 Year Impact Factors as of 2015 Rank 2 Years 5 Years 10 Years 1. JEL JEL JEL 2. QJE QJE QJE 3. JOF JOF JOF 4. JEP JEP JPE 5. ReStud JPE JEP 6. ECMA AEJae ECMA 7. AEJae ECMA AER 8. AER AER ReStud 9. JPE ReStud JOLE 10. JOLE AEJma EJ 11. AEJep AEJep JHR 12. AEJma EJ JOE 13. JME JOLE JME 14. EJ JHR HE 15. HE JME RED 16. JHR HE EER 17. JOE JOE - 18. AEJmi AEJmi - 19. RED RED - 20. EER EER - Note: Definition of abbreviated names: JEL - Journal of Economic Literature, JOF - Journal of Finance, JEP - Journal of Economic Perspectives, AEJae-American Economic Journal Applied Economics, AER - American Economic Review, JOLE-Journal of Labor Economics, AEJep-American Economic Journal Economic Policy, AEJma-American Economic Journal Macroeconomics, JME-Journal of Monetary Economics, EJ-Economic Journal, HE-Health Economics, JHR-Journal of Human Resources, JOE-Journal of Econometrics, AEJmi-American Economic Journal Microeconomics, RED-Review of Economic Dynamics, EER-European Economic Review; Source: Journal Citation Reports (Thomson Reuters, 2016). Heckman Curse of the Top Five Figure 1: Articles Published in Last 10 years by RePEc's T10 Authors (Last 10 Years Ranking) (a) T10 Authors (Unadjusted) (b) T10 Authors (Adjusted) Prop.
    [Show full text]
  • The Process of Inflation Expectations' Formation
    The Process of Inflation Expectations’ * Formation Anna Loleyt** Ilya Gurov*** Bank of Russia July 2010 Abstract The aim of the investigation is to classify and systematize groups of economic agents with different types of inflation expectations in information economy. Particularly it’s found out that it is not feasible to exclude the possibility of current signals perception by economic agents. The analysis has also shown that there is an uncertainty in economy when authorities redeem monetary policy promises, but their action wouldn’t influence on average inflation expectations of economic agents. The investigation results testify the flat existence of agents in economy which are characterizing with rational, quasi-adaptive (including adaptive) and also arbitral inflation expectations. Keywords: information economy, information signal, information perception, agent belief in information, inflation expectations, quasi-adaptive expectations, arbitral expectations. *Acknowledgments: The first authors gratefully acknowledge support through the Bank of Russia. Especially we would like to thank Mr. Alexey V. Ulyukaev for helpful research assistance and Mrs. Nadezhda Yu. Ivanova for strong support. We are also grateful to Mr. Sergey S. Studnikov for his comments. **General Economic Department, Bank of Russia, 12 Neglinnaya Street, Moscow, 107016 Russia Faculty of Economics, Lomonosov Moscow State University, Moscow, Russia Email: [email protected] ***General Economic Department, Bank of Russia, 12 Neglinnaya Street, Moscow, 107016 Russia Faculty of Economics, Lomonosov Moscow State University, Moscow, Russia Email: [email protected] Abbreviations: a variety of information signals. W an element of a variety of information signals that is an information signal. w economic agents. x q a number of signals.
    [Show full text]
  • The Narrow and Broad Arguments for Free Trade Author(S): Paul R
    American Economic Association The Narrow and Broad Arguments for Free Trade Author(s): Paul R. Krugman Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 83, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Hundred and Fifth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association (May, 1993), pp. 362-366 Published by: American Economic Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2117691 Accessed: 02/12/2010 04:57 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=aea. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The American Economic Review.
    [Show full text]
  • New Keynesian Macroeconomics: Empirically Tested in the Case of Republic of Macedonia
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Josheski, Dushko; Lazarov, Darko Preprint New Keynesian Macroeconomics: Empirically tested in the case of Republic of Macedonia Suggested Citation: Josheski, Dushko; Lazarov, Darko (2012) : New Keynesian Macroeconomics: Empirically tested in the case of Republic of Macedonia, ZBW - Deutsche Zentralbibliothek für Wirtschaftswissenschaften, Leibniz-Informationszentrum Wirtschaft, Kiel und Hamburg This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/64403 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu NEW KEYNESIAN MACROECONOMICS: EMPIRICALLY TESTED IN THE CASE OF REPUBLIC OF MACEDONIA Dushko Josheski 1 Darko Lazarov2 Abstract In this paper we test New Keynesian propositions about inflation and unemployment trade off with the New Keynesian Phillips curve and the proposition of non-neutrality of money.
