Income, Wealth, and Debt and the Great Recession October 2012 the Russell Sage Foundation and the Stanford Center on Poverty and Inequality

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Income, Wealth, and Debt and the Great Recession October 2012 the Russell Sage Foundation and the Stanford Center on Poverty and Inequality A GREAT RECESSION BRIEF Income, Wealth, and Debt and the Great Recession October 2012 The Russell Sage Foundation and The Stanford Center on Poverty and Inequality TIMOTHY SMEEDING, UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN, MADISON he Great Depression is often cast as the concentrated among young and minority KEY FINDINGS Tbeginning of the end for the late Gilded men with less than a high school degree, Age. Because it brought on the institutional which means that the bottom of the income • During the Great Recession, reforms of the New Deal, it led to dramatic distribution has not fared all that well. Wealth the wealthiest Americans lost the most wealth in absolute reductions in income inequality and set the inequality has also increased. The wealthy terms, whereas the middle stage for a long period of comparatively low did suffer large losses in wealth early on in classes lost the most in pro- inequality. The purpose of this recession the recession, as the financial crisis unrav- portional terms. This pattern brief is to ask whether the Great Recession, eled the stock market, but since then they arises mainly because middle like the Great Depression, is likewise shaping have recovered. Meanwhile, middle class class losses in the housing up as a compressive event that will reverse home owners lost much wealth with the market have been substan- tial. some of the run-up in inequality of the so- housing crisis, especially the emerging Black called New Gilded Age. This question can be and Latino middle class who bought first • Whereas the Great Depres- taken on by examining recent and long-term homes in the mid-2000s. sion ultimately brought trends in wealth inequality, income inequal- about substantial declines in ity, median incomes, and debt. We review these and other effects of the income inequality, the Great Recession has not yet had a recession in four sections covering wealth similarly compressive effect. The evidence presented below will suggest inequality, income inequality, median The recently released Sur- that the Great Recession has not typically incomes, and debt. The theme throughout: vey of Consumer Finances worked to reduce inequality. The labor mar- The Great Recession has been a “business shows, for example, that ket has been slow to recover, with job losses as usual” recession in which those at the the middle classes suffered steeper income losses than bottom have fared espe- the top of the distribution. cially poorly while those at FIGURE 1. Changes in Wealth (in 2009 Dollars) at Various Percentiles the top have, after heavy of the Wealth Distribution, 1962–2009 • Median household income initial wealth losses, recov- has declined from the begin- ered rather quickly. ning of the Great Recession Recession years through to 2011. 10 9 Wealth Inequality 8 It is useful to begin by 7 considering changes in 6 the distribution of wealth 5 (where wealth is under- stood as the value of all $ IN MILLIONS 4 3 assets less the value of all 2 outstanding debt). Figure 1 1 shows average wealth 0 at the 50th, 90th, and 99th 1962 1983 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2009 percentiles of the wealth YEAR distribution between 1962 50th percentile 90th percentile 99th percentile and 2009. From 1962 to Source: Kennickel, Arthur B. (2011). 2007, wealth in the middle RECESSION TRENDS • The Russell Sage Foundation and The Stanford Center on Poverty and Inequality 2 Income, Wealth, and Debt and the Great Recession of the distribution grew by 171% (from $46,000 to $125,000). Income Inequality But this growth was dwarfed by accumulation at the top. Is there any evidence of compression in the income distribu- Wealth at the 90th percentile grew by 242% (from $276,000 tion? Figure 2 shows income shares of various quintiles in the to $945,000), while wealth at the 99th percentile grew by a U.S. from 1967 to 2009 using household-size adjusted data staggering 452% (from $1,634,000 to $9,016,000). from the Census Bureau. It’s anchored at 100 percent in 1967 to highlight changes in income shares over time. What has happened since the recession? From 2007 to 2009, the wealthiest Americans have lost the most in abso- We find that the bottom quintile’s share of income was 5.2 lute terms (approximately $1.74 million at the 99th percentile), percent in 1967, but it fell to 3.6 percent by 2008 and then to whereas the middle class has lost the most in proportional an all-time low of 3.4 percent in 2009 (a drop from start to fin- terms. Those at the 50th percentile lost 23% of their wealth, ish of about 