The "Fundamental Transformation" in Macroeconomics

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The TRANSACTIONALMICROSTRUCTURE AND MACROECONOMIC PERFORMANCEt The "Fundamental Transformation" in Macroeconomics By RICARDO J. CABALLERO AND MOHAMAD L. HAMMOUR* When factors enter into joint production, pensate the appropriatedfactors, providing a they often develop a degree of "specificity" highly inefficient macroeconomic "solution" with respect to each other. Their value in the to the unresolved microeconomic contracting context where they have come to produce ex- problem. Appropriabilityaffects major aspects ceeds their outside value. Committing a pro- of the macroeconomy. It results in misalloca- duction factor in such a relationship is a form tion, underutilization, and unemployment of of specific investment, whose sunk component the economy's productive factors; it hampers may have technological as well as institutional growth by depressing the incentives to replace origins. what is outdated and to utilize fully the econ- By itself, this "irreversibility" has impor- omy's resources; it disrupts macroeconomic tant and extensively studied implications for adjustment, by inducing a wedge between investment decisions. But, when combined timid creation and excessive destruction of the with contracting problems, it acquires an en- old system; and it exacerbates downturns by tirely new dimension. When two factors enter "elastifying" the cyclical response of inelastic into a joint-productionrelationship, specificity factors. creates ex post quasi-rents that need to be pro- tected through ex ante contracting. Unless L Microeconomics complete and enforceable contracts are avail- able, those quasi-rents may be appropriated The prototypical macroeconomic example by the other factor. This transformationfrom of specificity we choose to focus on is that of an ex ante competitive setting to an ex post the relationship between capital and labor. bilateral monopoly-what Oliver Williamson Other examples are also important and affect terms the "fundamental transformation"-is such diverse relations as that between an a central building block in the modem eco- entrepreneur and his external sources of nomic theory of institutions (e.g., Benjamin finance (e.g., Oliver Hart and John Moore, Klein et al., 1978; Williamson, 1979). 1994) or that between an upstream firm and The problem of appropriabilityspreads un- its downstream customers (as discussed ex- protected quasi-rents throughout the economy tensively in the microeconomic literature on and, in a partial-equilibrium setting, leads to vertical integration). underinvestment. In general equilibrium, the In the presence of specificity, the centralunit market system will adjust to help partly com- of analysis is the joint-productionrelation be- tween the factors. We embody this relation in the concept of a "productionunit" which, we assume, combines in fixed proportionsone unit of capital and one unit of labor. Because of t Discussants: Steven J. Davis, University of Chicago; specificity, productionunits cannotbe costlessly Mark Gertler, New York University; Abhijit Banerjee, reshuffled.It is thereforemeaningful to analyze Massachusetts Institute of Technology. * both the creation decision, by which factors Caballero: Departmentof Economics, Massachusetts choose to enter into a productionrelation, and Institute of Technology, 50 Memorial Drive, Cambridge, MA 02139, and NBER; Hammour: Capital Guidance, 32 the destructiondecision, by which factorswithin Avenue Hoche, 75008 Paris, France. We thank Olivier an existing productionunit choose whether to Blanchard and Steven Davis for helpful comments. continue producingjointly or not. 181 182 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 1996 We outline a minimalist model to help struc- with respect to the relationship, so we repre- ture our discussion. For a more complete treat- sents both its ex ante and its ex post opportu- ment, we refer the reader to Caballero and nity cost. Hammour (1996a, b, c). The units of analysis that arise from the notion of specificity provide The Fundamental Transformation.-If cap- the natural setting for a Schumpeterian view ital and labor were able to precommit to their of a macroeconomy with ongoing creation and ex post terms of trade, they would follow the destruction (see e.g., Caballero and Hammour, efficient entry rule. But when complete con- 1994). In this short paper, however, we reduce tracts are costly to write and enforce, agents' our treatmentof dynamics to a minimum. We ability to precommit is limited, and a William- model destruction and creation decisions dur- sonian "fundamental transformation" arises: ing a single period. We assume that factors can the ex ante competitive relationship between either be part of a production unit in the capital and labor turns into an ex post bilateral "joint-production" sector, or remain in their monopoly. Assuming that no precommitment "autarky" sectors. The period starts with pre- is possible, the specific quasi-rents from a pro- existing production units as well as a supply