George Westinghouse and the Business of Innovation During the Age of Edison

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

George Westinghouse and the Business of Innovation During the Age of Edison Steven W. Usselman From Novelty to Utility: George Westinghouse and the Business of Innovation during the Age of Edison This article argues that Thomas Edison and George West- inghouse, despite some shared characteristics in their approach to technical problems and a common interest in electric power, pursued distinct markets for innovation. Edison sold novelties to upper-class urbanites, whereas Westinghouse provided equipment to railroads and other industrial customers. As a consequence, the two entrepre- neurs consistently exhibited different attitudes toward the process of innovation and different inclinations as business- men. Westinghouse, more than Edison, foreshadowed the coming of corporate research and development. ince the late 1970s, few areas of inquiry in business history Shave proved as fruitful as the study of corporate research and development. Moving beyond an older, simpler image of R&D as science applied by industry to produce novelty, historians now interpret R&D programs as components of corporate strategies designed to address specific business conditions.1 Corporations typically created laboratories in hopes of attaining order and con- trol over established lines of business.2 In joining programs of technological development to their production and marketing STEVEN W. USSELMAN is associate professor of history at the University of North Carolina at Charlotte. I wish to thank David Hounshell for his sustaining interest in this project and for his help in obtaining illustrations and Glenn Porter for his wise counsel after reading an earlier draft of this essay. 1 For a recent review of this literature, see John Kenly Smith, Jr., "The Scientific Tradition in American Industrial Research," Technology and Culture 31 (1990): 121-31. 2 For an excellent discussion of the motivations behind the founding of two impor- tant early laboratories, see Leonard S. Reich, The Making of American Industrial Research: Science and Business at GE and Bell, 1876-1926 (New York, 1985). Business History Review 66 (Summer 1992): 251-304. © 1992 by The President and Fellows of Harvard College. Steven W. Usselman I 252 organizations, these firms gave life to institutions that inexorably altered the ways in which new technology was generated and dif- fused. A new breed of managers, the corporate research directors, emerged as important figures in the realm of science and technol- ogy.3 Their prominence signaled clearly that bureaucracy and organization had come to exert powerful influences on the course of technological innovation. Studies of R&D have revealed many important and suggestive insights into the connections between economic institutions and technical change, but they have concentrated on the twentieth century, when corporate research programs acquired a distinct identity at several prominent firms.4 Historians have made far less headway in addressing similar issues during earlier stages of the corporate revolution. Our understanding of the process of techno- logical innovation during the last quarter of the nineteenth century remains highly fragmented. Case studies tell us how particular firms innovated technologically, but we lack synthetic interpreta- tions that draw comparisons and consider relations among firms.5 Perhaps the single greatest exception to this generalization is the work of Thomas P. Hughes. Throughout his distinguished career, Hughes has sought to bring a more structured analysis to the elusive subject of invention and innovation. In American Genesis, he summarized his thinking about inventors of the late nineteenth century and made them the foundation stone of what he called "a century of technological enthusiasm" that began in the United States in 1876. By placing his analysis of inventors such as Thomas Edison and Elmer Sperry in a larger chronological context that includes corporate research, Hughes invites comparison between the processes of technological change in the different 3 Ibid. For an insightful discussion of one prominent research director, Charles M. A. Stine, see David A. Hounshell and John Kenly Smith, Jr., Science and Corporate Strategy: Du Pont R&D, 1902-1980 (New York, 1988), 125-37. 4 Many of the recent treatments of corporate R&D begin with overviews of techni- cal activities at the firms prior to 1900, but these introductory sections seldom examine the connections between technical expertise and business strategy and organization with anything close to the detail and insight they achieve for the period after 1900. For a partial exception, see Reich, The Making of American Industrial Research, chaps. 2, 3, and 6. On research during the nineteenth century at Bell, also see Lillian Hodde- son, "The Emergence of Basic Research in the Bell Telephone System, 1875-1915," Technology and Culture 22 (1981): 512-44. 