45 percent). The second quintile also lost share, as opposed to 13% and 20% at the 90th and 99th percen- falling 20 percent from 11.9 to 9.2 percent of total income in tiles, respectively. The most recent release of the Survey of 2009, again an all-time low. Even the middle quintile experi- Consumer Finances (which brings in 2010 data) bears out this enced a 10 percent drop in share over this recession, while general pattern: It shows that middle-class families lost the the fourth quintile showed little change, ranging between 22 most wealth in proportional terms while those at the top have, and 24 percent of total income. In contrast, the top quintile by 2010, recovered their wealth lost in the recession. This share rose from 42.5 to 49.4 percent of total income in 2009, pattern arises because middle class losses in the housing an all-time high (similar to that reached in 2006, before the market have been substantial and persisting. Indeed, home recession). Hence the top income share has risen through the values for the middle class (their biggest asset) dropped 30% recession, while the bottom has dropped precipitously, mainly nationwide from their 2006 peak, with little sign of recovery. due to job losses. In the two post-recession years (not shown in Figure 2), this general pattern of rising inequality contin- What about the very bottom of the distribution? The latest ues apace, with the lowest-quintile share falling to 3.2 in 2011 Survey of Consumer Finances shows that low-income fami- and the highest-quintile share increasing to 51.1 in 2011 (see lies, which tend to have very few assets, have also lost some DeNavas-Walt, Proctor, and Smith, 2012, Table A-2). of their wealth, albeit not as much in proportional terms as middle-class families. The latter result is the only compres- Other measures of income tend to tell a similar story. The sive one to be had. same trends emerge, for example, with data from the Con- gressional Budget Office, which include all types of cash and noncash income, employee benefits, realized capital gains, and the burden of all taxes, including tax rebates. The recently FIGURE 2. Percent Change in Shares of Adjusted Household Income by released Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF), which can be Quintile (Share of Income of Each Quintile Relative to Share used to compare trends from 2007 to 2010, again shows that in 1967) the middle classes suffered steeper losses than the top of the distribution, although the income going to the top decile in the Recession years 20 SCF did also decline. The main surprise from the SCF is that there are modest income gains between 2007 and 2010 at the 49.4% D 10 very bottom of the distribution, largely due to the expansion in enrollment and benefits of the food stamp (SNAP) program. OUSEHOL 0 H 22.9% OME C ENT N I C -10 The foregoing data do not include various forms of capital Y ER HARES OF P 15% S income that are not realized in a given year. An even more ONE -20 M thorough account of income from wealth—whether realized 9.2% or not—is useful for understanding the full distribution of -30 2009 QUINTILE economic resources, especially as far as the very top of the 3.4% -40 income distribution is concerned. To address this issue, Jeff Thompson and I recently developed a measure of “More Com- 1967 1969 1971 1973 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 YEAR plete Income” (MCI) using the Survey of Consumer Finances Highest quintile Third quintile Lowest quintile (SCF) from 1988-89 to 2006-7 and also using simulations to Fourth quintile Second quintile adjust for property and employment income losses in 2008 Source:DeNavas-Walt, Proctor, and Smith (2010), Table A-2, pages 40–43. and property income recovery in 2009. We first subtracted RECESSION TRENDS • The Russell Sage Foundation and The Stanford Center on Poverty and Inequality 3 Income, Wealth, and Debt and the Great Recession reported property income from the SCF, then systematically the income gains of recent decades have gone to the very top, added back the returns on financial wealth, retirement assets, we also want to know whether the middle classes have expe- housing, other investments (including real estate), and busi- rienced at least some income gains during this period. We turn ness income for owners and proprietors. Figure 3 shows the to this question next. trend in the Gini index of income inequality using the MCI measure, alongside a more traditional measure of income Figure 4 shows median family income from 1953 to 2009. also derived from the SCF. The figure suggests increasing Family income rose strongly and consistently up until about inequality in both measures, with inequality highest in 2006- 1973. It then stayed fairly flat until the mid-1980s, when it 07, but with 2008-09 higher than 2003-04 using either income began increasing again until the recession of the early 1990s.