duction unit is the difference between the of uncommitted units of capital and labor. unit's revenue and its factors' ex post oppor- First, the factors in all preexiting units decide tunity costs: whether to produce jointly in the coming pe- riod or to separate and join the uncommitted (2) sY -We. factors; second, all uncommitted factors either form new production units or remain in au- Following the Nash bargaining solution for tarky; finally, production of the economy's sharing the unit's revenue, we assume that unique consumption good takes place in the each factor gets its ex post opportunity cost joint-production and autarky sectors. plus half of the unit's bargaining-surplus s. Using the superscript j to denote payments Creation. -We denote by y the production to factors in new joint-production units, we revenue of a newly created production unit, have and by wk and we the reward of capital and labor in autarky (all in terms of the consump- - tion good). In partial equilibrium, the efficient (3) Wk 2 decision is to create a production unit as long as (4) = We + W5 2 (1) Y?Wk + We. This rule would, in fact, be followed as long Underinvestment.-It is clear from equa- as factors of production can freely and cost- tions (3) and (4) that labor will willingly par- lessly move in and out of production units. ticipate in production as long as the surplus from joint production is nonnegative. Capital, Specificity.-Such freedom of movement the factor that is vulnerable to appropriation, rarely holds in reality. Let us take the extreme requires more. Its share of the ex post surplus irreversible-investmentview, where once cap- must be enough to justify forfeiting its ex ante ital is locked into a specific relationship, it is opportunity cost: lost if the relationship breaks up. Although it can also be due to such institutional factors as s - organized labor or legislated firing costs, we 2 Wk. view specificity here as a purely technological phenomenon. As a result, while the ex ante Replacing (2) into this expression yields the opportunity cost of capital is Wk,its ex post entry rule more explicitly: opportunitycost is zero. On the other extreme, we assume that labor develops no specificity (5) y 2 2Wk+ We VOL. 86 NO. 2 TRANSACTIONALMICROSTRUCTURE AND MACROECONOMICS 183 which states that a unit's revenue must not assume that preexisting production units are only cover its factors' opportunity costs, as in of infinitesimal mass. We assume that, in its the efficient condition (1), but must also gen- autarky sector, capital can be turned one-to- erate enough rents for capital to recover its ex one into the consumption good, so Wk = 1. ante opportunitycost after being appropriated. On the other hand, labor experiences decreas- This increased-revenue requirement generally ing returns in its autarky sector, resulting in gives rise to an underinvestment problem, a joint-production labor supply function: a result most clearly stated by Paul Grout (1984) in this context. (7) We = 2L"/77 r1> O Destruction. -The other decision of inter- where L measures joint-production employ- est to us is that of a preexisting productionunit ment. The supply of capital into joint produc- with production revenue x that must decide tion is therefore perfectly elastic, while the whether to remain in operation or shut down supply of labor is partly inelastic. Finally, we and free its nonspecific resources. The pri- restrict our analysis to values of y E (2, 3), vately efficient rule is to exit if the opportunity where both the efficient and inefficient econ- cost of the two factors of production cannot be omies exhibit positive but not full employment covered. Since capital is fully specific, its op- in joint production. portunity cost is zero. On the other hand, the opportunity cost of labor in a preexisting unit A. The Efficient Economy is pwle + (1 - p)we, where p is the proba- bility of finding employment in joint produc- If precommitment with complete and en- tion (see below). The exit rule is therefore forceable contracts is available, equilibrium will be efficient. Capital and labor will receive (6) x <pwJe +(1-p)We . their ex ante equilibrium opportunity cost in joint production. An interior solution in this In the context of bilateral bargaining, the case requires that entry condition ( 1) holds question of the private efficiency of separa- with equality. Denoting efficient levels by as- tions arises. When there is a "nontransferabil- terisks, and recalling that W* = 1, the oppor- ity" problem, due, for example, to asymmetnc tunity cost of labor is information (as in Robert Hall and Edward Lazear [1984], for example) or to a minimum- W*= y -1. wage constraint, the exit decision may be pri- vately inefficient (see e.g., Roger Myerson and Taking labor supply (7) into account, the ef- Mark Satterthwaite, 1983). We abstract away ficient joint-productionlevel of employment is from this possibility and assume for simplicity that exit decisions are privately efficient. As we will show, this is in sharp contrast with (8) L*= (Y2 1) their social inefficiency at the macroeconomic level.
