Fostering Sustainable Economic Growth by Redefining Competitiveness and Industrial

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Fostering Sustainable Economic Growth by Redefining Competitiveness and Industrial Brief for GSDR 2015 Fostering sustainable economic growth by redefining competitiveness and industrial policy: Towards a systemic policy approach aligned with beyond-GDP goals Policy Brief prepared for the UN Global Sustainable Development Report 2015 Karl Aiginger – Michael Böheim* Abstract research sectors, (iii) by greater public awareness Industrial policy is back on the agenda and the and (iv) if consumer preferences will call for consensus is that it must be different 'this time' socio-ecological transition. from the past. Following Aiginger et al. (2013) we redefine industrial policy for industrialised Ten Theses for a “new” industrial policy countries as a strategy to promote 'high-road fostering sustainable growth 1 competitiveness', understood as the ability of an economy to achieve 'Beyond-GDP' Goals. 'High- (1) Industrial policy is back on the political road strategies' are based on advanced skills, agenda , driven by fear (globalisation, innovation, supporting institutions, ecological deindustrialisation) and hope (increasing ambition and an activating social policy. This 'new employment, sustainability). Bubbles in non- industrial policy' is systemic, working in manufacturing sectors (finance, construction, alignment with other policy strands and housing) have fuelled the financial crisis, and supporting social and environmental goals; it recovery is especially difficult in countries with a affects the structure of the economy as the small manufacturing sector, particularly when it whole not only the manufacturing sector. Short- is combined with a current account deficit. term actions, such as protecting employment in (2) Academia suggests that a new industrial unviable companies, low prices for fossil fuels, or policy must be different from the past. It should reducing wages in high-income economies are promote competition and be a discovery process counterproductive. To pursue an industrial policy in a cooperative climate between government that targets society's ultimate goals without and companies. It should align industrial policy public micromanagement will be challenging. It with the long-term interests of the society. It has could be achieved (i) by setting incentives, to be systemic and driven by a wider vision, particularly those impacting on technical progress instead of a standalone policy in conflict with (e.g. to make it less labour-saving and more other strands of government policy. It should energy-saving), (ii) by the use of the important stop extending the life of non-viable industries or role governments have in the education and artificially creating national champions requiring shelter from global competitors. ________________________ (3) A new industrial policy requires three new *The views and opinions expressed are the authors’ and do not yardsticks leading to a redefinition of industrial represent those of the Secretariat of the United Nations. Online policy. publication or dissemination does not imply endorsement by the United Nations. Authors’ can be reached at [email protected]. 1 The 10 theses are essentially based on the work by Aiginger (2014, 2013, 2012). • First, economic performance should be promotes the inclusion of social and ecological measured by a broader set of goals or a goals into economic models and thinking. more comprehensive indicator, instead of (5) The European Commission puts sustainability GDP (or GDP growth). This could be the 'at the centre stage' of industrial policy 'beyond-GDP goals' or some overall (unfortunately jointly with a rather conventional indicator of wellbeing like life satisfaction, defined competitiveness). Its Energy Roadmap happiness or life expectation. 2050 sets the goal to reduce greenhouse gas • Second, it should downgrade or abandon emissions by as much as '80 to 95%'. Radical the concept of price competitiveness, innovation projects – e.g. on ultra-low carbon which emphasises low costs (or in its steel - have been started. Recently, the European enlightened version low unit labour Commission set a goal to increase costs). Competitiveness should be defined manufacturing's share of nominal value-added as 'ability to achieve beyond-GDP goals'. GDP to 20% by 2020 (from 16% currently) which • Third, in trying to increase welfare is realistic only if quality of production is (beyond-GDP goals) countries may significantly upgraded and service components pursue a low-road strategy (emphasising are added. low costs, taxes, social and ecological (6) The renewed interest in industrial policy in standards) or a high-road strategy based the U.S. was motivated by the current account on