Recommended publications
  • A Structural Model of the Unemployment Insurance Take-Up
    A Structural Model of the Unemployment Insurance Take-up Sylvie Blasco∗ Fran¸coisFontainey GAINS, University of Aarhus, BETA-CNRS, CREST and IZA LMDG and IZA. January 2012 - IN PROGRESSz Abstract A large fraction of the eligible workers do not claim the unemployment insurance when they are unemployed. This paper provides a structural framework to identify clearly, through the esti- mates, the economic mechanisms behind take-up. It incorporates take-up in a job search model and accounts for the determinants of claiming, especially the level of the unemployment benefits and the practical difficulties to make a claim. It provides a simple way to model selection into participation and sheds new light on the link between the job search and the claiming efforts. We estimate our model using a unique administrative dataset that matches a linked employer - employee data and the records of the national employment agency. Keywords: Unemployment Insurance Take-up, Job Search JEL Classification numbers: J64, J65, C41 ∗Address : Universit´e du Maine, Av. Olivier Messiaen, 72085 Le Mans Cedex 9, France ; Email: [email protected] yUniversity of Nancy 2, Email: [email protected]. zWe thank Jesper Bagger, Sebastian Buhai, Sam Kortum, David Margolis, Dale Mortensen, Fabien Postel-Vinay, Jean-Marc Robin, Chris Taber and participants at the Tinbergen Institute internal seminar, CREST-INSEE, Nancy and Royal Holloway seminars, the ESEM conference, the AFSE, IZA-Labor Market Policy Evalation, LMDG, T2M workshops for comments and discussions. This is a preliminary version of the paper, the readers are invited to check on the authors' websites for newer versions.
    [Show full text]
  • Reducing Income Inequality While Boosting Economic Growth: Can It Be Done?
    Economic Policy Reforms 2012 Going for Growth © OECD 2012 PART II Chapter 5 Reducing income inequality while boosting economic growth: Can it be done? This chapter identifies inequality patterns across OECD countries and provides new analysis of their policy and non-policy drivers. One key finding is that education and anti-discrimination policies, well-designed labour market institutions and large and/or progressive tax and transfer systems can all reduce income inequality. On this basis, the chapter identifies several policy reforms that could yield a double dividend in terms of boosting GDP per capita and reducing income inequality, and also flags other policy areas where reforms would entail a trade-off between both objectives. 181 II.5. REDUCING INCOME INEQUALITY WHILE BOOSTING ECONOMIC GROWTH: CAN IT BE DONE? Summary and conclusions In many OECD countries, income inequality has increased in past decades. In some countries, top earners have captured a large share of the overall income gains, while for others income has risen only a little. There is growing consensus that assessments of economic performance should not focus solely on overall income growth, but also take into account income distribution. Some see poverty as the relevant concern while others are concerned with income inequality more generally. A key question is whether the type of growth-enhancing policy reforms advocated for each OECD country and the BRIICS in Going for Growth might have positive or negative side effects on income inequality. More broadly, in pursuing growth and redistribution strategies simultaneously, policy makers need to be aware of possible complementarities or trade-offs between the two objectives.