Recommended publications
  • Understanding Development and Poverty Alleviation
    14 OCTOBER 2019 Scientific Background on the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2019 UNDERSTANDING DEVELOPMENT AND POVERTY ALLEVIATION The Committee for the Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel THE ROYAL SWEDISH ACADEMY OF SCIENCES, founded in 1739, is an independent organisation whose overall objective is to promote the sciences and strengthen their influence in society. The Academy takes special responsibility for the natural sciences and mathematics, but endeavours to promote the exchange of ideas between various disciplines. BOX 50005 (LILLA FRESCATIVÄGEN 4 A), SE-104 05 STOCKHOLM, SWEDEN TEL +46 8 673 95 00, [email protected] WWW.KVA.SE Scientific Background on the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2019 Understanding Development and Poverty Alleviation The Committee for the Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel October 14, 2019 Despite massive progress in the past few decades, global poverty — in all its different dimensions — remains a broad and entrenched problem. For example, today, more than 700 million people subsist on extremely low incomes. Every year, five million children under five die of diseases that often could have been prevented or treated by a handful of proven interventions. Today, a large majority of children in low- and middle-income countries attend primary school, but many of them leave school lacking proficiency in reading, writing and mathematics. How to effectively reduce global poverty remains one of humankind’s most pressing questions. It is also one of the biggest questions facing the discipline of economics since its very inception.
    [Show full text]
  • Rohini Pande
    ROHINI PANDE 27 Hillhouse Avenue 203.432.3637(w) PO Box 208269 [email protected] New Haven, CT 06520-8269 https://campuspress.yale.edu/rpande EDUCATION 1999 Ph.D., Economics, London School of Economics 1995 M.Sc. in Economics, London School of Economics (Distinction) 1994 MA in Philosophy, Politics and Economics, Oxford University 1992 BA (Hons.) in Economics, St. Stephens College, Delhi University PROFESSIONAL EXPERIENCE ACADEMIC POSITIONS 2019 – Henry J. Heinz II Professor of Economics, Yale University 2018 – 2019 Rafik Hariri Professor of International Political Economy, Harvard Kennedy School, Harvard University 2006 – 2017 Mohammed Kamal Professor of Public Policy, Harvard Kennedy School, Harvard University 2005 – 2006 Associate Professor of Economics, Yale University 2003 – 2005 Assistant Professor of Economics, Yale University 1999 – 2003 Assistant Professor of Economics, Columbia University VISITING POSITIONS April 2018 Ta-Chung Liu Distinguished Visitor at Becker Friedman Institute, UChicago Spring 2017 Visiting Professor of Economics, University of Pompeu Fabra and Stanford Fall 2010 Visiting Professor of Economics, London School of Economics Spring 2006 Visiting Associate Professor of Economics, University of California, Berkeley Fall 2005 Visiting Associate Professor of Economics, Columbia University 2002 – 2003 Visiting Assistant Professor of Economics, MIT CURRENT PROFESSIONAL ACTIVITIES AND SERVICES 2019 – Director, Economic Growth Center Yale University 2019 – Co-editor, American Economic Review: Insights 2014 – IZA
    [Show full text]
  • Esther Duflo
    Policies, Politics: Can Evidence Play a Role in the Fight against Poverty? Esther Duflo The Sixth Annual Richard H. Sabot Lecture A p r i l 2 0 1 1 The Center for Global Development The Richard H. Sabot Lecture Series The Richard H. Sabot Lecture is held annually to honor the life and work of Richard “Dick” Sabot, a respected professor, celebrated development economist, successful internet entrepreneur, and close friend of the Center for Global Development who died suddenly in July 2005. As a founding member of CGD’s board of directors, Dick’s enthusiasm and intellect encouraged our beginnings. His work as a scholar and as a development practitioner helped to shape the Center’s vision of independent research and new ideas in the service of better development policies and practices. Dick held a PhD in economics from Oxford University; he was Professor of Economics at Williams College and taught previously at Yale University, Oxford University, and Columbia University. His contributions to the fields of economics and international development were numerous, both in academia and during ten years at the World Bank. The Sabot Lecture Series hosts each year a scholar-practitioner who has made significant contributions to international development, combining, as did Dick, academic work with leadership in the policy community. We are grateful to the Sabot family and to CGD board member Bruns Grayson for the support to launch the Richard H. Sabot Lecture Series. Previous Lectures 2010 Kenneth Rogoff, “Austerity and the IMF.” 2009 Kemal Derviş, “Precautionary Resources and Long-Term Development Finance.” 