Low Interest Rates and High Asset Prices: an Interpretation in Terms of Changing Popular Economic Models

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Low Interest Rates and High Asset Prices: an Interpretation in Terms of Changing Popular Economic Models 10922-08a_Shiller_REV.qxd 1/25/08 11:23 AM Page 111 ROBERT J. SHILLER Yale University Low Interest Rates and High Asset Prices: An Interpretation in Terms of Changing Popular Economic Models MANY HAVE NOTED THAT we appear to be living in an era of low long-term interest rates and high asset prices. Although long-term rates have been increasing in the last few years, rates so far in the twenty-first century are still commonly described as low, in both nominal and real terms, compared with historical averages or with a decade or two ago. Meanwhile stock prices, home prices, commercial real estate prices, land prices, and even oil and other commodity prices are said to be very high.1 The two phenomena appear to be connected: elementary finance theory states that if the long-term real interest rate is low, the rate of discount used to determine present values will also be low, and hence present values should be high. This pair of phe- nomena, connected through the present-value relation, is often described as one of the most powerful forces operating on the world economy today. In this paper I will critique this common view about interest rates and asset prices. I will question the accuracy and robustness of the “low long rates, high asset prices” description of the world. I will also evaluate a pop- ular interpretation of this situation, namely, that it is due to a worldwide regime of easy money. I will argue instead that changes in both long-term interest rates and asset prices seem to have been tied up with important changes in the public’s ways of thinking about the economy. Rational expec- tations theorists like to assume that everyone agrees on the model of the economy, which never changes, and that only some truly exogenous factor, The author is indebted to Tyler Ibbotson-Sindelar for research assistance. 1. See also Shiller (2007) on real estate prices, written concurrently with this paper. 111 10922-08a_Shiller_REV.qxd 1/25/08 11:23 AM Page 112 112 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:2007 like monetary policy or technological shocks, moves economic variables. Economists then have the convenience of analyzing the world from a stable framework that describes consistent thinking on the public’s part. But an odd contradiction here is rarely pointed out: the economists who propose these rational expectations models are themselves regularly changing their models of the economy. Is it reasonable to suppose that the public is stably and con- sistently behind the latest incarnation of the rational expectations model? I propose that the public itself, largely independently of economists, changes its thinking about the economy over time, and indeed that these changes in popular economic models have been dramatic. I further propose that these changes in popular thinking have driven both long-term rates and asset prices and should be central to our understanding of the large asset price movements we have seen.2 I will begin by presenting some stylized facts about the level of interest rates (both nominal and real) and the level of asset prices in the world. Next I will consider some aspects of the public’s understanding of the economy, including common understandings of liquidity, the significance of inflation, and real interest rates, and how these have impacted both asset prices and interest rates. This will lead me to conclude that the relation between asset prices and either nominal or real interest rates is very tenuous, and clouded from definitive econometric analysis by this continual change in difficult-to-observe popular models. Changes in Decade-Long Trends in Long-Term Interest Rates Figure 1 plots nominal long-term (roughly ten-year) interest rates on government bonds for four countries and the euro area since 1950.3 With the exception of India, an example of an emerging economy, rates in all of these countries have been on a massive downtrend since the early 1980s, and even in India rates have been falling since the mid-1990s. The low point for long-term rates over this period appears to have been around 2003, but, broadly speaking, the upward movement since then has been small. 2. The concept of a popular economic model is discussed in Shiller (1990). 3. The long-term government interest rate series used here is an update of the series I spliced together for my book Irrational Exuberance (Shiller, 2005), from Sydney Homer’s A History of Interest Rates (for 1871 to 1952) and the ten-year Treasury bond series from the Federal Reserve (from 1953 on). 