    [Show full text]
  • A Glossary of Fiscal Terms & Acronyms
    AUGUST7,1998VOLUME13,NO .VII A Publication of the House Fiscal Analysis Department on Government Finance Issues A GLOSSARY OF FISCAL TERMS & ACRONYMS 1998 Revised Edition Abstract. This issue of Money Matters is a resource document containing terms and acronyms commonly used by and in legislative fiscal committees and in the discussion of state budget and tax issues. The first section contains terms and abbreviations used in all fiscal committees and divisions. The remaining sections contain terms for particular budget categories and accounts, organized according to fiscal subject areas. This edition has new sections containing economic development, family and early childhood, and housing terms and acronyms. The other sections are revised and updated to reflect changes in terminology, particularly the human services section. For further information, contact the Chief Fiscal Analyst or the fiscal analyst assigned to the respective House fiscal committee or division. A directory of House Fiscal Analysis Department personnel and their committee/division assignments for the 1998 legislative session appears on the next page. Originally issued January 1997 Revised August 1998 House Fiscal Analysis Department Staff Assignments — 1998 Session Committee/Division Fiscal Analyst Telephone Room Chief Fiscal Analyst Bill Marx 296-7176 373 Capital Investment John Walz 296-8236 376 EDIT— Economic Development Finance CJ Eisenbarth Hager 296-5813 428 EDIT— Housing Finance Cynthia Coronado 296-5384 361 Environment & Natural Resources Finance Jim Reinholdz 296-4119 370 Education — Higher Education Finance Doug Berg 296-5346 372 K-12 Education Finance Greg Crowe 296-7165 378 Family & Early Childhood Finance Cynthia Coronado 296-5384 361 Health & Human Services Finance Joe Flores 296-5483 385 Judiciary Finance Gary Karger 296-4181 383 State Government Finance Helen Roberts 296-4117 374 Transportation Finance John Walz 296-8236 376 Taxes — Income, sales, misc.
    [Show full text]
  • The Theory of Distribution Francis Y
    The Theory of Distribution Francis Y. Edgeworth Quarterly Journal of Economics, February, 1904. Distribution is the species of Exchange by which produce is divided between the parties who have contributed to its production.1 Exchange being divided according as both, or one only, or neither of the parties have competitors, Distribution is similarly divided. The case in which both parties have competitors will here be first and principally considered. The simplest type of this distributive exchange would be of a kind which is effected once for all, without reference to a series of future productions and exchanges. For example, to adapt an illustration used by Mr. Henry George,2 let it be supposed that on a particular occasion each out of a number of white men hires one or more black men to assist in catching seals, on the agreement that each white man shall give his black assistants a certain proportion of the take, the terms having been settled in an open market in which any one white is free to bid against any other white and any one black against any other black. A conception more appropriate to existing industry is that each white agrees to pay in exchange for a certain amount of service a definite quantity of produce, not in general limited to the result of a particular operation. On a particular day less seal may be taken than the employer has agreed to give the employee for the day. In this case, even if payment is not made till the end of the day, the employer must pay for help on a particular day in part with seal caught on a previous day.
    [Show full text]
  • Key Areas of Economic Analysis of Projects: an Overview
    KEY AREAS OF EcoNOMIC ANALYSIS OF PROJECTS An Overview ECONOMIC ANALYSIS AND OPERATIONS SUPPORT DIVISION (EREA) ECONOMICS AND RESEARCH DEPARTMENT (ERD) June 2004 CONTENTS INTRODUCTION PART I: SCOPE OF PROJECT ECONOMIC ANALYSIS 2 PART II: THE 10 AREAS OF ANALYSIS 10 1. Assess Macroeconomic Context 10 2. Assess Sector Context 11 3. Assess Demand 12 4. Identify Economic Rationale 13 5. Identify Project Alternatives 13 6. Identify and Compare Benefits and Costs 14 7. Assess Financial and Institutional Sustainability 15 8. Undertake Distribution Analysis 16 9. Undertake Sensitivity and Risk Analyses 16 10. Establish a Project Performance Monitoring System (PPMS) 17 PART Ill: AREAS OF ANALYSIS IN ADB's PROJECT PROCESSING CYCLE 18 6. Identification of Costs and Benefits 7. Fiscal/Financial Sustainability 8. Distribution Analysis 9. Sensitivity and Risk Analyses 10. Project Performance Monitoring System INTRODUCTION conomic analysis of projects helps identify and Eselect public investments that will sustainably improve the welfare of beneficiaries and a country as a whole. This 2"d edition pamphlet1 outlines key areas of economic analysis of projects. It stresses that analysis begins during country strategy studies and programming, when projects are identified, and continues iteratively throughout the project cycle. Economic analysis is coordinated with institutional, financial, environmental, social, and poverty analyses, forming an integral part of investment appraisal. Part I of the pamphlet summarizes the principles and key areas of analysis needed to appraise the economic feasibility of every project. The detailed assessment methods are outlined in ADB's Guidelines for the Economic Analysis of Projects (1997). Part II summarizes the main issues to be addressed in each of the 10 key areas of analysis (AAs).
