Economics 103 Fall 2007 Section F01 Multiple Choice

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Economics 103 Fall 2007 Section F01 Multiple Choice Economics 103 Fall 2007 Section F01 Multiple Choice 1. When the price of rice rises, quantity demanded of beans falls. The cross-price elasticity of demand for rice and beans must be a. equal to zero. b. larger than zero. c. less than zero. d. cannot be estimated. 1. As the price of rice rises, quantity demanded of rice will fall. If the quantity demanded of beans also falls as the price of rice rises, then rice and beans must be eaten together and therefore they are complement goods. The cross-price elasticity of demand is negative. Answer: C. 2. If the demand curve for a good is perfectly price inelastic and the government imposes a tax in the market, a. there will be no deadweight loss. b. the government’s tax revenue will equal the loss in producer surplus. c. the government’s tax revenue will be more than the loss in producer surplus. d. the government’s tax revenue will be less than the loss in producer surplus. 2. The figure below shows that as the government imposes a tax in a market where the demand curve is perfectly price inelastic, there will be no deadweight loss. Triangle B is the producer surplus both before and after the tax and rectangle C is the government’s revenue from the tax. Answer: A. 3. As soon as the price of a good goes up, suppliers would like to produce more but may not be able to because they cannot immediately hire more skilled laborers and/or purchase new machinery. However, over time firms can hire more workers and purchase more machinery. Consequently, the price elasticity of supply a. decreases over time. b. increases over time. c. remains constant over time. d. may increase or decrease over time. 3. As the firm has more time to change the number of workers and purchase or sell machinery, the more it will be able to change quantity supplied due to a given percent change in price. Answer: B. 4. Assume that the market demand curve is perfectly price inelastic and the supply curve is up-sloping. When an excise tax is imposed, the deadweight loss will be a. the maximum positive value. b. zero. c. more than zero. d. less than zero. 4. With the vertical demand curve, the price increases by the amount of the excise tax. The total loss of surplus is equal to the total tax revenues. Therefore, there is zero deadweight loss. Answer: B. 5. Along the demand curve in the accompanying figure, the price elasticity of demand a. is constant and equal to its slope. b. is larger at P2 than at P1. c. is smaller at P2 than at P1. d. is unit-elastic. 5. The demand curve shown is a linear demand curve. Linear demand curves have constant slopes but price elasticity varies along the curve. In particular, the price elasticity of demand is larger at higher prices than at lower prices. Since P2 is a lower price than P1, the price elasticity of demand must be smaller at P2 than at P1. Answer: C. 6. If the demand curve is perfectly price elastic, a. consumer surplus will equal zero. b. consumer surplus will equal producer surplus. c. consumer surplus will equal total surplus. d. consumer surplus will be greater than producer surplus. 6. If the demand curve is perfectly price elastic, consumers are only willing to buy units of the good at one particular price. That price must be the market price. Since there is no difference between the price consumers are willing to pay and the market price, there is no area below the demand curve and above the market price and consumer surplus is zero. The figure below shows the answer graphically. Answer: A. 7. The accompanying figure shows the weekly demand and supply curves for ice cream that we discussed in earlier questions. If the government imposes a tax of $0.75 per cone collected from the producers, what will be the consumers’ burden from the tax? a. The consumers will pay $2.75 for 500 cones after the tax for a burden to them of $0.75 per cone. b. The consumers will pay $2.50 for 600 cones after the tax for a burden to them of $0.50 per cone. c. The consumers will pay $2.25 for 700 cones after the tax for a burden to them of $0.25 per cone. d. The consumers will continue to pay $2.00 for 800 cones after the tax and avoid any burden from the tax. 7. When the government imposes a tax of $0.75, the supply curve shifts up by that amount. The new equilibrium price will be $2.50 per cone and the new equilibrium quantity will be 600 cones. See the following figures. The government’s revenue from the tax will be $450 (= $0.75 ⋅ 600). The consumers paid $2.00 per cone prior