10922-08a_Shiller_REV.qxd 1/25/08 12:46 PM Page 113 Robert J. Shiller 113 Figure 1. Nominal Long-Term Bond Yields in Selected Countries, 1950–2007a Percent a year 16 14 12 Euro area 10 8 United Kingdom 6 India 4 Japan 2 United States 1955 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 Source: Global Financial Data. a. Data are monthly and refer to yields on government securities of approximately ten years’ maturity. Certainly one can say that the world is still in a period of low long-term rates relative to much of the last half century.4 Economic theory has widely been interpreted as implying that the discount rate used to capitalize today’s dividends or today’s rents into today’s asset prices should be the real, not the nominal, interest rate, because dividends and rents can be broadly expected to grow at the rate of inflation. However, as Franco Modigliani and Richard Cohn argued nearly thirty years ago,5 it may be, because of a popular model related to money illusion, the nominal rate that is used in the market to convert today’s dividend into a price. The downtrend in nominal rates since the early 1980s is certainly tied up with a downtrend in inflation rates over much of the world since the 4. Long-term rates are not any lower now than they were in the 1950s, but the high rates of the middle part of the period are gone. In the United States, long-term rates are actually above their 1871–2007 historical average of 4.72 percent a year. The best one can say from this very long term perspective is that U.S. long-term rates are not especially high now. 5. Modigliani and Cohn (1979). The authors also stressed that reported corporate earn- ings need to be corrected for the inflation-induced depreciation of their nominal liabilities, and investors do not make these corrections properly. 10922-08a_Shiller_REV.qxd 1/25/08 11:23 AM Page 114 114 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:2007 Figure 2. Ex Post Real Long-Term Bond Yields in Selected Countries, 1950–2007a Percent a year 12 10 8 6 Euro area 4 India 2 0 Japan United –2 States –4 –6 United Kingdom 1955 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 Source: Author’s calculations using data from Global Financial Data. a. Data are monthly and refer to yields on government securities of approximately ten years’ maturity. early 1980s. Figure 2 shows real ex post long-term interest rates on bonds with a ten-year maturity in the same countries depicted in figure 1. The annual inflation rate that actually transpired over the subsequent ten years has been used to correct the nominal yield. (For dates since 1997, the entire ten-year subsequent inflation is not yet known, and so the missing future inflation rates have been replaced with the historical average for the last ten years.) Note that there has been a strong downtrend in ex post real interest rates over the period since the early 1980s as well. Indeed, this trend is nearly as striking as that for nominal rates. Ex post real long-term rates in some countries were remarkably close to zero in 2003. And just as with nominal rates, real rates have picked up since then.6 6. The ex post real annual yield on U.S. long-term government bonds has averaged 2.40 percent over 1871–1997, which is below their yield in 1997 (the last year this yield can be computed without making assumptions about the future). Even today, using the latest inflation rate as a forecast, U.S. real long-term interest rates are not obviously low compared with this long-run average. The best one can say for the popular view that long-term interest rates are low today is that they remain relatively low compared with twenty or thirty years ago. 10922-08a_Shiller_REV.qxd 1/25/08 11:23 AM Page 115 Robert J. Shiller 115 Figure 3. Yield on Ten-Year Inflation-Indexed Bonds in the United States, the United Kingdom, Australia, Chile, and France, 1985–2007a Percent a year 9 8 Chile 7 6 Australia 5 United States 4 3 United Kingdom 2 1 France 1985 1990 19952000 2005 Source: Global Financial Data. a. Data are monthly, beginning in January 1985 for the United Kingdom, July 1985 for Australia, April 1992 for Chile, January 1997 for the United States, and September 1997 for Sweden, and ending in July 2007 for all. However, ex post real interest rates may not correspond to ex ante, or expected, rates. It seems unlikely that investors expected the negative real long-term rates that, in the 1970s, afflicted every major country except stable- inflation Germany. It is equally unlikely that they expected the high real long-term rates of the 1980s. After the very high inflation of the 1970s and the beginning of the 1980s, inflation in the United States and elsewhere came crashing down.