    [Show full text]
  • The Spectre of Monetarism
    The Spectre of Monetarism Speech given by Mark Carney Governor of the Bank of England Roscoe Lecture Liverpool John Moores University 5 December 2016 I am grateful to Ben Nelson and Iain de Weymarn for their assistance in preparing these remarks, and to Phil Bunn, Daniel Durling, Alastair Firrell, Jennifer Nemeth, Alice Owen, James Oxley, Claire Chambers, Alice Pugh, Paul Robinson, Carlos Van Hombeeck, and Chris Yeates for background analysis and research. 1 All speeches are available online at www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Pages/speeches/default.aspx Real incomes falling for a decade. The legacy of a searing financial crisis weighing on confidence and growth. The very nature of work disrupted by a technological revolution. This was the middle of the 19th century. Liverpool was in the midst of a golden age; its Custom House was the national Exchequer’s biggest source of revenue. And Karl Marx was scribbling in the British Library, warning of a spectre haunting Europe, the spectre of communism. We meet today during the first lost decade since the 1860s. In the wake of a global financial crisis. And in the midst of a technological revolution that is once again changing the nature of work. Substitute Northern Rock for Overend Gurney; Uber and machine learning for the Spinning Jenny and the steam engine; and Twitter for the telegraph; and you have dynamics that echo those of 150 years ago. Then the villains were the capitalists. Should they today be the central bankers? Are their flights of fancy promoting stagnation and inequality? Does the spectre of monetarism haunt our economies?i These are serious charges, based on real anxieties.
    [Show full text]
  • Artificial Intelligence and Its Implications for Income Distribution
    Artificial Intelligence and Its Implications ... The Economics of Artifi cial Intelligence National Bureau of Economic Research Conference Report The Economics of Artifi cial Intelligence: An Agenda Edited by Ajay Agrawal, Joshua Gans, and Avi Goldfarb The University of Chicago Press Chicago and London The University of Chicago Press, Chicago 60637 The University of Chicago Press, Ltd., London © 2019 by the National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. All rights reserved. No part of this book may be used or reproduced in any manner whatsoever without written permission, except in the case of brief quotations in critical articles and reviews. For more information, contact the University of Chicago Press, 1427 E. 60th St., Chicago, IL 60637. Published 2019 Printed in the United States of America 28 27 26 25 24 23 22 21 20 19 1 2 3 4 5 ISBN-13: 978-0-226-61333-8 (cloth) ISBN-13: 978-0-226-61347-5 (e-book) DOI: https:// doi .org / 10 .7208 / chicago / 9780226613475 .001 .0001 Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Names: Agrawal, Ajay, editor. | Gans, Joshua, 1968– editor. | Goldfarb, Avi, editor. Title: The economics of artifi cial intelligence : an agenda / Ajay Agrawal, Joshua Gans, and Avi Goldfarb, editors. Other titles: National Bureau of Economic Research conference report. Description: Chicago ; London : The University of Chicago Press, 2019. | Series: National Bureau of Economic Research conference report | Includes bibliographical references and index. Identifi ers: LCCN 2018037552 | ISBN 9780226613338 (cloth : alk. paper) | ISBN 9780226613475 (ebook) Subjects: LCSH: Artifi cial intelligence—Economic aspects. Classifi cation: LCC TA347.A78 E365 2019 | DDC 338.4/ 70063—dc23 LC record available at https:// lccn .loc .gov / 2018037552 ♾ This paper meets the requirements of ANSI/ NISO Z39.48-1992 (Permanence of Paper).