research, skills, ecological ambition, an deficit. Reducing energy imports and becoming a empowering employment policy and net exporter for energy seem to be the excellent institutions. While Industrialised overarching policy priorities. But a large share of countries have to pursue a high-road the U.S. deficit - 180 billion euro - stems from an strategy, if they want to maintain their U.S. trade deficit in technology-driven industries frontier position, developing countries (where energy costs are about 1% of total costs). can start with a low-road strategy taking Reducing energy prices will not boost the U.S.'s into account their current status of share of manufacturing in global trade, as development, but also keeping in mind keeping the median wage constant for 50 years that a sustainable growth path should be did not help. the long-term goal. (7) The new intentions of industrial policy are • Industrial policy for high-income still on trial. Europe's fear of losing cost countries should be defined as the sum competitiveness relative to the U.S. is reducing of policy measures to achieve 'high-road its determination to put sustainability at the competitiveness'. By targeting high-road 'centre stage'. On the positive side the share of competitiveness and achieving society's renewable energy has increased strongly, with wider aims (including social and ecological some countries producing 50% of electric energy goals), industrial policy thus merges into a from 'green' sources. But new energy sources systemic socio-economic strategy. need complementary fossil fuels and investment (4) Policy documents developed by international in the power-grid infrastructure. Coal use in organisations have already defined new goals Europe increased after the collapse of the for industrial policy that partially follow the ideas European emissions trading scheme. Increasing of academia. All proposals directly or indirectly U.S. coal exports made coal cheaper in Europe focus on the structure of the economies as a than gas. At the same time China is undertaking a whole, not only on a narrowly defined deep transformation, trying to increase resource manufacturing sector since the borders between and energy efficiency – albeit from a very low manufacturing and services are ever more initial level. It has set goals to increase R&D blurred. The OECD's 'New Perspectives Program' investment to 2% of GDP (the current EU share) and makes advances in electric vehicles and world no1 in manufacturing. Some academic alternative energies. papers develop ideas how Industrial policy, which (8) Europe has in principle two choices to cope had previously been of mixed success, should be with high energy prices: to go for lower energy different this time (see Aghion et al, 2011, Rodrik , prices itself (by exploiting shale gas or by 2004, Aiginger , 2012): the "new industrial policy" reducing taxes on energy) or to further its lead in should be forward looking, pro competitive, energy efficiency plus to increase investment in supporting long term societal needs. Above all, it innovation and top education. Given a vision of a should not be an isolated policy strand in conflict system encompassing social and ecological goals, with regional policy or energy policy, but it the only viable choice is to pursue an industrial should be an integrated or systemic policy. policy to encourage energy efficiency, social and The European Commission developed just such a ecological innovation. new industrial policy in "Communications" first (9) Going for a socio-ecological transition can calling for an "integrated industrial policy with make Europe a 'role model' for other countries, sustainability at centre stage" ( European even if different preferences and circumstances Commission, 2010), and then for a "stronger will always call for some heterogeneity. Industrial European Industry" setting the target to raise the policy should foster the long-run transition, not manufacturing share in GDP from 16% to 20% decelerate structural change. This is a demanding (European Commission , 2012). challenge, given vested interests and the traditional role of governments to preserve the The interface with climate policy status quo and national champions. The systemic character of industrial policy can be (10) Refocusing on the economy's industrial illustrated by the interface between industrial base makes sense, particularly after the policy and energy policy. Placing sustainability on experience of bubbles in financial and real-estate the centre stage suggests that environmental markets. New industrial policy should support the standards are no longer seen as an obstacle for a transition of traditional narrowly defined competitive manufacturing sector, but as manufacturing to a sector producing greater potential drivers of growth. And the European consumer value, supporting the economy's long- targets are ambitious: shifting away