to the tax, so the consumers are paying $0.50 of the tax on the 600 cones or $300. Answer: B. 8. In the problem before, what is the producers’ burden from the tax? a. The producers will receive a price of $1.75 for 600 cones after the tax for a burden to them of $0.25 per cone. b. The producers will receive a price of $1.50 for 700 cones after the tax for a burden to them of $0.50 per cone. c. The producers will receive a price of $1.25 for 800 cones after the tax for a burden to them of $0.75 per cone. d. There is no burden to the producers—the consumers will pay all of the tax. 8. The producers’ net price is $1.75—compared with the initial price of $2.00. The producers are paying $0.25 of the tax on the 600 cones or $150. Answer: A. 9. If the government imposes a price ceiling in a market, the resulting shortage will be smaller when demand is _________ and supply is ___________ . a. elastic; inelastic b. inelastic; inelastic c. elastic; elastic d. perfectly inelastic; elastic 9. The shortage resulting from a price ceiling will be smaller, the smaller the price elasticities of supply and demand. Answer: B. 10. A higher minimum wage will increase total income of the unskilled labour if the demand for unskilled labour is a. elastic. b. inelastic. c. unit-elastic. d. perfectly elastic. 10. Since both wage rate as well as labour income increased, it is a case of inelastic demand. Answer: B. Problem The province needs to raise money, and the premier has a choice of imposing an excise tax of the same amount on one of two previously untaxed goods: the province can either tax sales of restaurant meals or sales of gasoline. Both the demand for and the supply of restaurant meals are more elastic than the demand for and the supply of gasoline. If the premier wants to minimize the deadweight loss caused by the tax, which good should be taxed? For each good, draw a diagram that illustrates the deadweight loss from taxation. 1. The tax should be imposed on sales of gasoline. Since both demand for and supply of gasoline are less elastic, changes in the price of gasoline will result in smaller reductions in the quantity demanded and the quantity supplied. As a result, fewer transactions are discouraged by the tax—in other words, less total surplus (consumer and producer surplus) is lost. Panel (a) of the accompanying diagram illustrates a tax imposed on sales of gasoline, for which both demand and supply are less elastic; panel (b) illustrates a tax imposed on sales of restaurant meals, for which both demand and supply are more elastic. As you can see, deadweight loss—the shaded triangle —is larger in panel (b) than in panel (a). .
Recommended publications
  • THE DEADWEIGHT LOSS from Alan J. Auerbach Working Paper No. 2510
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE DEADWEIGHT LOSS FROM "NONNEUTRAL" CAPITAL INCOME TAXATION Alan J. Auerbach Working Paper No. 2510 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 February 1988 I am grateful to the National Science Foundation for financial support (grant #SES— 8617495), to Kevin Hassett for excellent research assistance, and to Jim Hines, Larry Kotlikoff and participants in seminars at Columbia, NBER, Penn and Western Ontario for connnents on earlier drafts. The research reported here is part of the NBERs research program in Taxation. Any opinions expressed are those of the author and not those of the National Bureau of Economic Research, Support from The Lynde and Harry Bradley Foundation is gratefully acknowledged. NBER Working Paper #2510 The Deadweight Loss froni "Nonneutral" Capital Income Taxation ABSTRACT This paper develops an overlapping generations general equilibrium growth model with an explicit characterization of the role of capital goods in the evaluate and production process. The model is rich enough in structure to measure simultaneously the different distortions associated with capital income taxation (across sectors, across assets and across time) yet simple enough to yield intuitive analytical results as well. The main result is that uniform capital income taxation is almost certainly suboptimal, theoretically, but that empirically, optimal deviations from uniform taxation are inconsequential. We also find that though the gains from a move to uniform taxation are not large in absolute magnitude these of gains would be offset only by an overall rise in capital income tax rates several percentage points. A separate contribution of the paper is the development of a technique for distinguishing intergenerational transfers from efficiency gains in analyzing the effects of policy changes on long—run welfare.