    [Show full text]
  • Adaptive Expectations Versus Rational Expectations: Evidence from the Lab
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Repositori Institucional de la Universitat Jaume I Adaptive Expectations versus Rational Expectations: Evidence from the lab Annarita Colasante1, Antonio Palestrini, Alberto Russo, Mauro Gallegati Universit`aPolitecnica delle Marche, Piazzale Martelli 8, Ancona, Italy. Abstract The aim of the present work is to shed light on the extensive debate about expectations in financial market. We analyze the behavior of subjects in an exper- imental environment in which it is possible to directly observe expectations since the sole task of each player is to predict the future price of an asset. We investi- gate the mechanism of expectation formation in two different contexts: in the first, the fundamental value is constant; in the second, the fundamental price increases over repetitions. First of all we observe if, according to the main results shown in Palestrini and Gallegati (2015), there is a convergence to the rational equilibrium even if agents have adaptive expectations. Moreover, we concentrate on the accu- racy of aggregate forecasts compared with the individual forecasts. We find that there is collective rationality instead of individual rationality. In the context of increasing fundamental value, contrary to the theoretical predictions, players are able to capture the trend but they underestimate that value. This implies that if all agents make their forecasts according to an adaptive scheme, there is no full convergence to the rational expectations equilibrium. Keywords: Price forecasting, Financial market, Experiment, Panel data, Forecasting practice 1. Introduction The recent financial crisis highlighted the importance of agents' behaviour in the financial market and, in turn, the impact of individual financial choices in the real economy.
    [Show full text]
  • A New Keynesian Model with Heterogeneous Expectations
    ARTICLE IN PRESS Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 33 (2009) 1036–1051 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jedc A New Keynesian model with heterogeneous expectations William A. Branch a, Bruce McGough b,Ã a University of California, Irvine, USA b Department of Economics, Oregon State University, Corvallis, OR 97330, USA article info abstract Article history: Within a New Keynesian model, we incorporate bounded rationality at the individual Received 30 January 2008 agent level, and we determine restrictions on expectations operators sufficient to imply Accepted 14 November 2008 aggregate IS and AS relations of the same functional form as those under rationality. This Available online 14 February 2009 result provides dual implications: the strong nature of the restrictions required to JEL classification: achieve aggregation serve as a caution to researchers—imposing heterogeneous E52 expectations at an aggregate level may be ill-advised; on the other hand, accepting E32 the necessary restrictions provides for tractable analysis of expectations heterogeneity. D83 As an example, we consider a case where a fraction of agents are rational and the D84 remainder are adaptive, and find specifications that are determinate under rationality may possess multiple equilibria in case of expectations heterogeneity. Keywords: & 2009 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. Heterogeneous expectations Monetary policy Adaptive learning Aggregation 1. Introduction During the
    [Show full text]
  • HYSTERESIS and the NAIRU: DOI: 10.18267/J.Pep.526 the CASE of COUNTRIES Accepted: 25
    Prague Economic Papers HYSTERESIS AND THE NAIRU: DOI: 10.18267/j.pep.526 THE CASE OF COUNTRIES Accepted: 25. 6. 2014 IN TRANSITION Published: 20. 7. 2015 Gordana Marjanovic, Ljiljana Maksimovic,1Nenad Stanisic* Abstract: The paper examines the hysteresis hypothesis in unemployment in the case of eight selected countries in transition, using the Kalman fi lter and testing whether the NAIRU time series are ONLINE FIRST ONLINE stationary. The empirical results show that the hysteresis eff ect is confi rmed for the majority of the countries. Testing the infl uence of the infl ation growth rate on the decline in the NAIRU and / vice versa, performed using the panel regression with fi xed eff ect, confi rmed that the increase in infl ation leads to decline in the NAIRU. The conclusion also suggests the existence of the impact of actual unemployment rate on the NAIRU, which may be aff ected by the change in aggregate demand. Keywords: hysteresis, NAIRU, Kalman fi lter, infl ation, unemployment. JEL Classifi cation: E24, E30, E50, C13 1. Introduction Unemployment is a major problem, both in developed market economies, and countries that have gone through the transitional changes. Therefore, the goal of economic policy in modern economies is to reduce unemployment and thereby to avoid the rising infl a- tionary pressures. In achieving this goal, the concept of Non - Accelerating Infl ation Rate of Unemployment (NAIRU) and policy recommendations arising from this concept are of great importance. NAIRU concept was fi rst introduced by Modigliani and Papademos in 1975 (Snowdon, Vane, 2005, p. 402). Among economists, there are signifi cant discrepancies in the defi nitions of the concepts of natural rate of unemployment (NRU), which was founded by Nobel Laureate M.