Recommended publications
  • Rebirth of Industrial Policy and an Agenda for the 21St Century
    QUERDENKERPLATTFORM: WIEN – EUROPA www.querdenkereuropa.at Mimeo 1/2019 – November 2019 REBIRTH OF INDUSTRIAL POLICY AND AN AGENDA FOR THE 21ST CENTURY KARL AIGINGER1 AND DANI RODRIK2 THE REBIRTH OF INDUSTRIAL POLICY: REASONS AND OPEN QUESTIONS After a period of decline in interest and premature predictions of demise, industrial policy is back on the scene. A variety of trends have contributed to the renewed interest. In the developing world there has been a pushback against the market-fundamentalist approach, typically associated with the Washington Consensus. Even when growth rates have been high, economies in Sub-Saharan Africa and Latin America have experienced unsatisfactory rates of productive transformation and shortfalls in generating quality jobs in manufacturing or modern services. This has created a demand for proactive government policies to diversify and upgrade economies beyond simply freeing up markets. In the advanced economies, generalized labor market malaise and the lingering effects of the financial crisis have produced similar effects. Low growth dynamics occurred especially in the euro zone, as countries with 1 Policy Crossover Center Vienna-Europe (www.querdenkereuropa.at), 1090 Vienna, Rotenhausgasse 6/9 (OeGFE), Vienna University of Economics and Business, Vienna, Austria, corresponding author, [email protected] 2 79 J.F. Kennedy Street, Harvard Kennedy School, Cambridge,MA 02138, USA [email protected] trade and budget double deficits with a common currency struggled to come out of the crisis The continuing decline in the employment shares of manufacturing in the US and Western European countries, and the increasing competitive threat posed by China on world markets have pushed in the same direction.3 Interest in industrial policy is being further stimulated by disruptive technological change – from automatization to digitalization, industry 4.0, and the internet of things.
    [Show full text]
  • The European Socio-Economic Model. Differences to the USA and Changes Over Time
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Aiginger, Karl; Guger, Alois Working Paper The European Socio-Economic Model. Differences to the USA and Changes over Time WIFO Working Papers, No. 266 Provided in Cooperation with: Austrian Institute of Economic Research (WIFO), Vienna Suggested Citation: Aiginger, Karl; Guger, Alois (2005) : The European Socio-Economic Model. Differences to the USA and Changes over Time, WIFO Working Papers, No. 266, Austrian Institute of Economic Research (WIFO), Vienna This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/128806 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu ÖSTERREICHISCHES INSTITUT FÜR WIRTSCHAFTSFORSCHUNG WORKING PAPERS The European Socio-Economic Model Differences to the USA and Changes over Time Karl Aiginger, Alois Guger 266/2005 The European Socio-Economic Model Differences to the USA and Changes over Time Karl Aiginger, Alois Guger WIFO Working Papers, No.
    [Show full text]
  • New Dynamics for Europe: Reaping the Benefits of Socio-Ecological Transition
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Aiginger, Karl; Schratzenstaller, Margit Research Report New Dynamics for Europe: Reaping the Benefits of Socio-ecological Transition. Synthesis Report Part I WWWforEurope Deliverable, No. 11 Provided in Cooperation with: WWWforEurope - WelfareWealthWork, Wien Suggested Citation: Aiginger, Karl; Schratzenstaller, Margit (2016) : New Dynamics for Europe: Reaping the Benefits of Socio-ecological Transition. Synthesis Report Part I, WWWforEurope Deliverable, No. 11, WWWforEurope, Vienna This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/169308 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen
    [Show full text]
  • Econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Aiginger, Karl Working Paper Catching-up in Europe: The Experiences of Portugal, Spain and Greece in the Nineties WIFO Working Papers, No. 212 Provided in Cooperation with: Austrian Institute of Economic Research (WIFO), Vienna Suggested Citation: Aiginger, Karl (2003) : Catching-up in Europe: The Experiences of Portugal, Spain and Greece in the Nineties, WIFO Working Papers, No. 212, Austrian Institute of Economic Research (WIFO), Vienna This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/128757 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu ÖSTERREICHISCHES INSTITUT FÜR WIRTSCHAFTSFORSCHUNG WORKING PAPERS Catching-up in Europe: The Experiences of Portugal, Spain and Greece in the Nineties Karl Aiginger 212/2003 Catching-up in Europe: The Experiences of Portugal, Spain and Greece in the Nineties Karl Aiginger WIFO Working Papers, No.