5 For an important exception that connects research to corporate structure across an entire industry during the nineteenth century, see Reese Jenkins, Images and Enter- prise: Technology and the American Photographic Industry, 1839-1925 (Baltimore, Md., 1975). George Westinghouse and the Business of Innovation I 253 institutional settings of late nineteenth and early twentieth century America. He writes of "independent inventors" who produced "radical" inventions in the nineteenth century, of "industrial sci- entists" who "were often constrained" and produced "conserva- tive" ones in the twentieth. The rise of technological systems drew a line between the independents and the industrial scientists. Independents invented systems; industrial scientists were left to work within them. "System-originating" inventions gave way to "system-improving" ones.6 In this conceptualization, Hughes naturally reserves an espe- cially prominent place for Thomas Edison, who provides the archetype for the independent, system-originating inventor. Hughes devotes virtually none of his account to George Westing- house, Edison's famous contemporary and notorious adversary in the field of electric light and power. This comparative neglect of Westinghouse is very much in keeping with the balance of atten- tion paid the two men by other historians in recent times. The collection and cataloging of the vast Edison archives has unleashed a flurry of outstanding new studies by specialists. At the same time, generalists seeking to incorporate invention and technology into the American experience have naturally turned first to the familiar figure of the Wizard of Menlo Park. This concentration on Edison at the expense of Westinghouse marks an intriguing depar- ture, however, from the view that prevailed during their own life- times and for many decades afterward. Even before the notorious "battle of the currents" linked their names in the public conscious- ness a century ago, Edison and Westinghouse often appeared as a matched set. And as recently as a generation ago, Harold Passer gave them twin billing in his outstanding study of invention and entrepreneurship. In Passer's assessment, Edison and Westing- house represented two peas in a pod, the two "pioneer innovators" of the electrical industry. "The similarity between the two," he concluded, "is striking."7 6 Thomas P. Hughes, American Genesis: A Century of Invention and Technological Enthusiasm (New York, 1989). For a comprehensive, integrated presentation of his ideas, see Thomas P. Hughes, Networks of Power: Electrification in Western Society, 1880-1930 (Baltimore, Md., 1983). On his thinking about invention, see also Thomas Parke Hughes, Elmer Sperry: Inventor and Engineer (Baltimore, Md., 1971) and Tho- mas P. Hughes, Thomas Edison: Professional Inventor (London, 1976). 7 Harold C. Passer, The Electrical Manufacturers, 1875-1900: A Study in Competi- tion, Technical Change, and Economic Growth (Cambridge, Mass., 1953), esp. chap. 11, quotation from 192. Steven W. Usselman I 254 This article attempts to bring Westinghouse back into the pic- ture and to assess his career in light of the transformation that Hughes has demarcated. Utilizing materials found in the archives of several railroads, it seeks to re-evaluate Westinghouse, and it draws on recent scholarship to offer fresh comparisons between him and Edison. This perspective suggests that the two men shared important traits as inventors but differed markedly in their approach to the business aspects of innovation. From his early years as a contract inventor for the telegraph industry through the obsessive pursuit of better sound reproduction that occupied him into old age, Edison devoted his talents to providing novelties for the urban upper class. His enterprises always made novelty their top priority, often at the expense of development and manufactur- ing. Frequently they gave way to more focused competitors. Westinghouse, by contrast, began his professional life marketing innovative products to the railroads, a small group of highly orga- nized institutions that placed a premium on system and order. He responded with a variety of business tactics, including clever use of patent rights and a keen appreciation for technical compromise and standardization, that enabled him to secure tight control over several products. Later, his endeavors in electric power and other fields exhibited similar characteristics. As a consequence, West- inghouse better exemplified the features of systematic, ordered technological development that would become hallmarks of corpo- rate R&D. More than Edison, he foreshadowed the future. Edison: Inventive Showman Contrary to what his involvement with electric power
Recommended publications
  • A Revisionist History of Regulatory Capture WILLIAM J
    This chapter will appear in: Preventing Regulatory Capture: Special Interest . Influence and How to Limit it. Edited by Daniel Carpenter and David Moss. Copyright © 2013 The Tobin Project. Reproduced with the permission of Cambridge University Press. Please note that the final chapter from the Cambridge University Press volume may differ slightly from this text. A Revisionist History of Regulatory Capture WILLIAM J. NOVAK A Revisionist History of Regulatory Capture WILLIAM J. NOVAK PROFESSOR, UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN SCHOOL OF LAW The idea of regulatory capture has controlled discussions of economic regulation and regulatory reform for more than two generations. Originating soon after World War II, the so-called “capture thesis” was an early harbinger of the more general critique of the American regulatory state that dominated the closing decades of the 20th century. The political ramifications of that broad critique of government continue to be felt today both in the resilient influence of neoliberal policies like deregulation and privatization as well as in the rise of more virulent and populist forms of anti-statism. Indeed, the capture thesis has so pervaded recent assessments of regulation that it has assumed something of the status of a ground norm – a taken-for-granted term of art and an all-purpose social-scientific explanation – that itself frequently escapes critical scrutiny or serious scholarly interrogation. This essay attempts to challenge this state of affairs by taking a critical look at the emergence of regulatory capture theory from the perspective of history. After introducing a brief account of the diverse intellectual roots of the capture idea, this essay makes three interpretive moves.