    [Show full text]
  • Externalities and Public Goods Introduction 17
    17 Externalities and Public Goods Introduction 17 Chapter Outline 17.1 Externalities 17.2 Correcting Externalities 17.3 The Coase Theorem: Free Markets Addressing Externalities on Their Own 17.4 Public Goods 17.5 Conclusion Introduction 17 Pollution is a major fact of life around the world. • The United States has areas (notably urban) struggling with air quality; the health costs are estimated at more than $100 billion per year. • Much pollution is due to coal-fired power plants operating both domestically and abroad. Other forms of pollution are also common. • The noise of your neighbor’s party • The person smoking next to you • The mess in someone’s lawn Introduction 17 These outcomes are evidence of a market failure. • Markets are efficient when all transactions that positively benefit society take place. • An efficient market takes all costs and benefits, both private and social, into account. • Similarly, the smoker in the park is concerned only with his enjoyment, not the costs imposed on other people in the park. • An efficient market takes these additional costs into account. Asymmetric information is a source of market failure that we considered in the last chapter. Here, we discuss two further sources. 1. Externalities 2. Public goods Externalities 17.1 Externalities: A cost or benefit that affects a party not directly involved in a transaction. • Negative externality: A cost imposed on a party not directly involved in a transaction ‒ Example: Air pollution from coal-fired power plants • Positive externality: A benefit conferred on a party not directly involved in a transaction ‒ Example: A beekeeper’s bees not only produce honey but can help neighboring farmers by pollinating crops.
    [Show full text]
  • Welfare Standards Underlying Antitrust Enforcement: What You Measure Is What You Get
    United States of America Federal Trade Commission Welfare Standards Underlying Antitrust Enforcement: What You Measure is What You Get Christine S. Wilson∗ Commissioner, U.S. Federal Trade Commission Luncheon Keynote Address at George Mason Law Review 22nd Annual Antitrust Symposium: Antitrust at the Crossroads? Arlington, VA February 15, 2019 ∗ The views expressed in these remarks are my own and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Trade Commission or any other Commissioner. Many thanks to my Attorney Advisor, Tom Klotz, for assisting in the preparation of these remarks. I. Introduction It is delightful to join you today at the George Mason University Antonin Scalia Law School. Many thanks to the George Mason Law Review and the Law and Economics Center for inviting me. As always, they have put together a great program. Before launching into the substance, I must provide the standard disclaimer: The views I express today are my own, and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Trade Commission or any other Commissioner. With the administrative details out of the way, I would like to spend my time this afternoon discussing the appropriate welfare standard for antitrust enforcement. This topic was the subject of two panels at the FTC’s Hearings on Competition and Consumer Protection in the 21st Century in November 2018.1 The discussion of whether we should continue to rely on the consumer welfare standard, which has long underpinned our approach to antitrust, arises in the context of a larger debate. According to some critics, lax antitrust enforcement has led to historic levels of consolidation and concentration, which have led to greater income inequality, stagnant wages, and reduced innovation.2 These observers recognize that the consumer welfare standard, the yardstick used to evaluate mergers and competitive conduct for more than 40 years, is an intellectual barrier for their desired approach to enforcement.