Recommended publications
  • EC541: Monetary Theory & Policy
    EC541: Monetary Theory & Policy RGK Home Main Class preparation Lab sessions Teaching Assistant Paper topics News links Office hours and email Electronics policies Fall 2012 This class is designed so that it can be taken in two different ways by students in the masters programs. First, a student attending just the lectures can gain an overview of issues in monetary theory and policy. Second, a student attending both the lectures and the weekly lab sessions can obtain a more detailed understanding of how modern macroeconomic models are constructed and used. These lab sessions are optional, but most students find that the sessions substantially advance their understanding of the lecture material. Students are likely to find that there is a higher benefit from this class if they have previously taken MA macroeconomics (EC 502) or are taking it simultaneously. Students in their third semester of the MA program that have previously taken EC 502 optionally may take this class on a research basis (all such students must get written consent of the instructor prior to October 1). These students will attend all sessions of the class as well as taking examinations and quizzes. However, as discussed further below, their grade will be partly based on writing and presenting a research paper on a macroeconomic topic using the tools developed in their macro classes and in the lab sessions. The topics of these papers will be developed in consultation with the instructor. Research papers must be written in teams of two students. The two authors must jointly prepare the presentation of the paper.
    [Show full text]
  • NBER WORKII4G PAPER SERS Christopher A. Sims Forthcoming In
    NBER WORKII4G PAPER SERS TOWARD A MODERN MACROECONOMIC MODEL USABLE FOR POLICY ANALYSIS Eric M. L.eeper Christopher A. Sims Working Paper No. 4761 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 June1994 Forthcomingin Fischer, Stanley and Rotemberg, Julio J.. eds., NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1994. MIT Press, Cambridge. MA. This paper is part of NBER's research program in International Trade and Investment. Any opinions expressed are those of the authors and not those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER Working Paper #4761 June 1994 TOWARD A MODERN MACROECONOMIC MODEL USABLE FOR POLICY ANALYSIS ABS'rRAa This paper presents a macroeconomic model that is both a completely specified dynamic general equilibrium model and a pmbabilistic model for time series data. We view the model as a potential competitor to existingISLM-based modelsthat continue to be used for actual policy analysis. Our approach is also an alternative to recent efforts to calibrate real business cycle models. In contrast to these existing models, the one we present embodies all the following important characteristics: 1) It generates a complete multivariate stochastic process model for the data it aims to explain, and the full specification is used in the maximum likelihood estimation of the model; ii) It integrates modeling of nominal variables --moneystock, price level, wage level, and nominal interest rate --withmodeling real vthables iii) It contains a Keynesian investment function, breaking the tight relationship of the return on investment with the capital-output ratio; iv) It treats both monetary and fiscal policy explicitly; v) It is based on dynamic optimizing behavior of the private agents in the model.
    [Show full text]
  • On the Mechanics of Economic Development*
    Journal of Monetary Economics 22 (1988) 3-42. North-Holland ON THE MECHANICS OF ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT* Robert E. LUCAS, Jr. University of Chicago, Chicago, 1L 60637, USA Received August 1987, final version received February 1988 This paper considers the prospects for constructing a neoclassical theory of growth and interna­ tional trade that is consistent with some of the main features of economic development. Three models are considered and compared to evidence: a model emphasizing physical capital accumula­ tion and technological change, a model emphasizing human capital accumulation through school­ ing. and a model emphasizing specialized human capital accumulation through learning-by-doing. 1. Introduction By the problem of economic development I mean simply the problem of accounting for the observed pattern, across countries and across time, in levels and rates of growth of per capita income. This may seem too narrow a definition, and perhaps it is, but thinking about income patterns will neces­ sarily involve us in thinking about many other aspects of societies too. so I would suggest that we withhold judgment on the scope of this definition until we have a clearer idea of where it leads us. The main features of levels and rates of growth of national incomes are well enough known to all of us, but I want to begin with a few numbers, so as to set a quantitative tone and to keep us from getting mired in the wrong kind of details. Unless I say otherwise, all figures are from the World Bank's World Development Report of 1983. The diversity across countries in measured per capita income levels is literally too great to be believed.