    [Show full text]
  • Distributional National Accounts: Methods and Estimates for the United States∗
    THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Vol. 133 May 2018 Issue 2 DISTRIBUTIONAL NATIONAL ACCOUNTS: METHODS AND ESTIMATES FOR THE UNITED STATES∗ THOMAS PIKETTY EMMANUEL SAEZ GABRIEL ZUCMAN This article combines tax, survey, and national accounts data to estimate the distribution of national income in the United States since 1913. Our distributional national accounts capture 100% of national income, allowing us to compute growth rates for each quantile of the income distribution consistent with macroeconomic growth. We estimate the distribution of both pretax and posttax income, making it possible to provide a comprehensive view of how government redistribution affects inequality. Average pretax real national income per adult has increased 60% from 1980 to 2014, but we find that it has stagnated for the bottom 50% of the distribution at about $16,000 a year. The pretax income of the middle class—adults between the median and the 90th percentile—has grown 40% since 1980, faster than what tax and survey data suggest, due in particular to the rise of tax-exempt fringe benefits. Income has boomed at the top. The upsurge of top incomes was first a labor income phenomenon but has mostly been a capital income phenomenon ∗We thank the editors, Lawrence Katz and Andrei Shleifer; four anony- mous referees; Facundo Alvaredo, Tony Atkinson, Gerald Auten, Lucas Chancel, Patrick Driessen, Oded Galor, David Johnson, Arthur Kennickell, Nora Lustig, Jean-Laurent Rosenthal, John Sabelhaus, David Splinter, and Danny Yagan; and numerous seminar and conference participants for helpful discussions and com- ments. Antoine Arnoud, Kaveh Danesh, Sam Karlin, Juliana Londono-V˜ elez,´ and Carl McPherson provided outstanding research assistance.
    [Show full text]
  • Distributional National Accounts: a Macro-Micro Approach to Inequality in Germany
    Distributional National Accounts: A Macro-Micro Approach to Inequality in Germany Stefan Bach* Charlotte Bartels Theresa Neef March 1, 2021 Abstract This project aims to provide new income inequality series for reunified Germany combining tax data, survey data, and national accounts. Estimat- ing Distributional National Accounts (DINA), we capture 100% of national income and can compute the distribution of pretax and posttax incomes for the entire adult population. This allows us to answer the following questions: Who has benefited more from economic growth: employees or capital owners? The bottom 50%, the middle class or the top 10%, 1% and 0.1% of earners? Further, our paper is the first to apply the DINA methodology to the analysis of regional disparities. 30 years after the German reunification, substantial income differences remain between those living in East and West Germany. In the 1990s, West German investors bought real estate and factories in East Germany, following favourable tax incentives. We investigate to what extent capital income generated in East Germany flowing to West German capital owners can explain structural differences between the income distributions in East and West Germany. JEL Classification: E1, H2, H5, J3 Keywords: Income distribution; Capital accumulation; Wage distribution; Income composition; Top Income Groups *DIW Berlin. Contact: [email protected] DIW Berlin, IZA, UCFS. Contact: [email protected] Freie Universit¨atBerlin & World Inequality Lab. Contact: [email protected]. 1 Introduction The recent rise in income inequality in rich countries across the world has increas- ingly been the subject of academic and public debate. However, long-run inequality series, that put these developments into a wider perspective, are still scarce, and observed inequality trends are far from conclusive even for recent years.