    [Show full text]
  • Deadweight Loss by ERIC NIELSEN
    RF Fall2005 v10 revisedpg9.ps - 10/14/2005 4:54 PM JARGONALERT Deadweight Loss BY ERIC NIELSEN t one point or another, all of us have received an inefficient gift, such as grandparents, are also those most unwanted gift from a well-meaning friend or relative. likely to give cash instead of a gift-in-kind. AOut of politeness we may wear the unwanted gar- It is worth noting that Waldfogel’s study explicitly ment at the next family reunion, or make a halfhearted stab ignores any sentimental value people may place on received at reading the 700-page tome. Still, we must reach the gifts. Some psychology studies have found that people place inescapable conclusion that the money spent on the gift was a very high premium on the worth of things they have almost entirely wasted. received as gifts. If this is indeed the case, then gift giving The loss in value described above — the difference could at times be a form of “value creation.” At the very least between what was paid for the gift and what the gift is there may still be social reasons to engage in gift giving, even worth to the recipient — is one example of the economic if it does result in a deadweight loss. concept of “deadweight loss.” Technically, deadweight loss Certain government actions may also produce dead- is defined as the waste resulting from economic inefficien- weight losses. For instance, taxes prevent sellers and buyers cy of any kind, be it through poorly designed regulation, from realizing all the gains from trade, and subsidies encour- antiquated production techniques, leaky pipes, monopoly age more consumption than otherwise would occur.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 6: Consumer and Producer Surplus
    South Dakota State University Economics 201: Principles of Microeconomics Efficiency of Markets and the Role of Government Surplus Measures Consumer surplus is defined as the difference between a consumer’s willingness to pay and what he or she actually has to pay (the price of the good). When analyzing a market, CS is just the area under the demand curve and above the price. If the demand curve is linear, it is easy to calculate total CS as the area of the triangle formed by the P-axis intercept, the market price, and quantity demanded. e.g. Auto industry. P (1000s$/car) $50 $24 D Q (cars/year) 60,000 (In the above diagram, $50,000 is sometimes called a “choke price”). If the price of a car is $24,000 and 60,000 are sold CS is the area of the resulting triangle, so CS = (1/2)(60,000)($26,000) = $780,000. Basically, this means that consumers gain $780,000 from the opportunity to buy 60,000 cars at a price of $24,000 each. Producer surplus is the difference between the price (what the seller actually gets) and cost (what the seller would have settled for). Again, notice that producer surplus Development of this review sheet was made possible by funding from the US Department of Education through South Dakota’s EveryTeacher Teacher Quality Enhancement grant. corresponds to an area. In this case, it is the area below price and above supply. If the supply curve were linear, it would be easy to calculate PS for the industry.
    [Show full text]
  • Marshallian Cross Diagrams and Their Uses Before Alfred Marshall: the Origins of Supply and Demand Geometry
    Marshallian Cross Diagrams and Their Uses before Alfred Marshall: The Origins of Supply and Demand Geometry ThonaasM. Humphrey And Karl Rau (184 l), Jules Dupuit (1844), Hans von Mangoldt (1863), and Fleeming Jenkin (1870) thor- Undoubtedly the simplest. and most frequently oughly developed it years before Marshall presented used tool of microeconomic analysis is the conven- it in his Pzm Theory of Domestic Vafues (1879) and tional partial equilibrium demand-and-supply-curve later in his Pnitciples of fionomics (1890). Far from diagram of the textbooks. Economics professors merely introducing the diagram, these writers applied and their students put the diagram to at least six it to derive many of the concepts and theories often main uses. They use it to depict the equilibrium or attributed to Marshall or his followers. The notions market-clearing price and quantity of any particular of price elasticity of demand and supply, of stability good or factor input. They employ it to show how of equilibrium, of the possibility of multiple equilibria, (Walrasian) price or (Marshallian) quantity adjust- of comparative statics analyses involving shifts in the ments ensure this equilibrium: the first by eliminating curves, of consumers’ and producers’ surplus, of con- excess supply and demand, the second by eradicating stant, increasing and decreasing costs, of pricing of disparities between supply price and demand price. joint and composite products, of potential benefits They use it to illustrate how parametric shifts in of price discrimination, of tax incidence analysis, of demand and supply curves induced by changes in deadweight-welfare-loss triangles and the allocative tastes, incomes, technology, factor prices, and prices inefficiency of monopoly: all find expression in of related goods operate to alter a good’s equilibrium early expositions of the diagram.