    [Show full text]
  • Low Interest Rates and High Asset Prices: an Interpretation in Terms of Changing Popular Models
    LOW INTEREST RATES AND HIGH ASSET PRICES: AN INTERPRETATION IN TERMS OF CHANGING POPULAR MODELS By Robert J. Shiller October 2007 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 1632 COWLES FOUNDATION FOR RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS YALE UNIVERSITY Box 208281 New Haven, Connecticut 06520-8281 http://cowles.econ.yale.edu/ Low Interest Rates and High Asset Prices: An Interpretation in Terms of Changing Popular Economic Models By Robert J. Shiller October, 2007 Low Interest Rates and High Asset Prices: An Interpretation in Terms of Changing Popular Economic Models Abstract There has been a widespread perception in the past few years that long-term asset prices are generally high because monetary authorities have effectively kept long-term interest rates, which the market uses to discount cash flows, low. This perception is not accurate. Long-term interest rates have not been especially low. What has changed to produce high asset prices appears instead to be changes in popular economic models that people actually rely on when valuing assets. The public has mostly forgotten the concept of “real interest rate.” Money illusion appears to be an important factor to consider. Robert J. Shiller Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics 30 Hillhouse Avenue New Haven CT 06520-8281 [email protected] 2 Low Interest Rates and High Asset Prices: An Interpretation in Terms of Changing Popular Economic Models1 By Robert J. Shiller It is widely discussed that we appear to be living in an era of low long-term interest rates and high long-term asset prices. Although long rates have been increasing in the last few years, they are still commonly described as low in the 21st century, both in nominal and real terms, when compared with long historical averages, or compared with a decade or two ago.
    [Show full text]
  • Some Skeptical Observations on Real Business Cycle Theory (P
    Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Modern Business Cycle Analysis: A Guide to the Prescott-Summers Debate (p. 3) Rodolfo E. Manuelli Theory Ahead of Business Cycle Measurement (p. 9) Edward C. Prescott Some Skeptical Observations on Real Business Cycle Theory (p. 23) Lawrence H. Summers Response to a Skeptic (p. 28) Edward C. Prescott Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review Vol. 10, NO. 4 ISSN 0271-5287 This publication primarily presents economic research aimed at improving policymaking by the Federal Reserve System and other governmental authorities. Produced in the Research Department. Edited by Preston J. Miller and Kathleen S. Rolte. Graphic design by Phil Swenson and typesetting by Barb Cahlander and Terri Desormey, Graphic Services Department. Address questions to the Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank, Minneapolis, Minnesota 55480 (telephone 612-340-2341). Articles may be reprinted it the source is credited and the Research Department is provided with copies of reprints. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis or the Federal Reserve System. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review Fall 1986 Some Skeptical Observations on Real Business Cycle Theory* Lawrence H. Summers Professor of Economics Harvard University and Research Associate National Bureau of Economic Research The increasing ascendancy of real business cycle business cycle theory and to consider its prospects as a theories of various stripes, with their common view that foundation for macroeconomic analysis. Prescott's pa- the economy is best modeled as a floating Walrasian per is brilliant in highlighting the appeal of real business equilibrium, buffeted by productivity shocks, is indica- cycle theories and making clear the assumptions they tive of the depths of the divisions separating academic require.
