Online Auctions
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Terrence Hendershott, Ed., Handbooks in Information Systems, Vol. 1 Copyright r 2006 by Elsevier B.V. Chapter 12 Online Auctions Axel Ockenfels Department of Economics, University of Cologne, Albertus Magnus Platz, Cologne, Germany David H. Reiley Department of Economics, University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ, USA Abdolkarim Sadrieh Faculty of Economics and Management, University of Magdeburg, Magdeburg, Germany Abstract The economic literature on online auctions is rapidly growing because of the enormous amount of freely available field data, moreover the emergence of numerous innovative auction design features on auction platforms such as eBay have created excellent research opportunities. In this article, we survey the theoretical, empirical, and experimental research on bidder strategies (including the timing of bids and winner’s-curse effects) and seller strategies (including reserve-price policies and the use of buy-now options) in online auctions as well as some of the literature dealing with online-auction design (including stopping rule and multi-object pricing rules). 1 Why do information systems make auctions (even) more popular? Long before any electronic information systems were in place, people used auctions to trade all kinds of goods and services. In his comprehensive overview of the history of auctions, Cassady (1967) reports auctions of items of almost every size, from jewels and spices to ships and provinces. Auctions have also sold a wide range of services, including anything from a date with a bachelor (for charity fundraising) to the lifetime work of a slave. Despite being widespread, auctions have not been the most common way of 571 572 A. Ockenfels et al. trading because the costs of conducting and participating in an auction. Have been quite high: the buyers would gather in the same place, at the same time, and the seller would pay for the use of an auctioneer’s services. For many purposes, fixed prices are quite convenient: buyers know they can buy at the posted price, and they don’t have to decide how much to bid. The auctions depends on a trade off between the advantage of price discovery (i.e., discovering the market-clearing price level) and the disadvantage of having high transaction costs. Because of this, auctions are most valuable when the party running the auction is highly uncertain of the item’s market value and, thus, receives a considerable advantage from the price discovery afforded by the auction. With the emergence and spread of electronic information systems, both the advantages and disadvantages have changed radically. On the one hand, the transaction costs associated with conducting and participating in an auction have decreased so substantially that auctions seem worthwhile even when the expected advantage of detecting the true market value of the item is relatively low. On the other, the expected advantage of price discovery has increased sharply because many more potential auction participants can virtually meet in an online auction house than at any physical location. The effect is magnified by the fact that software agents in virtual auction houses enable participants to interact ‘‘on time’’ without having to be present in person. The time and space emancipation provided by electronic informa- tion systems has increased the expected number of potential participants at an auction, making it more likely for the auctioneer to meet participants with especially high valuations. Since transaction costs have decreased and potential gains of trade have increased, it comes as no surprise that the volume of online auction trades has exploded ever since the service was first offered. Meanwhile, there is no doubt that online auctions constitute a major market with growing signifi- cance for the global economy. Not only size matters. For in addition to the significance of trade volume, online auctions have also taken a central role in market research and in- novation. No other economic institution has induced as much innovation and created as many research opportunities as online auctions have. New features concerning the design of online auctions are proposed and dis- cussed almost on a daily basis. At the same time, the enormous amount of market data that is generated in online auctions and recorded electronically has enabled researchers to empirically address many issues that previously were not researchable. Finally, the open access to online auctions has also opened a door for field experimentation that enables the research of con- trolled variations in a running market. In this chapter, we provide an overview of some of the theoretical, em- pirical, and experimental research on online auctions. The literature in this field is expanding so quickly that comprehensive coverage is impossible. Nevertheless, we have tried to cover all major aspects of the research in the Ch. 12. Online Auctions 573 field with the one notable exception being the work on reputation in online auctions. An entire other chapter of this book deals extensively with the issue of online reputation. The rest of this chapter is organized as follows: in Section 2, some of the foundations of auction theory are presented for the simplest case of single- object auctions. The theoretical results are compared to experimental find- ings and related to empirical observations in online auctions. In Section 3, we discuss theoretical and empirical aspects of using public and secret re- serve prices in online auctions. Furthermore, we present the research on the relationship between alternative reserve price instruments, such as mini- mum bids and shill bids. In Section 4, we present the research on late and incremental bidding in online auctions. This research deals with the fact that in some online auctions many bids are submitted within the last few moments. An interesting aspect of this strand of research is that it is entirely motivated by phenomena that were first discovered in online auctions. In Section 5, we present the research on the buy-now option, which is wide- spread in online auctions, but rarely observed in classical auctions. The buy-now option creates a hybrid market situation that allows bidders to choose between normal bidding or accepting a posted sales price. The buy- now option is in effect an outside option for the buyers that is provided by the seller. In Section 6, we examine other types of buyer outside options, such as multiple parallel auctions and market posted-prices. In Section 7, we present the research on multi-object auctions that are both theoretically and empirically more difficult to deal with than the single-object auctions, and in Section 8, we conclude the chapter with some general remarks on the design of online auctions. 2 Single-object auctions: theory and experiments Auction theory has been remarkably influential on the design of elec- tronic market mechanisms. It has also motivated much of the empirical research on auction behavior that we are surveying in this chapter. This section, together with our discussion of multi-object auctions in Section 7, reviews some of the central theoretical and experimental results relevant to online auctions.1 2.1 Standard auction mechanisms and models An auction elicits information, in the form of bids, from potential buyers regarding their willingness to pay. The outcome—who wins and pays how 1For more comprehensive and mathematical treatments of auction theory see, e.g., Klemperer (1999), Krishna (2002), Milgrom (2004), and Menezes and Monteiro (2005). 574 A. Ockenfels et al. much—is then determined based on this information. In a single-object auction, one indivisible object is for sale. There are four single-object auc- tion types, which are widely used and analyzed both in theory and practice: the ascending-price auction (sometimes called English auction), the de- scending-price auction (sometimes called Dutch auction),2 the first-price sealed-bid auction, and the second-price sealed-bid auction (sometimes called Vickrey auction). The ascending-price auction is probably the best-known auction proce- dure: the price is raised until only one bidder remains. This remaining bidder wins the object at the price at which the strongest competitor dropped out. There are many ways to run ascending-price auctions: having the seller announce prices, the bidders announce prices, or the price con- tinuously rising on a ‘‘price clock’’. In the latter version, which is the one we will refer to when we speak of ascending-price auctions, bidders can quit the auction at any price and observe other bidders quitting. Because the price clock determines the price path, there is no possibility for bidders to speed up or slow down the auction process, or to employ ‘‘jump bids’’ as a signaling device. The descending-price auction works in the opposite way: the auction starts at a high price, which a price clock then lowers. The first bidder to call out his acceptance of the displayed price immediately stops the clock. This bidder wins the object and pays the price at which the clock stopped. Note that while in the ascending-price auction the winner pays a price determined by his strongest competitor (the price on the clock when the second-to-last bidder exits), the winner in the descending-price auction determines the final price (the price on the clock which he was the first to accept). In the first-price sealed-bid auction, bidders independently submit a single bid, without seeing the others’ bids. There is no open, dynamic bidding. The bidder who submits the highest bid wins and pays a price equal to his bid. In the second-price sealed-bid auction, again the bidder who submits the highest bid wins, but here he pays a price equal to the second- highest bid. In addition to the four types of auctions, there are two standard models of how bidders value an item: the private-value and the common-value model.