    [Show full text]
  • Social Welfare, Redistribution, and the Tradeoff Between Efficiency and Equity, with Developing Country Applications
    Social Welfare, Redistribution, and the Tradeoff between Efficiency and Equity, with Developing Country Applications Jon Bakija Williams College First Draft: August 2012 This Draft: August 2014 Abstract: The economic literature on “optimal income taxation” addresses the question of how to design tax and transfer policy so as to maximize “social welfare,” which is some function of the well- being of all members of society. It clarifies how the social-welfare-maximizing policy depends on one’s philosophy of distributive justice, and on empirical evidence about the behavioral response to incentives, and thus provides a systematic way of evaluating the tradeoff between equity and efficiency. Here, I explain the key insights of the optimal income taxation literature in a way that should be accessible to those with a familiarity with introductory economics, and then provide a brief introduction to some interesting pieces of evidence from around the world that are relevant to this question. 1 I. Social Welfare, the Tradeoff between Equity and Efficiency, and Optimal Income Taxation: Theory Introduction As Arthur Okun (1975) memorably put it, taxing the better-off to finance transfers to the worse- off is like “carrying water in a leaky bucket.” The leak represents the administrative costs of the tax and transfer system, and the deadweight losses caused by the fact that taxes and transfers distort incentives, causing people to change their behavior in an effort to reduce their tax bill or increase the transfer received. Different philosophies of distributive justice lead to different conclusions about how much of a leak we should be willing to accept before we stop carrying further buckets.
    [Show full text]
  • ECONOMICS and MICROECONOMICS Paul Krugman | Robin Wells
    THIRD EDITION ECONOMICS and MICROECONOMICS Paul Krugman | Robin Wells Chapter 5 Price Controls and Quotas: Meddling with Markets • The meaning of price controls and quantity controls, two kinds of government interventions in markets • How price and quantity controls create WHAT YOU problems and can make a market WILL LEARN inefficient IN THIS • What deadweight loss is • Why the predictable side effects of CHAPTER intervention in markets often lead economists to be skeptical of its usefulness • Who benefits and who loses from market interventions, and why they are used despite their well-known problems Why Governments Control Prices • The market price moves to the level at which the quantity supplied equals the quantity demanded. But, this equilibrium price does not necessarily please either buyers or sellers. • Therefore, the government intervenes to regulate prices by imposing price controls, which are legal restrictions on how high or low a market price may go. • Price ceiling is the maximum price sellers are allowed to charge for a good or service. • Price floor is the minimum price buyers are required to pay for a good or service. Price Ceilings • Price ceilings are typically imposed during crises—wars, harvest failures, natural disasters—because these events often lead to sudden price increases that hurt many people but produce big gains for a lucky few. • Examples: . U.S. government–imposed ceilings on aluminum and steel during World War II . Rent control in New York City The Market for Apartments in the Absence of Government Controls
    [Show full text]
  • The Economics of Food and Agricultural Markets
    Chapter 2. Welfare Analysis of Government Policies 2.1 Price Ceiling In some circumstances, the government believes that the free market equilibrium price is too high. If there is political pressure to act, a government can impose a maximum price, or price ceiling, on a market. Price Ceiling = A maximum price policy to help consumers. A price ceiling is imposed to provide relief to consumers from high prices. In food and agriculture, these policies are most often used in low-income nations, where political power is concentrated in urban consumers. If food prices increase, there can be demonstrations and riots to put pressure on the government to impose price ceilings. In the United States, price ceilings were imposed on meat products in the 1970s under President Richard M. Nixon. Price ceilings were also used for natural gas during this period of high inflation. It was believed that the cost of living had increased beyond the ability of family earnings to pay for necessities, and the market interventions were used to make beef, other meat, and natural gas more affordable. Price ceilings are often imposed on housing prices in US urban areas. Rent control has been a longtime feature in New York City, where rent-controlled apartments continue to have low rental rates relative to the free market rate. The boom in the software industry has increased housing prices and rental rates enormously in the San Francisco Bay Area, Seattle, and the Puget Sound region. Rent control is being considered in both places to make San Francisco and Seattle more affordable for middle-class workers.