    [Show full text]
  • Rethinking the Implications of Monetary Policy: How a Transactions Role for Money Transforms the Predictions of Our Leading Models* by JULIA K
    Rethinking the Implications of Monetary Policy: How a Transactions Role for Money Transforms the Predictions of Our Leading Models* BY JULIA K. THOMAS ver the past several decades, economists have everything from car and home sales to consumer spending over the Christmas O devoted ever-growing effort to developing holiday season. Whenever business economic models to help us understand conditions are widely perceived to be weak, most people welcome cuts in the how changes in interest rates brought federal funds rate. about by monetary policy actions affect the production Despite these observations, however, the means through which and provision of goods and services in the economy. changes in an interest rate affect Although New Keynesian models have broad appeal in business activity is, in fact, far from obvious. Over the past few decades, explaining how changes in the money stock can affect economists have devoted ever-growing business activity, these models generate results that are effort to developing formal economic models to help us understand precisely inconsistent with what we know about how interest rates how changes in interest rates brought move with policy-induced changes in the money stock. about by monetary policy actions affect the production and provision of goods In this article, Julia Thomas argues that by extending the and services throughout the economy. New Keynesian model to reintroduce money’s liquidity While there are several different types role, we can resolve some of the remaining divorce of models describing how monetary policy actions drive short-run changes between economic theory and the patterns observed in in total employment and GDP, a the workings of actual economies.
    [Show full text]
  • The New Neoclassical Synthesis and the Role of Monetary Policy
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1997, Volume 12 Volume Author/Editor: Ben S. Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg Volume Publisher: MIT Press Volume ISBN: 0-262-02435-7 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/bern97-1 Publication Date: January 1997 Chapter Title: The New Neoclassical Synthesis and the Role of Monetary Policy Chapter Author: Marvin Goodfriend, Robert King Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c11040 Chapter pages in book: (p. 231 - 296) Marvin Goodfriendand RobertG. King FEDERAL RESERVEBANK OF RICHMOND AND UNIVERSITY OF VIRGINIA; AND UNIVERSITY OF VIRGINIA, NBER, AND FEDERAL RESERVEBANK OF RICHMOND The New Neoclassical Synthesis and the Role of Monetary Policy 1. Introduction It is common for macroeconomics to be portrayed as a field in intellectual disarray, with major and persistent disagreements about methodology and substance between competing camps of researchers. One frequently discussed measure of disarray is the distance between the flexible price models of the new classical macroeconomics and real-business-cycle (RBC) analysis, in which monetary policy is essentially unimportant for real activity, and the sticky-price models of the New Keynesian econom- ics, in which monetary policy is viewed as central to the evolution of real activity. For policymakers and the economists that advise them, this perceived intellectual disarray makes it difficult to employ recent and ongoing developments in macroeconomics. The intellectual currents of the last ten years are, however, subject to a very different interpretation: macroeconomics is moving toward a New NeoclassicalSynthesis. In the 1960s, the original synthesis involved a com- mitment to three-sometimes conflicting-principles: a desire to pro- vide practical macroeconomic policy advice, a belief that short-run price stickiness was at the root of economic fluctuations, and a commitment to modeling macroeconomic behavior using the same optimization ap- proach commonly employed in microeconomics.
    [Show full text]
  • BU Econ News 2011#2.Indd
    Economics News NEWSLETTER OF THE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS SPRING 2011 A letter from the Chair Dear Students, Parents, Alumni, Colleagues and Friends, My second year as Department Chair has been exciting, marked by growth and change. In faculty recruiting, we hired two stellar teacher-scholars. Kehinde Ajayi specializes in economic development, focusing on education issues in Ghana. She’ll receive her PhD this spring from the University of California at Berkeley. Carola Frydman will join us from MIT’s Sloan School to teach courses in economic and fi nancial history, as well as the economics of organizations. A Harvard PhD, Frydman is recognized internationally for her path-breaking work on the economic history of executive pay. This year, more international recognition came to BU Economics, which boasts some of the most distinguished economics faculty in the world. Kevin Lang was appointed a Fellow of the Social of Labor Economics for his distinguished research in labor economics, our fi rst SOLE fellow. Robert King was elected a Fellow of the Econometric Society, one of the highest honors in the profession, joining seven other ES fellows on our faculty. This February marked the 100th anniversary volume of the American Economic Review, the fl agship journal of the American Economic Association, and one of the most infl uential in economics. As part of the celebration, the Association selected the twenty most infl uential papers in the fi rst century of the Review: included is one by BU’s John Harris. Short of a Nobel Prize, it does not get much better than this – congratulations John! Every year BU Economics sponsors workshops and visits by some of the world’s leading economists.