    [Show full text]
  • Rebirth of Industrial Policy and an Agenda for the 21St Century1
    REBIRTH OF INDUSTRIAL POLICY AND AN AGENDA FOR THE 21ST CENTURY1 Karl Aiginger 1 and Dani Rodrik2 1 Policy Crossover Center Vienna-Europe (www.querdenkereuropa.at), 1103 Vienna, Rotenhausgasse 6/9 (OeGFE), Vienna University of Economics and Business, Vienna, Austria, corresponding author 279 J.F. Kennedy Street, Harvard Kennedy School, Cambridge,MA 02138, USA [email protected], [email protected] THE REBIRTH OF INDUSTRIAL POLICY: REASONS AND OPEN QUESTIONS After a period of decline in interest and premature predictions of demise, industrial policy is back on the scene. A variety of trends have contributed to the renewed interest. In the developing world there has been a pushback against the market-fundamentalist approach, typically associated with the Washington Consensus. Even when growth rates have been high, economies in Sub-Saharan Africa and Latin America have experienced unsatisfactory rates of productive transformation and shortfalls in generating quality jobs in manufacturing or modern services. This has created a demand for proactive government policies to diversify and upgrade economies beyond simply freeing up markets. In the advanced economies, generalized labor market malaise and the lingering effects of the financial crisis have produced similar effects. Low growth dynamics occurred especially in the euro zone, as countries with trade and budget double deficits with a common currency struggled to come out of the crisis The continuing decline in the employment shares of manufacturing in the US and Western European countries, and the increasing competitive threat posed by China on world markets have pushed in the same direction.2 Interest in industrial policy is being further stimulated by disruptive technological change – from automatization to digitalization, industry 4.0, and the internet of things.
    [Show full text]
  • Harnessing Competitiveness for Social and Ecological Goals High Road Competitiveness Is Necessary and Feasible
    Karl Aiginger1 Harnessing competitiveness for social and ecological goals High road competitiveness is necessary and feasible In: Chiocchetti, Paolo and Allemand, Frédéric. Competitiveness and Solidarity in the European Union: Interdisciplinary Perspectives. London: Routledge. ISBN 978-1-138-54587-8 Forthcoming 2018. Abstract The term competitiveness has been “captured” for too long by lobbyists and politicians in pursuing a low wage strategy. The right-wing populists of today, like the new US administration, have extended this low road agenda by calling for lower environmental ambitions and for a lower social standard. The potential loss of jobs due to “unfair” low cost competitors, but also to inward migration, can mobilize popular support against globalization, even if the trade balance is positive, as it is in the EU. This article argues that countries focusing on innovation, skills and product quality are more successful in the long run. Especially for industrialized countries this is the only strategy to further increase welfare, since low cost countries will enter the market all the time. A high road strategy however needs an alternative framework of concepts and definitions: competitiveness is defined as the ability to deliver outcomes that include social and environmental goals; performance is measured by “Beyond GDP indicators”; and finally a systemic industrial policy has to support innovation and retrain the losers of structural change. In a “high road” approach, competiveness harnesses societal goals and undermines the roots of populism. 1 Karl Aiginger Vienna University of Economics and Business, Policy Crossover Center Vienna Europa (www.querdenkereuropa.at, [email protected]) The article heavily draws on the research in WWWforEurope, specifically Aiginger (2016), Aiginger– Bärenthaler-Sieber-Vogel (2013), Aiginger-Vogel (2015) and Aiginger-Firgo (2016).