    [Show full text]
  • Thomas Edison Vs Nikola Tesla THOMAS EDISON VS NIKOLA TESLA
    M C SCIENTIFIC RIVALRIES PHERSON AND SCANDALS In the early 1880s, only a few wealthy people had electric lighting in their homes. Everyone else had to use more dangerous lighting, such as gas lamps. Eager companies wanted to be the first to supply electricity to more Americans. The early providers would set the standards—and reap great profits. Inventor THOMAS EDISON already had a leading role in the industry: he had in- vented the fi rst reliable electrical lightbulb. By 1882 his Edison Electric Light Company was distributing electricity using a system called direct current, or DC. But an inventor named NIKOLA TESLA challenged Edison. Tesla believed that an alternating cur- CURRENTS THE OF rent—or AC—system would be better. With an AC system, one power station could deliver electricity across many miles, compared to only about one mile for DC. Each inventor had his backers. Business tycoon George Westinghouse put his money behind Tesla and built AC power stations. Meanwhile, Edison and his DC backers said that AC could easily electrocute people. Edison believed this risk would sway public opinion toward DC power. The battle over which system would become standard became known as the War of the Currents. This book tells the story of that war and the ways in which both kinds of electric power changed the world. READ ABOUT ALL OF THE OF THE SCIENTIFIC RIVALRIES AND SCANDALS BATTLE OF THE DINOSAUR BONES: Othniel Charles Marsh vs Edward Drinker Cope DECODING OUR DNA: Craig Venter vs the Human Genome Project CURRENTS THE RACE TO DISCOVER THE
    [Show full text]
  • Transformers, the Unsung Technology
    NUMBERS DON’T LIE_BY VACLAV SMIL OPINION lem. It so puts to shame all mechanical attempts at regulation, it handles with such ease, certainty, and economy vast loads of energy that are instantly given to or taken from it. It is so reliable, strong, and certain. In this mingled steel and copper, extraordinary forces are so nicely balanced as to be almost unsuspected.” The biggest modern incarnations of this enduring design have made it pos- sible to deliver electricity across great distances. In 1890, de Ferranti stepped up from 2.5 kilovolts to 10 kV, enough to bridge 11 kilometers in London. Now ABB, based in Zurich, is working on stepping up to a record-breaking 1,100 kV, to span more than 3,000 km in China. The sheer number of transformers has risen above anything Stanley could have imagined, thanks to the explosion of por- table electronic devices that have to be charged. In 2016, the global output of smartphones alone was in excess of 1.8 bil- TRANSFORMERS, THE lion units, each one supported by a char- ger housing a tiny transformer. You don’t UNSUNG TECHNOLOGY have to take your mobile phone charger apart to see the heart of that small device: A complete iPhone charger teardown is I HAVE ALWAYS DISLIKED EXAGGERATED CLAIMS of imminent posted on the Net, with the transformer scientific and technical breakthroughs, like inexpensive fusion, cheap as its single largest component. supersonic travel, and the terraforming of other planets. But I am fond But many chargers contain even tinier of the simple devices that do so much of the fundamental work of mod- transformers.
    [Show full text]
  • Download File
    Downloaded from https://doi.org/10.1017/S1537781400001444 474 Journal of the Gilded Age and the Progressive Era / October 2009 Who Were the Gilders? And Other Seldom-Asked Questions about https://www.cambridge.org/core Business, Technology, and Political Economy in the United States, 1877- 1900 . By Richard K John, Columbia University Columbia University - Law Library Historians of the United States have for many decades termed the late nineteenth century the "Gilded Age." No consensus exists as to when this period began and ended, or how it might best be characterized. Most textbook authors place the origins of the Gilded Age around 1877 and its demise around 1900. Few would deny that this period witnessed a host of epochal , on innovations that included the rise of the modern industrial corporation, 03 Sep 2019 at 14:52:04 the building of large-scale technical systems, including the electric power grid, and the creation of governmental institutions that were conducive to rapid industrialization. Yet the significance of these innovations remained a matter of dispute. This essay contends that no synthetic account of the late nineteenth-century United States that aspires to be at all comprehensive , subject to the Cambridge Core terms of use, available at can ignore these innovations—innovations that have come to be known by various names such as the "managerial revolution," the "Second Industrial Revolution," and "modernization."1 It further contends that the reluctance of some of the most respected historians of business, technology, and political economy to embrace the Gilded Age construct raises questions about its utility as a periodizing device.2 'Robert J.