    [Show full text]
  • Tsinghua Workshop in Macroeconomics for Young Economists June 30, 2013 Conference Program (Conference Venue: Shunde 418, SEM)
    Tsinghua Workshop in Macroeconomics for Young Economists June 30, 2013 Conference Program (Conference Venue: Shunde 418, SEM) 9:00-9:15 Registration 9:15-10:00 Macroeconomic Effect of Credit and Labor Frictions Feng Dong (Washington University in St. Louis) 10:00-10:45 Financial Frictions and Agricultural Productivity Differences Junmin Liao (Washington University in Saint Louis) Wei Wang (Washington University in Saint Louis) 10:45-11:00 Coffee Break 11:00-11:45 Competitors, Complementors, and Parents: Explaining Regional Agglomeration in the U.S. Auto Industry Luis Cabral (New York University and CEPR) Zhu Wang (Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond) Daniel Yi Xu (Duke University and NBER) 11:45-12:30 Redefining Industrial Revolution: Song China and England Ronald Edwards (Tamkang University) 12:30-14:00 Lunch 14:00-14:45 Monetary Policy Shocks and Stock Returns: Identification through the Impossible Trinity Ali Ozdagli (Federal Reserve Bank of Boston) Yifan Yu (Federal Reserve Bank of Boston) 14:45-15:30 Asset Pricing and Monetary Policy Bingbing Dong (University of Virginia) 15:30-15:45 Coffee Break 15:45-16:30 An Equilibrium Analysis of the Rise in House Prices and Mortgage Debt Shaofeng Xu (Bank of Canada) 16:30-17:15 Housing and Liquidity Chao He (Hanqing Advanced Institute, Renmin University of China) Randall Wright (Wisconsin-Madison, FRB Minneapolis and NBER) Yu Zhu (University of Wisconsin-Madison) Tsinghua Workshop in Macroeconomics 2013 July 1-3, 2013 Preliminary Program (Conference Venue: Room 418, Shunde Building, SEM) Monday,
    [Show full text]
  • Inside-Outside Money Competition
    Inside-Outside Money Competition Ramon Marimon, Juan Pablo Nicolini and Pedro Teles Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago WP 2003-09 Inside-Outside Money Competition∗ a,b,c d e,c Ramon Marimon , Juan Pablo Nicolini and Pedro Teles † aUniversitat Pompeu Fabra. bCentre for Economic Policy Research. cNational Bureau of Economic Research. dUniversidad Torcuato Di Tella. eFederal Reserve Bank of Chicago. Revised, July, 2003 Abstract We study how competition from privately supplied currency substitutes affects monetary equilibria. Whenever currency is inefficiently provided, inside money competition plays a disciplinary role by providing an upper bound on equilibrium inflation rates. Furthermore, if “inside monies” can be produced at a sufficiently low cost, outside money is driven out of circu- lation. Whenever a ’benevolent’ government can commit to its fiscal policy, sequential monetary policy is efficient and inside money competition plays no role. ∗A previous version of this paper was circulated with the title: ”Electronic Money: Sustaining Low Inflation?”. We thank Isabel Correia, Giorgia Giovanetti, Robert King, Sérgio Rebelo, Neil Wallace and participants at seminars where this work was presented for helpful comments and suggestions. We are particularly grateful to an anonymous referee, for many useful comments and suggestions. Teles thanks hospitality at the European University Institute (European Forum), and the financial support of Praxis XXI. Marimon thanks the support of CREA (Generalitat de Catalunya). The opinions expressed herein do not necessarily represent those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal Reserve System. †Corresponding author: Pedro Teles, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 230 S. LaSalle St., Chicago, Il 60604, USA. Tel.: +1-312-3222947; fax.: +1-312-3222357; [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • Finance 30220 Macroeconomic Analysis Spring 2007