2008 Lord Nicholas Stern, “Towards a Global Deal on Climate Change.” 2007 Ngozi Okonjo-Iweala, “Corruption: Myths and Reality in a Developing Country Context.” 2006 Lawrence H.
    [Show full text]
  • Interview with Esther Duflo
    The tapestry behind Esther Duflo, “Peoples of the World,” was handcrafted by Japanese artist Fumiko Nakayama. It was donated by MIT alumnus Mohammed Abdul Latif Jameel, a major J-PAL funder. Esther Duflo The problems of poverty in the developing world are extreme, extensive and seemingly immune to solution. Charitable handouts, massive foreign aid, large construction projects and countless other well- intentioned efforts have failed to alleviate poverty for many in Asia, Africa and Latin America. Market- oriented fixes—improved regulatory efficiency and lower trade barriers —also have had limited effect. What does work? MIT economist Esther Duflo has spent the past 20 years intensely pursuing answers to that question. With randomized control experiments—a technique commonly used to test pharmaceuticals— Duflo and her colleagues investigate potential solutions to a wide variety of health, education and agricultural problems, from sexually transmitted diseases to teacher absenteeism to insufficient fertilizer use. Her work often reveals weaknesses in popular fixes and conventional wisdom. Microlending, for example, hasn’t proven the miracle its advocates espouse, but it can be useful in the right setting. Women’s empower- ment, though essential, isn’t a magic bullet. At the same time, she’s discovered truths that hold great promise. A slight financial nudge dramatically increased fertilizer usage in a western Kenya trial. Monitoring teacher attendance, combined with additional pay for showing up, decreased teacher absenteeism by half in
    [Show full text]
  • Esther Duflo Wins Clark Medal
    Esther Duflo wins Clark medal http://web.mit.edu/newsoffice/2010/duflo-clark-0423.html?tmpl=compon... MIT’s influential poverty researcher heralded as best economist under age 40. Peter Dizikes, MIT News Office April 23, 2010 MIT economist Esther Duflo PhD ‘99, whose influential research has prompted new ways of fighting poverty around the globe, was named winner today of the John Bates Clark medal. Duflo is the second woman to receive the award, which ranks below only the Nobel Prize in prestige within the economics profession and is considered a reliable indicator of future Nobel consideration (about 40 percent of past recipients have won a Nobel). Duflo, a 37-year-old native of France, is the Abdul Esther Duflo, the Abdul Latif Jameel Professor of Poverty Alleviation Latif Jameel Professor of Poverty Alleviation and and Development Economics at MIT, was named the winner of the Development Economics at MIT and a director of 2010 John Bates Clark medal. MIT’s Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab Photo - Photo: L. Barry Hetherington (J-PAL). Her work uses randomized field experiments to identify highly specific programs that can alleviate poverty, ranging from low-cost medical treatments to innovative education programs. Duflo, who officially found out about the medal via a phone call earlier today, says she regards the medal as “one for the team,” meaning the many researchers who have contributed to the renewal of development economics. “This is a great honor,” Duflo told MIT News. “Not only for me, but my colleagues and MIT. Development economics has changed radically over the last 10 years, and this is recognition of the work many people are doing.” The American Economic Association, which gives the Clark medal to the top economist under age 40, said Duflo had distinguished herself through “definitive contributions” in the field of development economics.