    [Show full text]
  • How the House of Morgan Cooperated to Develop the Large-Cap US Multinational Corporation, 1895-1913
    How the House of Morgan Cooperated to Develop the Large-Cap US Multinational Corporation, 1895-1913 The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Sawe, Joseph. 2015. How the House of Morgan Cooperated to Develop the Large-Cap US Multinational Corporation, 1895-1913. Master's thesis, Harvard Extension School. Citable link http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:24078367 Terms of Use This article was downloaded from Harvard University’s DASH repository, and is made available under the terms and conditions applicable to Other Posted Material, as set forth at http:// nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:dash.current.terms-of- use#LAA ! How the House of Morgan Cooperated to Develop the Large-Cap US Multinational Corporation, 1895-1913 Joseph Sawe A Thesis in the Field of International Relations for the Degree of Master of Liberal Arts in Extension Studies Harvard University November 2015 ! ! ! ! ! ! Abstract The following investigation is intended to determine how the large-cap US multinational corporation was further advanced during the pivotal years of 1895-1913 by a leading private unincorporated institution—House of Morgan. Historical review and assessment focused on the broader US society, government, monetary landscape, the House of Morgan, leading large cap US multinationals; looking at both the key organizations and underlying people in power. The report framework focuses upon the development of the US super structure within which all major companies work down to the way actual institutions organize economic assets in the form of a multinational corporation. Questions that have been considered include: how was business conducted globally with so little formal mechanisms in place, the importance of the various forms of capital for business, and the various roles politics played in business development.
    [Show full text]
  • Pedaling Energy Harvesting by Low Speed Gearless Generator 1Prof T
    International Journal for Research in Engineering Application & Management (IJREAM) ISSN : 2454-9150 Vol-03, Issue-11, Feb 2018 Pedaling Energy Harvesting by Low Speed Gearless Generator 1Prof T. T. Bellundagi, 2Prof A. S. Jaibhai, 3Prof A. E. Shivdas 1,2,3Assistant Professor, 1, 2, 3Electrical Dept TSSM’S BSCOER Narhe Pune, India. [email protected], [email protected], [email protected] Abstract - In rural areas of India today also we use bicycle as main medium of transportation. The pedaling energy generated is wasted. It can be used for a better purpose by converting pedaling power in to electrical energy. The same concept of the energy generated due to pedaling can be obtained by gym cycles in urban areas. The energy generated can be stored and can be used for running electrical appliances [1]. These types of systems are already available in markets but they are less efficient, needs more rpm to generate power. This paper presents design of gym cycle which produces same output with less rpm. In this paper low speed generator is designed and modified the position of generator which eliminates gears and belt arrangement. In Low speed generator high power magnets are implemented and number of poles are increased also gauge of winding used is 23.The main intention of this paper is to build straight forward human powered low speed generator. It is clean way of generating energy efficiently. Keywords – Pedaling Energy, Gearless Generator, harvesting, low speed generator, electrical appliances. I. INTRODUCTION II. HISTORY World is a storehouse of energy. We all know that energy can The generator evolved from work by Michael Faraday either be created or destroyed but can be transformed from one and Joseph Henry in the 1820s.