    [Show full text]
  • Econ 301 Intermediate Microeconomics Week 2 Lecture - Calculus of Consumer and Producer Surplus
    Econ 301 Intermediate Microeconomics Week 2 Lecture - Calculus of Consumer and Producer Surplus 1 Consumer and Producer Surplus Every time you go to the supermarket and purchase something, you benefit (or at least you expect to benefit), otherwise you wouldn't have made the purchase. Similarly, the owner of the supermarket benefits, otherwise they wouldn't have sold the item too you. Measuring how much each of you benefits is a tricky question, especially if we want to compare them. In economics, we solve the problem by not actually trying to measure the benefits; rather, we try to measure the dollar value of the benefits to both you and the supermarket owner. Then we can add these up and use it as a sort of crude approximation to the total benefits to everyone in the market (even though it's not clear what exactly we mean by \total benefits” but we'll leave that discussion for philosophy class). When we measure the dollar value of all benefits in a market, we split it into two parts | the supply side and the demand side. Consumer surplus measures the demand side | it is the difference between the amount of money the consumer is willing to pay for a good and the amount of money they did pay, summed across each unit of the good purchased (which may be worth less and less as more are purchased) and summed across all consuemrs. Producer surplus measures the supply side | it is the difference between the amount of money the producer receives for the good and the amount they were willing to sell the good for, summed over each good sold and each producer.
    [Show full text]
  • Government Cheese: a Case Study of Price Supports
    Case Study Government Cheese: A Case Study of Price Supports Katherine Lacy1, Todd Sørensen1, Eric Gibbons2 1University of Nevada, Reno; 2The Ohio State University at Marion JEL Codes: A22, Q18, H50 Keywords: Agricultural Policy, Government Cheese, Government Policy, Market Inefficiencies, Price Floor, Price Support Abstract In this paper, we present a case study that uses a Planet Money podcast to introduce microeconomics students to several important economic concepts. The podcast, which is about a policy intervention in the dairy industry, reveals the unintended consequences of government price supports under the Food and Agriculture Act of 1977, which increased dairy price supports through government purchases of manufactured milk products. By 1981, the government was struggling to reduce its stockpile of 560 million pounds of cheddar cheese stored in caves across the Midwest. This case study examines the history of dairy price supports and the government’s resulting acquisition of millions of pounds of cheese, butter, and nonfat dry milk. Available on request are detailed teaching notes with learning objectives and background materials, questions (and answers) for student evaluation, and a table displaying meta-data for each question, such as learning objective, difficulty level, and Bloom’s Taxonomy level. 1 Introduction John Block pulled out a five-pound block of molding yellow cheese, showed it to President Ronald Reagan, and exclaimed, “We’ve got 60 million of these that the government owns! . It’s moldy, it’s deteriorating. We can’t find a market for it, we can’t sell it, and we’re looking to try and give some of it away” (Thomas 1981).
    [Show full text]
  • Microeconomics Topic 8 “Apply Principles of Consumer/Producer Surplus to Explain Efficient Level of Production and Sales in a Market.”
    Microeconomics Topic 8 “Apply principles of consumer/producer surplus to explain efficient level of production and sales in a market.” Reference: Gregory Mankiw’s Principles of Microeconomics, 2nd edition, Chapter 7. Consumer Surplus Consumer surplus is the buyer's net gain from purchasing a good. Put another way, it is the excess of what a buyer would have been willing to pay for a good over what he actually had to pay for that good. Graphically, it is the area below the demand curve, above the price, and left of the quantity bought. For example, you might be willing, if you had to, to pay $20 to make an important phone call. If the price you actually have to pay for that phone call is $1, then you earn consumer surplus of $19 when you make the call. Figure 2.1 Price A: $3 of CS B: $2 of CS 9 8 C: $1 of CS 7 D: $0 of CS 6 Total CS=3+2+1=$6 Demand 1 2 3 4 Quantity In figure 2.1, we suppose there are 4 consumers: A, B, C, and D. A is willing to pay $9 for one unit of the good. B will pay $8, C will pay $7, and D will pay $6. If the market price of the good is $6 per unit, then A earns consumer surplus of $3, since he was willing to pay $9, but only had to pay $6. Similarly, B earns $2 of consumer surplus (CS), and C earns $1 of CS. Customer D, the so-called "marginal" consumer, is willing to pay $6 for a unit, but since the market price is $6, D gets no consumer surplus.
    [Show full text]