    [Show full text]
  • Introduction Robert Gibbons and John Roberts
    Introduction Robert Gibbons and John Roberts Organizational economics involves the use of economic logic and methods to understand the existence, nature, design, and performance of organizations, especially managed ones. As this handbook documents, economists working on organizational issues have now generated a large volume of exciting research, both theoretical and empirical. However, organizational economics is not yet a fully recognized field in economics—for example, it has no JournalofEconomic Literature classification number, and few doctoral programs offer courses in it. The intent of this handbook is to make the existing research in organizational economics more accessible to economists and thereby to promote further research and teaching in the field. The Origins of Organizational Economics As Kenneth Arrow (1974: 33) put it, “organizations are a means of achieving the benefits of collective action in situations where the price system fails,” thus including not only business firms but also consortia, unions, legislatures, agencies, schools, churches, social movements, and beyond. All organizations, Arrow (1974: 26) argued, share “the need for collective action and the allocation of resources through nonmarket methods,” suggesting a range of possible structures and processes for decisionmaking in organizations, including dictatorship, coalitions, committees, and much more. Within Arrow’s broad view of the possible purposes and designs of organizations, many distinguished economists can be seen as having addressed organizational issues
    [Show full text]
  • Executive Committee Meeting of April 27, 2012
    Minutes of the Meeting of the Executive Committee in Chicago, IL, April 27, 2012 The first meeting of the 2012 Executive Committee was called to order at 10:01 AM on April 27, 2012 in the Writer Room of the Renaissance O’Hare Hotel, Chicago, IL. Members present were: Orley Ashenfelter, Alan Auerbach, Janet Currie, Pinelopi Goldberg, Claudia Goldin, Jonathan Gruber, Robert Hall, Anil Kashyap, Rosa Matzkin, Christina Paxson, Monika Piazzesi, Andrew Postlewaite, Valerie Ramey, Nancy Rose, John Siegfried, Christopher Sims, and Michael Woodford. Executive Committee members David Autor and Esther Duflo participated in parts of the meeting by phone. Caroline Hoxby participated in part of the meeting and Abhijit Banerjee and Vincent Crawford participated by phone as members of the Honors and Awards Committee. Angus Deaton participated in part of the meeting as chair of the Nominating Committee. Associate Secretary- Treasurer Peter Rousseau also attended. Sims welcomed the newly elected members of the 2012 Executive Committee: Claudia Goldin, President-elect, Christina Paxson and Nancy Rose, Vice-presidents; and Anil Kashyap and Rosa Matzkin, and recognized the Secretary at the last meeting of his 16 year tenure. The Minutes of the January 5, 2012 meeting of the Executive Committee were approved as written. Report of the Secretary (Siegfried). Siegfried reviewed the schedule for sites and dates of future meetings: San Diego, January 4-6, 2013 (Friday, Saturday, and Sunday); Philadelphia, January 3-5, 2014 (Friday, Saturday, and Sunday); Boston, January 3-5, 2015 (Saturday, Sunday, and Monday); San Francisco, January 3-5, 2016 (Sunday, Monday, and Tuesday); Chicago, January 6-8, 2017 (Friday, Saturday, and Sunday); Atlanta, January 5-7, 2018 (Friday, Saturday, and Sunday; Philadelphia, January 4-6, 2019 (Friday, Saturday, and Sunday); and San Diego, January 3-5, 2020 (Friday, Saturday, and Sunday).