    [Show full text]
  • JP Morgan and the Money Trust
    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS ECONOMIC EDUCATION The Panic of 1907: J.P. Morgan and the Money Trust Lesson Author Mary Fuchs Standards and Benchmarks (see page 47) Lesson Description The Panic of 1907 was a financial crisis set off by a series of bad banking decisions and a frenzy of withdrawals caused by public distrust of the banking system. J.P. Morgan, along with other wealthy Wall Street bankers, loaned their own funds to save the coun- try from a severe financial crisis. But what happens when a single man, or small group of men, have the power to control the finances of a country? In this lesson, students will learn about the Panic of 1907 and the measures Morgan used to finance and save the major banks and trust companies. Students will also practice close reading to analyze texts from the Pujo hearings, newspapers, and reactionary articles to develop an evidence- based argument about whether or not a money trust—a Morgan-led cartel—existed. Grade Level 10-12 Concepts Bank run Bank panic Cartel Central bank Liquidity Money trust Monopoly Sherman Antitrust Act Trust ©2015, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Permission is granted to reprint or photocopy this lesson in its entirety for educational purposes, provided the user credits the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, www.stlouisfed.org/education. 1 Lesson Plan The Panic of 1907: J.P. Morgan and the Money Trust Time Required 100-120 minutes Compelling Question What did J.P. Morgan have to do with the founding of the Federal Reserve? Objectives Students will • define bank run, bank panic, monopoly, central bank, cartel, and liquidity; • explain the Panic of 1907 and the events leading up to the panic; • analyze the Sherman Antitrust Act; • explain how monopolies worked in the early 20th-century banking industry; • develop an evidence-based argument about whether or not a money trust—a Morgan-led cartel—existed • explain how J.P.
    [Show full text]
  • William Stanley Lighted a Town and Powered an Industry
    William Stanley Lighted a Town and Powered an Industry by Bernard A. Drew and Gerard Chapman preface by Samuel Sass Berkshire History Fall 1985 Vol. VI No. 1 Published by the Berkshire County Historical Society Pittsfield Massachusetts Preface: At a meeting of engineers in New York a half century ago, a paper was read which contained the following description of a historic event in the development of electrical technology: For the setting we have a small town among the snow-clad New England Hills. There a young man, in fragile health, is attacking single-handed the control of a mysterious form of energy, incalculable in its characteristics, and potentially so deadly that great experts among his contemporaries condemned attempts to use it. With rare courage he laid his plans, with little therapy or precedent to guide him; with persistent experimental skill he deduced the needed knowledge when mathematics failed; with resourcefulness that even lead him to local photographers to requisition their stock of tin-type plates (for the magnetic circuit of his transformer), successfully met the lack of suitable materials, and with intensive devotion and sustained effort, despite poor health, he brought his undertaking, in an almost unbelievably short time, to triumphant success. This triumphant success occurred in Great Barrington, Massachusetts, in 1886, and the young man in fragile health was William Stanley. A century ago he demonstrated the feasibility of transforming to a higher level the generated alternating current voltage, for transmission at a distance, and reducing it at the consumer end to a usable level. One hears or reads on occasion that Stanley “invented” the transformer.
    [Show full text]
  • Electrification and the Ideological Origins of Energy
    A Dissertation entitled “Keep Your Dirty Lights On:” Electrification and the Ideological Origins of Energy Exceptionalism in American Society by Daniel A. French Submitted to the Graduate Faculty as partial fulfillment of the requirements for the Doctor of Philosophy Degree in History _________________________________________ Dr. Diane F. Britton, Committee Chairperson _________________________________________ Dr. Peter Linebaugh, Committee Member _________________________________________ Dr. Daryl Moorhead, Committee Member _________________________________________ Dr. Kim E. Nielsen, Committee Member _________________________________________ Dr. Patricia Komuniecki Dean College of Graduate Studies The University of Toledo December 2014 Copyright 2014, Daniel A. French This document is copyrighted material. Under copyright law, no parts of this document may be reproduced without the express permission of the author. An Abstract of “Keep Your Dirty Lights On:” Electrification and the Ideological Origins of Energy Exceptionalism in American Society by Daniel A. French Submitted to the Graduate Faculty as partial fulfillment of the requirements for the Doctor of Philosophy Degree in History The University of Toledo December 2014 Electricity has been defined by American society as a modern and clean form of energy since it came into practical use at the end of the nineteenth century, yet no comprehensive study exists which examines the roots of these definitions. This dissertation considers the social meanings of electricity as an energy technology that became adopted between the mid- nineteenth and early decades of the twentieth centuries. Arguing that both technical and cultural factors played a role, this study shows how electricity became an abstracted form of energy in the minds of Americans. As technological advancements allowed for an increasing physical distance between power generation and power consumption, the commodity of electricity became consciously detached from the steam and coal that produced it.