    [Show full text]
  • A Systemic Industrial Policy to Pave a New Growth Path for Europe
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Aiginger, Karl Working Paper A Systemic Industrial Policy to Pave a New Growth Path for Europe WIFO Working Papers, No. 421 Provided in Cooperation with: Austrian Institute of Economic Research (WIFO), Vienna Suggested Citation: Aiginger, Karl (2012) : A Systemic Industrial Policy to Pave a New Growth Path for Europe, WIFO Working Papers, No. 421, Austrian Institute of Economic Research (WIFO), Vienna This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/129006 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu ÖSTERREICHISCHES INSTITUT FÜR WIRTSCHAFTSFORSCHUNG WORKING PAPERS A Systemic Industrial Policy to Pave a New Growth Path for Europe Karl Aiginger 421/2012 A Systemic Industrial Policy to Pave a New Growth Path for Europe Karl Aiginger WIFO Working Papers, No.
    [Show full text]
  • Industrial Policy for a Sustainable Growth Path
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Aiginger, Karl Working Paper Industrial Policy for a Sustainable Growth Path WIFO Working Papers, No. 469 Provided in Cooperation with: Austrian Institute of Economic Research (WIFO), Vienna Suggested Citation: Aiginger, Karl (2014) : Industrial Policy for a Sustainable Growth Path, WIFO Working Papers, No. 469, Austrian Institute of Economic Research (WIFO), Vienna This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/129024 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu ÖSTERREICHISCHES INSTITUT FÜR WIRTSCHAFTSFORSCHUNG WORKING PAPERS Industrial Policy for a Sustainable Growth Path Karl Aiginger 469/2014 Industrial Policy for a Sustainable Growth Path Karl Aiginger WIFO Working Papers, No. 469 June 2014 Abstract Industrial policy is back on the agenda and the consensus is that it must be different "this time" from the past.
    [Show full text]
  • Policy Strategies of Successful European Countries in the Nineties Karl Aiginger
    Copying the US or developing a New European Model – policy strategies of successful European countries in the nineties Karl Aiginger Paper presented to the UN-ECE Spring Seminar 2004: Competitiveness and economic growth in the ECE region Geneva, 23. 2. 2004 Karl Aiginger Austrian Institute of Economic Research WIFO, University of Linz and European Forum at Stanford University P.O. Box 91 A-1103 Vienna Austria [email protected] www.wifo.ac.at/Karl.Aiginger NEMTHREETIERS_Genf 13. 02. 04 Copying the US or developing a New European Model – policy strategies of successful European countries in ∗ the nineties Abstract: In general, the economic performance of European countries was disappointing in the nineties. However, country differences increased, and in some European countries economic growth matched US rates. This paper uses a set of performance indicators to carve out a group of successful European countries and to compare their economic strategies to those of the more poorly performing, big continental economies. The analysis shows that the successful countries implemented a policy mixture of cost cutting, improving institutions, and investing in future growth. We consider the first two strategy elements to be preconditions, while investment in growth drivers such as research, education and technology diffusion is the sufficient condition for long-run growth. The difference between top and low performers is larger with respect to the dynamics of future investment than in cost cutting. In research expenditures, the top countries surpassed the big continental European countries in 1987, and have been increasing their lead steadily since that time. They are welfare states with a comprehensive social net, which they have maintained in principle, while improving institutions and incentive structures.