    [Show full text]
  • ΒΙΒΛΙΟΓ ΡΑΦΙΑ Bibliography
    Τεύχος 53, Οκτώβριος-Δεκέμβριος 2019 | Issue 53, October-December 2019 ΒΙΒΛΙΟΓ ΡΑΦΙΑ Bibliography Βραβείο Νόμπελ στην Οικονομική Επιστήμη Nobel Prize in Economics Τα τεύχη δημοσιεύονται στον ιστοχώρο της All issues are published online at the Bank’s website Τράπεζας: address: https://www.bankofgreece.gr/trapeza/kepoe https://www.bankofgreece.gr/en/the- t/h-vivliothhkh-ths-tte/e-ekdoseis-kai- bank/culture/library/e-publications-and- anakoinwseis announcements Τράπεζα της Ελλάδος. Κέντρο Πολιτισμού, Bank of Greece. Centre for Culture, Research and Έρευνας και Τεκμηρίωσης, Τμήμα Documentation, Library Section Βιβλιοθήκης Ελ. Βενιζέλου 21, 102 50 Αθήνα, 21 El. Venizelos Ave., 102 50 Athens, [email protected] Τηλ. 210-3202446, [email protected], Tel. +30-210-3202446, 3202396, 3203129 3202396, 3203129 Βιβλιογραφία, τεύχος 53, Οκτ.-Δεκ. 2019, Bibliography, issue 53, Oct.-Dec. 2019, Nobel Prize Βραβείο Νόμπελ στην Οικονομική Επιστήμη in Economics Συντελεστές: Α. Ναδάλη, Ε. Σεμερτζάκη, Γ. Contributors: A. Nadali, E. Semertzaki, G. Tsouri Τσούρη Βιβλιογραφία, αρ.53 (Οκτ.-Δεκ. 2019), Βραβείο Nobel στην Οικονομική Επιστήμη 1 Bibliography, no. 53, (Oct.-Dec. 2019), Nobel Prize in Economics Πίνακας περιεχομένων Εισαγωγή / Introduction 6 2019: Abhijit Banerjee, Esther Duflo and Michael Kremer 7 Μονογραφίες / Monographs ................................................................................................... 7 Δοκίμια Εργασίας / Working papers ......................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Public Action for Public Goods
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PUBLIC ACTION FOR PUBLIC GOODS Abhijit Banerjee Lakshmi Iyer Rohini Somanathan Working Paper 12911 http://www.nber.org/papers/w12911 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 February 2007 The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. © 2007 by Abhijit Banerjee, Lakshmi Iyer, and Rohini Somanathan. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Public Action for Public Goods Abhijit Banerjee, Lakshmi Iyer, and Rohini Somanathan NBER Working Paper No. 12911 February 2007 JEL No. H41,O12 ABSTRACT This paper focuses on the relationship between public action and access to public goods. It begins by developing a simple model of collective action which is intended to capture the various mechanisms that are discussed in the theoretical literature on collective action. We argue that several of these intuitive theoretical arguments rely on special additional assumptions that are often not made clear. We then review the empirical work based on the predictions of these models of collective action. While the available evidence is generally consistent with these theories, there is a dearth of quality evidence. Moreover, a large part of the variation in access to public goods seems to have nothing to do with the "bottom-up" forces highlighted in these models and instead reflect more "top-down" interventions. We conclude with a discussion of some of the historical evidence on top-down interventions.