    [Show full text]
  • The Distribution of Risk and the Great Recession: Old Problems, New Crises
    The Distribution of Risk and the Great Recession: Old Problems, New Crises Thomas Herndon∗ October 30, 2018 1 Intro This paper explores the central institutional and regulatory changes in U.S. mortgage nance that contributed to the historic loss of wealth during the Great Recession and aftermath. To do so, I will trace the developments which transformed mortgages from nancial instruments which shielded borrowers and savers from risk, to concentrating risk on those least able to bear it. In exploring these changes, we will nd that a consistent theme of the history of mortgage nance in the United States is that the risk-bearing capacity for private nancial intermediaries is both costly and limited. When this capacity becomes stressed due to rapid growth, competitive pressures, or other economic conditions, there is a persistent tendency to redistribute risk towards end users of the system borrowers and savers often with severe consequences. The central argument that I will develop in this paper is that stable mortgage nance on a widespread basis in the United States has always de- pended on direct public intervention, rather than occurring as the result of the unregulated market equilibirum. This stable form of lending was sup- ported by a particular regulatory structure dating to the New Deal era, and ∗Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, Loyola Marymount University. Email: [email protected]. 1 heavily relied on the active participation of public institutions in the market. Indeed, we will see through international and historical comparison that, ab- sent this regulatory structure, the unregulated equilibrium tends to towards risky mortgages in primary market, and a boom-bust cycle in the secondary market driven by agency problems.
    [Show full text]
  • Microeconomic Origins of Macroeconomic Tail Risks†
    American Economic Review 2017, 107(1): 54–108 https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20151086 Microeconomic Origins of Macroeconomic Tail Risks† By Daron Acemoglu, Asuman Ozdaglar, and Alireza Tahbaz-Salehi* Using a multisector general equilibrium model, we show that the interplay of idiosyncratic microeconomic shocks and sectoral heterogeneity results in systematic departures in the likelihood of large economic downturns relative to what is implied by the normal distribution. Such departures can emerge even though GDP fluctuations are approximately normally distributed away from the tails, highlighting the different nature of large economic downturns from regular business-cycle fluctuations. We further demonstrate the special role of input-output linkages in generating tail comovements, whereby large recessions involve not only significant GDP contractions, but also large simultaneous declines across a wide range of industries. JEL D57, E16, E23, E32 ( ) Most empirical studies in macroeconomics approximate the deviations of aggre- gate economic variables from their trends with a normal distribution. Besides analytical tractability, this approach has a natural justification: since most macro variables, such as GDP, are obtained from combining more disaggregated ones, it is reasonable to expect that a central limit theorem-type result should imply normality. As an implicit corollary to this argument, most of the literature treats the standard deviations of aggregate variables as sufficient statistics for measuring aggregate eco- nomic fluctuations.
    [Show full text]
  • Towards a System of Distributional National Accounts: Methods and Global Inequality Estimates from WID.World
    Towards a System of Distributional National Accounts: Methods and Global Inequality Estimates from WID.world Facundo Alvaredo*, Lucas Chancel**, Thomas Piketty***, Emmanuel Saez**** and Gabriel Zucman**** Abstract – This paper briefly presents the methodology of Distributional National Accounts (DINA), which distributes total national income and total wealth among all individual residents. With DINA, we can estimate inequality statistics and growth by income and wealth groups that are consistent with aggregate growth from National Accounts. This methodology has been recently applied to a number of countries, and the data produced are available from WID. world. The paper summarizes the initial empirical findings. We observe rising top income and wealth shares in nearly all countries in recent decades, but the magnitude of the increase varies substantially, thereby suggesting that different country‑specific institutions and policies matter. We combine countries’ statistics to estimate global inequality since 1980. Global inequality has increased since 1980 in spite of the catching up of large emerging countries like China and India. This has been driven by the income growth of top world earners. JEL Classification: D31, D33 Keywords: inequality, distribution, income, wealth, national accounts *PSE, IIEP‑UBA‑Conicet and INET at Oxford ([email protected]); **PSE and Iddri ([email protected]); ***PSE ([email protected]); **** UC Berkeley and NBER ([email protected]; [email protected]) The authors acknowledge funding from the Berkeley Center for Equitable Growth, the European Research Council (Grants 340831 and 856455), the Ford Foundation, the Sandler Foundation, the Sloan Foundation, and the Institute for New Economic Thinking. This article draws from recent work in Alvaredo et al.
    [Show full text]