    [Show full text]
  • Overview of Models and Methods for Measuring Economic Agent's Expectations
    Overview of models and methods for measuring economic agent's expectations Tine Janžek, Petra Ziherl Abstract Agents' expectations play an important role as one of the basic building blocks of theoretical macroeconomic models. In practise, though, their intangible nature has always caused consistency difficulties regarding their measurement and estimation methods. Increased importance and use of econometric modelling in contemporary financial stability analyses has triggered numerous advances in methods for measuring empirical expectations. Due to the shortage of empirical data for a more detailed evaluation of expectation measures, this article focuses more on the presentation of the most commonly established methods for their capturing and the methodological aspect of the prevailing models. KEYWORDS: expectations, rational expectations, surveys, qualitative measures, quantitative measures, probabilistic measures, visual analog scale, probability approach, regression approach, inflation, VAR. Expectation examination approaches Modern economic theory recognizes that the main difference between economics and natural sciences lies in the forward-looking decisions made by economic agents. Expectations play a key role in every segment of macroeconomics. In consumption theory the paradigm life-cycle and permanent income approaches stress the role of expected future incomes. In investment decisions present-value calculations are conditional on expected future prices and sales. Asset prices (equity prices, interest rates, and exchange rates) also clearly depend on expected future prices. Today we can distinct two major expectation paradigms and concepts, where the second became the mainstream approach for further development of expectation examination: Adaptive expectations (AE) represent a hypothesis in economics which states that people form their expectations about what will happen in the future based on what has happened in the past.
    [Show full text]
  • Hysteresis in Unemployment: Old and New Evidence
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HYSTERESIS IN UNEMPLOYMENT: OLD AND NEW EVIDENCE Laurence M. Ball Working Paper 14818 http://www.nber.org/papers/w14818 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 March 2009 This paper was prepared for "A Phillips Curve Retrospective" sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston in June 2008. I am grateful for research assistance from Sandeep Mazumder and for comments from V.V. Chari, Jordi Gali, Engelbert Stockhammer, two anonymous referees, and conference participants. The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2009 by Laurence M. Ball. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Hysteresis in Unemployment: Old and New Evidence Laurence M. Ball NBER Working Paper No. 14818 March 2009 JEL No. E24 ABSTRACT This paper argues that hysteresis helps explain the long-run behavior of unemployment. The natural rate of unemployment is influenced by the path of actual unemployment, and hence by shifts in aggregate demand. I review past evidence for hysteresis effects and present new evidence for 20 developed countries. A central finding is that large increases in the natural rate are associated with disinflations, and large decreases with run-ups in inflation.
    [Show full text]
  • On the Mechanics of Economic Development*
    Journal of Monetary Economics 22 (1988) 3-42. North-Holland ON THE MECHANICS OF ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT* Robert E. LUCAS, Jr. University of Chicago, Chicago, 1L 60637, USA Received August 1987, final version received February 1988 This paper considers the prospects for constructing a neoclassical theory of growth and interna­ tional trade that is consistent with some of the main features of economic development. Three models are considered and compared to evidence: a model emphasizing physical capital accumula­ tion and technological change, a model emphasizing human capital accumulation through school­ ing. and a model emphasizing specialized human capital accumulation through learning-by-doing. 1. Introduction By the problem of economic development I mean simply the problem of accounting for the observed pattern, across countries and across time, in levels and rates of growth of per capita income. This may seem too narrow a definition, and perhaps it is, but thinking about income patterns will neces­ sarily involve us in thinking about many other aspects of societies too. so I would suggest that we withhold judgment on the scope of this definition until we have a clearer idea of where it leads us. The main features of levels and rates of growth of national incomes are well enough known to all of us, but I want to begin with a few numbers, so as to set a quantitative tone and to keep us from getting mired in the wrong kind of details. Unless I say otherwise, all figures are from the World Bank's World Development Report of 1983. The diversity across countries in measured per capita income levels is literally too great to be believed.
    [Show full text]
  • A Cliometric Counterfactual: What If There Had Been Neither Fogel Nor
    A Cliometric Counterfactual: What if There Had Been Neither Fogel nor North? By Claude Diebolt (CNRS, University of Strasbourg) and Michael Haupert (University of Wisconsin-La Crosse Author contact information: [email protected] [email protected] Preliminary draft, please do not quote Abstract 1993 Nobel laureates Robert Fogel and Douglass North were pioneers in the “new” economic history, or cliometrics. Their impact on the economic history discipline is great, though not without its critics. In this essay, we use both the “old” narrative form of economic history, and the “new” cliometric form, to analyze the impact each had on the evolution of economic history. Introduction In December of 1960 the “Purdue Conference on the Application of Economic Theory and Quantitative Techniques to Problems of History” was held on the campus of Purdue University.1 It is recognized as the first meeting of what is now known as the Cliometric Society.2 While it was the first formal meeting of a group of like-minded applicants of economic theory and quantitative methods to the study of economic history, it was not the first time such a concept had been practiced or mentioned in the literature.3 Cliometrics was a long time in coming, but when it arrived, it eventually overran the approach to the discipline of economic history, leading to a bifurcation of the economists and historians who practice the art, and the blurring of the distinction between cliometricians and theorists who use historical data. Clio’s roots are historical in nature, and its focus on theory has actually come full circle over the last century and a half.
    [Show full text]