    Finance 30220 Macroeconomic Analysis Spring 2007 John Stiver 231 Mendoza College of Business Notre Dame, IN 46556 Phone: (574) 631-2803 Fax: (574) 631-5255 Email: [email protected] Web: www.nd.edu/~jstiver Office Hours: M, T, W, and TH: 2:00 – 4:00. Other times by appointment Teaching Assistants: Kim Lorenzen ([email protected]) Lizzie Reed ([email protected]) Objectives: • To analyze the key empirical properties of the US economy • To develop an analytical framework for analysis of the macroeconomy. Reading: • Abel, Andrew and Ben Bernanke, Macroeconomics 5th Ed, Addison, Wesley, 2001 • The Wall Street Journal • The Economist • Business Week Other Sources: • Blanchard, Olivier, Macroeconomics, Prentice Hall, 1997 • Hall, Robert and John Taylor, Macroeconomics 5th Ed., W.W Norton &Co.,1997 • Gordon, Robert, Macroeconomics 8th Ed., Addison-Wesley2000, 1997 • Landsburg, Steven and Lauren Feinstone, Macroeconomics, McGraw Hill, 1997 • Mankiw, N. Gregory, Macroeconomics 3rd Ed., Worth Publishers, 1997. Grading: There will be three non-cumulative exams given during the course as well as weekly quizzes (generally on Wednesdays). Quiz questions will be based on the problem sets posted on the class web site. Bonus points will be awarded for exceptional class participation. The final grade will be computed as follows: Highest two midterms = 200 Quizzes = 100 Total = 300 The median score (out of 300 points) will receive a ‘B’ for the course. The ranges for other grades will be at various intervals around the median based on the standard deviation of scores. For example, if the median score for the class is 250, a possible grade distribution could be as follows: 280 - 300: A 270 - 280: A- 260 - 270: B+ 250 - 260: B 240 - 250: B- 230 - 240: C+ 220 - 230: C 210 - 220: C- 200 - 210: D <200 : F Honor Code: This course, like all other courses at Notre Dame, is subject to the Academic Code of Honor.
    [Show full text]
  • Veronica Guerrieri October 2020
    Veronica Guerrieri October 2020 CONTACT INFORMATION University of Chicago Booth School of Business 5807 South Woodlawn Avenue Room 411 Chicago, IL 60637 [email protected] http://faculty.chicagobooth.edu/veronica.guerrieri/ STUDIES Ph.D., Economics, MIT, Cambridge Massachusetts, June 2006 Thesis title: ‘Essays on the Macroeconomics of Labor Markets’ Advisors: Daron Acemoglu and Ivan Werning M.A., Economics, Università Commerciale Luigi Bocconi, Milano, 2001 B.A., Economics, Università Commerciale Luigi Bocconi, Milano, 2000 ACADEMIC POSITIONS Jan 2014 – present Ronald E. Tarrson Professor of Economics, University of Chicago, Booth Jul 2019 – present Willard Graham Faculty Scholar Jul 2012 – Jan 2014 Professor of Economics, University of Chicago, Booth Jul 2010 – Jul 2012 Associate Professor of Economics, University of Chicago, Booth Jul 2006 – Jul 2010 Assistant Professor of Economics, University of Chicago, Booth Spring 2010 Visiting Scholar, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Research Department Fall 2009 Visiting Assistant Professor, MIT, Department of Economics OTHER POSITIONS AND AFFILIATIONS 2019-present China Star Tour Selection Committee 2018-present Co-director of the Becker Friedman Institute Macro Initiative 1 Veronica Guerrieri October 2020 2018-present EFG Steering Committee at the NBER 2017-present Managing Editor of the Review of Economics Studies 2017-present Member of the Becker Friedman Institute Research Council 2014-present Member of the Board of Editors of the Journal of Economic Literature 2013-present Research
    [Show full text]