    [Show full text]
  • The History of Transformers Began with That of Electricity Itself; As Voltages Became Ever Higher, Transformers Became Ever More Powerful
    HISTORY The history of transformers began with that of electricity itself; as voltages became ever higher, transformers became ever more powerful 126 TRANSFORMERS MAGAZINE | Volume 7, Issue 1 | 2020 François DEVAUX Though it was considered a DC device, the VSDUN LQGXFHU ˴ WKH IRUHUXQQHU RI WRGD\˹V WUDQVIRUPHU ˴ FRQWULEXWHG VLJQL̨FDQWO\ WR the development of transformer technology The transformation of transformers A short history of power transformers through the age 1. Introduction to the development of transformers as and Heinrich Ruhmkorff, among oth- a key segment of the electric power in- ers) took Faraday’s discovery further, Little did Michael Faraday know that dustry. inducing a high voltage using a spark his observation of electromagnetic in- inductor – the forerunner of today’s duction in 1831 would revolutionize A number of pioneers (Nicolas Cal- transformer. Though it was considered the application of electricity and lead len, Charles Page, Antoine Massen a DC device, the spark inducer contribut- )LJXUH$/67+20̵VWKUHHSKDVHWUDQVIRUPHUGHVWLQHGIRUFXVWRPHUQHUJLHOHFWULTXHGX5KLQDOVRPDQXIDFWXUHGLQ6DLQW2XHQ ABSTRACT major steps realized in the develop- them, played a pioneering role in that ment of transformers since the be- evolution. From Michael Faraday’s observation ginning. It also showcases how GE of electromagnetic induction in 1831 Renewable Energy’s Grid Solutions’ KEYWORDS through today’s largest standard, ancestor companies such as DELLE, converter and industrial power trans- British Electric, Thomson-Houston, history, power transformers, green trans- formers, this article summarizes the GEC Alsthom, AEG to name few of formers, HVDC converter transformers www.transformers-magazine.com 127 HISTORY 2. The transformer’s commercial era As production lines started up at the end of the 19th century, the transform- er became an essential device for the transmission and distribution of electric power.
    [Show full text]
  • What Can We Say About Trade and Growth When Trade Becames A
    27 S E R I E comercio internacional what can we say about trade and growth when trade becomes a complex system? Vivianne Ventura-Dias International Trade and Integration Division Santiago, Chile, July 2003 This document was prepared by Vivianne Ventura-Dias, Chief of the International Trade and Integration Division. The views expressed in this document, which has been reproduced without formal editing, are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Organization. United Nations Publications ISSN printed version: 1680-869X ISSN online version: 1680-872X ISBN: 92-1-121402-5 LC/L.1898-P Sales No.: E.03.II.G.57 Copyright © United Nations, July 2003. All rights reserved Printed in United Nations, Santiago, Chile Applications to the right to reproduce this work are welcomed and should be sent to the Secretary of the Publications Board, United Nations Headquarters, New York, N.Y. 10017 U.S.A. Member States and their governmental institutions may reproduce this work without prior authorization, but are requested to mention the source and inform the United Nations of such reproduction. CEPAL - SERIE comercio internacional N°27 Contents Abstract ........................................................................................ 5 I. Introduction................................................................................ 7 II. Non-market determinants of production disintegration and trade integration ............................................................. 11 Changes in the nature of international trade ..............................
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Theory and Business History
    Economic Theory and Business History Draft of August 2, 2006 Naomi R. Lamoreaux, UCLA Daniel M. G. Raff, The Wharton School Peter Temin, MIT Economic Theory and Business History Because work in business history has always consisted largely of studies of individual entrepreneurs, firms, and industries, scholars have continually had to struggle to prevent the field from disintegrating into antiquarianism. From the beginning economic theory has offered a solution—a way of distinguishing important trends from trivial changes and of building general understanding by comparing businesses and business people within and across industries and economies. However, practitioners have long resisted making serious use of economics in their work. Until recently they claimed that neoclassical theory’s restrictive assumptions about human behavior and the workings of firms rendered it useless for probing the motives of entrepreneurs or the activities of complex enterprises. This excuse disappeared in the 1970s and 1980s, when economists began to develop new theories based on much more realistic ideas about human behavior and organizations. Some business historians immediately recognized the value of the new theory for their work, but most remained indifferent, skeptical, or even hostile. The most common objection that business historians have posed to employing economic theory, even in its most recent forms, is that it founded on a method of analysis that is essentially static analysis and hence cannot account for the development of new business capabilities over time or, more generally, for innovation. This criticism is at best an exaggeration, but for the purposes of this essay we cheerfully acknowledge that there are important tasks for which economic theory, however construed, is not particularly well suited.
    [Show full text]