    [Show full text]
  • Breaking out of the Poverty Trap
    CHAPTER THREE Breaking Out of the Poverty Trap Lindsay Coates and Scott MacMillan Introduction In 2018, one of us visited a rural village in Bangladesh to speak to participants in a “graduation program,” a term used to describe programs designed to break the poverty trap with a boost of multiple, sequenced interventions. When we asked one woman what the program had changed for her, she brought out a piece of paper inviting her to a village event. Before she went through the program, her neighbors barely knew she existed, she said. Now she was a member of the com- munity, invited to people’s homes and weddings. One hears echoes of this senti- ment from participants in similar graduation programs worldwide. Such stories illustrate just one of the many cruel aspects of ultra- poverty: those afflicted by it tend to be invisible— to neighbors, distant policymakers, and nearly everyone in between. The ultra- poor need to stop being invisible to policymakers. We need to pay closer attention to the poorest and the unique set of challenges they face, for without a better understanding of the lived reality of ultra- poverty, we will fail to live up to the promise of “leaving no one behind.” Without programs tai- lored for people in these circumstances, the extreme poverty rate will become increasingly hard to budge. We are already starting to see this reflected in global poverty data. For decades, the global extreme poverty rate, defined as the portion of humanity living below the equivalent of $1.90 per day, fell rapidly, from 36 percent in 1990 to 10 percent in 2015.
    [Show full text]
  • Bounded Rationality As Deliberation Costs: Theory and Evidence from a Pricing Field Experiment in India
    Bounded Rationality as Deliberation Costs: Theory and Evidence from a Pricing Field Experiment in India by Dean E. Spears, Princeton University CEPS Working Paper No. 195 October 2009 Bounded Rationality as Deliberation Costs: Theory and Evidence from a Pricing Field Experiment in India Dean Spears∗ October 13, 2009 Abstract How might bounded rationality shape decisions to spend? A field experiment ver- ifies a theory of bounded rationality as deliberation costs that can explain findings from previous experiments on pricing in developing countries. The model predicts that (1) eliminating deliberation costs will increase purchasing at a higher price without impacting behavior at a lower price, (2) bounded rationality has certain greater effects on poorer people, and (3) deliberation costs can suppress screening by prices. Each prediction is confirmed by an experiment that sold soap in rural Indian villages. The experiment interacted assignment to different subsidized prices with a treatment that eliminated marginal deliberation costs. The results suggest implications of bounded rationality for theory and social policy. ∗[email protected]. Princeton University. first version: May 5th, 2009. I have many people to thank for much (though, of course, errors are my own). Priceton’s Research Program in Development Studies and Center for Health and Wellbeing partially funded the fieldwork; Tolani College of Arts and Sciences in Adipur provided support. I thank Abhijit Banerjee, Roland B´enabou, Jim Berry, Anne Case, Angus Deaton, Pascaline Dupas, Thomas Eisenbach, Rachel Glennerster, Tricia Gonwa, Faruk Gul, Karla Hoff, Michael Kremer, Stephen Morris, Sam Schulhofer-Wohl, Eldar Shafir, and Marc Shotland. Vijayendra Rao provided the data on Indian marriage.
    [Show full text]
  • Banerjee, Duflo, Kremer, and the Rise of Modern Development Economics*
    Banerjee, Duflo, Kremer, and the Rise of Modern Development Economics* Benjamin A. Olken MIT May 2020 Abstract In 2019, Abhijit Banerjee, Esther Duflo and Michael Kremer received the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in memory of Alfred Nobel. These three scholars were recognized “for their experimental approach to alleviating global poverty.” This paper reviews the contributions of these three scholars in the field of development economics, to put this contribution in perspective. I highlight how the experimental approach helped to break down the challenges of understanding economic development into a number of component pieces, and contrast this to understanding development using macroeconomic aggregates. I discuss pioneering contributions in understanding challenges of education, service delivery, and credit markets in developing countries, as well as how the experimental approach has spread to virtually all aspects of development economics. Introduction Development economics, broadly speaking, seeks to answer two questions. The first question development economics poses is: why are some countries poor and some countries rich, and relatedly, what can poor countries do to grow and become richer in the future? The second question of development economics is: how do the many and varied phenomena studied by economists differ systematically in environments characterized by low levels of development? * I thank the three Laureates -- Abhijit Banerjee, Esther Duflo, and Michael Kremer – for countless conversations over the many years, including comments on this article. Special thanks also to Rema Hanna and Seema Jayachandran for helpful comments. All errors are my own. Contact information: [email protected]. The field of development economics has changed dramatically over the past 25 years.
    [Show full text]