    [Show full text]
  • Exploring Paths to Prosperity
    Programme FIFTH EU-SOUTHEAST EUROPE SUMMIT EXPLORING PATHS TO PROSPERITY OCTOBER 5th 2016 • VIENNA Venues: Bristol hotel Austrian Federal Economic Chamber (WKO) Supporting organisations: Tuesday, October 4th 2016 Venue: Bristol hotel (By invitation only) 18:00 Arrival of guests, registration and cocktails 19:00 Opening Dinner Welcome remarks by: Richard Schenz, vice president, Austrian Federal Economic Chamber Guest of honour and keynote speaker: Karlheinz Kopf, second president of the National Council, Austria Wednesday, October 5th 2016 Venue: Austrian Federal Economic Chamber (WKO) 08:00 Registration and refreshments 08:45 THE ECONOMIST’S FORECAST ON SOUTHEAST EUROPE • Which countries are the front-runners? • Which will still struggle? • Why have the Balkans lagged behind other transition economies? John Andrews, consultant editor, The Economist Joan Hoey, lead analyst and regional manager, Europe, The Economist Intelligence Unit Laza Kekic, independent consultant, former regional director for Europe & director for country forecasting services, The Economist Intelligence Unit 08:55 Discussion 09:00 Welcome remarks by: Richard Schenz, vice president, Austrian Federal Economic Chamber EUROPE: ON THE EDGE • Dealing with the migrant crisis • After Brexit: What lies in store for the EU? • EU and the Balkans: should further integration be expected? Meglena Kuneva, deputy prime minister for European policies coordination and institutional affairs and minister of education and science, Bulgaria Vladimir Kavaric, minister of economy, Government
    [Show full text]
  • Karl Aiginger Director Austrian Institute of Economic Research (WIFO) Karl Aiginger
    Karl Aiginger Director Austrian Institute of Economic Research (WIFO) Karl Aiginger How Globalization Works: Seventeen Theses on Its Impact on Trade, FDI, Income and Welfare 1 Definition and Dimensions ature, these regions are often called We tentatively define globalization as developed versus developing coun- the extension of the horizon of ac- tries, or North versus South. tion. Economic strategies, but also While globalization has been an social relations, knowledge, and cul- important topic for a long time, there ture cease to be limited by national are several new aspects, as stressed in borders; they become international Pichelmann and Vengelers (2005): and finally global. – the weak economy in the EU ver- Within the economic realm, glo- sus the buoyant growth of the balization implies a larger horizon for world economy1 trade, production and sourcing as – the emergence of new players, with well as for physical and financial in- especially large labor forces and vestment. The origin of goods con- relatively high technical capaci- sumed widens, also for intangible ties activities and services, specifically – information and communications information, technology, organiza- technologies, which allow knowl- tion, culture and finally for the socio- edge to be codified, boosting the economic model. The choice of the tradability of goods and services location for living and working – a and causing vertical fragmenta- topic covered by the term “mobility” tion; there is a specialization ac- within an integration area and by the cording
    [Show full text]
  • M4149-HUGGINS 9781783475001 T.Indd
    Contributors Karl Aiginger is Director of the Austrian Institute of Economic Research (WIFO) and the Policy Crossover Center, and Professor of Economics at the Vienna University of Economics and Business Administration, Austria. Paola Annoni is a Policy Analyst at the Economic Analysis Unit of the Directorate- General for Regional and Urban Policy, European Commission, Belgium. Mari José Aranguren is General Director of Orkestra ‒ Basque Institute of Competitiveness and Professor of Economics at Deusto Business School at the University of Deusto, Spain. David Audretsch is a Distinguished Professor holding the Ameritech Chair of Economic Development, Director of the Institute for Development Strategies, Director of School of Public and Environmental Affairs (SPEA) Overseas Education Programs at Indiana University Bloomington, USA. Pierre- Alexandre Balland is Assistant Professor in Economic Geography and Deputy Head of the URU programme in Evolutionary Economic Geography at Utrecht University, the Netherlands, and Research Associate at the Centre for Innovation, Research and Competence in the Learning Economy (CIRCLE) of Lund University, Sweden. Ron Boschma is Professor in Regional Economics at the Urban and Regional Research Centre Utrecht (URU), Utrecht University, the Netherlands, and Professor of Innovation Studies and Director of the Centre for Innovation, Research and Competence in the Learning Economy (CIRCLE) of Lund University, Sweden. Roberto Camagni is Full Professor of Urban Economics and of Regional Economics at the Politecnico di Milano, Italy. Roberto Cellini is a Full Professor of Economics at the University of Catania, Italy, and General Secretary of the Italian Economic Association, Italy. Joan Crespo is a Researcher in Economic Geography at the Urban and Regional Research Centre Utrecht (URU), Utrecht University, the Netherlands.
    [Show full text]