Inter–temporal Differences in the Income Elasticity of Demand for Lottery Tickets Inter–temporal Differences in the Income Elasticity of Demand for Lottery Tickets

Abstract - We estimate annual income elasticities of demand for lottery tickets using county–level panel data for three states and fi nd that the income elasticity of demand (and, thus, the tax burden) for lottery tickets has changed over time. This is due to changes in a state’s lottery game portfolio and the growth in consumer income more so than competition from alternative gambling opportunities. Trends in the income elasticity for instant and online lottery games appear to be different. Our results raise doubts about the long–term growth potential of lottery revenue and have policy implications for state governments and those concerned about regressivity.

INTRODUCTION

eginning with New Hampshire in 1964, 42 states and Bthe District of Columbia have legalized state–sponsored lotteries. Lottery sales in the United States topped $48 billion in fi scal year 2006 (roughly $160 per capita), of which state governments retained nearly $17 billion (about one percent of total state government revenue) for spending on education, infrastructure, and other social programs. The preceding sales and tax revenues suggest an average tax rate of 35 percent, an average rate much higher than that of other state excise taxes (Clotfelter and Cook, 1987). The growth in lottery sales over the past several decades is not only a result of more state lotteries, but also of an ever–evolving product line that is designed to attract and retain customers through higher jackpots, some reaching several hundred million dollars. The growth of the lottery industry has sparked much research. Numerous studies, including Filer, Moak, and Uze (1988), Davis, Filer, and Moak (1992), and Alm, McKee, and Skidmore (1993), have explored the determinants of a state’s Thomas A. Garrett & decision to adopt a lottery.1 The optimal design of lottery Cletus C. Coughlin games in terms of maximizing sales was studied by Quiggin Federal Reserve Bank of (1991), Cook and Clotfelter (1993), and Garrett and Sobel St. Louis, P.O. Box 442 (1999). Whether lottery ticket purchases are substitutes or St. Louis, Missouri complements for other consumer goods has been explored 63166 by Borg, Mason, and Shapiro (1993) and Kearney (2005). The revenue impact of cross–border lottery shopping has been

National Tax Journal Vol. LXIl, No. 1 1 See Coughlin, Garrett, and Hernádez–Murillo (2006) for a literature review March 2009 of the determinants of lottery adoption. 77 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL studied by Garrett and Marsh (2002) and with another study (another state, county, Tosun and Skidmore (2004). Similarly, city, or zip code at a point in time), but Brown and Rork (2005) examined the little evidence exists on how the income strategic interaction between state lot- elasticity of demand for a specifi c state’s teries using a model of tax competition. lottery product has changed over time. Finally, because states earmark net lottery As discussed in the next section, rising revenues for programs such as education, consumer income, the introduction of new several studies have explored whether games, and other changes in the gambling lottery revenues increase spending on the landscape suggest that the tax incidence target program (Borg and Mason, 1990; of lottery expenditures has not remained Spindler, 1995; Novarro, 2005). constant over time. The issue that has received the greatest This paper provides evidence on the attention is the tax incidence of lottery dynamic nature of the income elasticity ticket expenditures for different income of demand for lottery tickets. Using a groups (Clotfelter and Cook, 1987, 1989; panel of annual county–level data for Scott and Garen, 1994; Hansen, 1995; Far- three states that have had a lottery for rell, Morgenroth, and Walker 1999; Price 17 or more years, we estimate annual and Novak, 1999; and Forrest, Gulley, and income elasticities of demand for each Simmons 2000).2 Studies have used data state. This provides a sufficient time of various levels of aggregation, such as series to track how the income elasticity individual survey data as well as aggre- of demand for lottery tickets and, thus, gate data for zip codes, cities, counties, the lottery tax burden in each state has and states.3 The majority of research has changed over the past several years.5 We shown that state lotteries can be charac- link the trends in the income elasticity of terized as regressive taxation, implying a demand over time to possible business decreasing tax burden in relative terms cycle effects, the introduction of new lot- as incomes rises.4 Not surprisingly, this tery products, and changes in consumer tax regressivity is raised as an objection income. Our framework also allows us to state lotteries, especially in light of the to explore whether growing competition revenue maximization objective of state for lottery products from casino gambling lottery agencies. and neighboring state lottery games has In most lottery demand studies a single changed the income elasticity of demand income elasticity of demand is estimated for lottery tickets. from the sample of data, thus providing Our results shed new light on the a static look at the tax incidence of lottery dynamic nature of lottery tax burdens and tickets. The results from previous research suggest that income elasticities estimated allow a comparison of a single income from a single year of data may accurately elasticity estimate from one study (state, refl ect the income elasticity of demand county, city, or zip code at a point in time) only for a specifi c year. The degree of

2 This is not a complete list of all lottery demand studies. See the above studies for additional research. 3 Studies of lottery purchases have typically used personal income. A recent study by Coughlin and Garrett (forthcoming) fi nds that lottery purchases are most strongly infl uenced by transfer payments. 4 For example, Miyazaki, Hansen, and Sprott (1998) found 19 of 27 cases in which the specifi c lottery was regressive. Cases of proportionality and progressivity were also found. 5 Changing income elasticities provide evidence on the changing tax regressivity or progressivity of the lottery. An income elasticity exceeding one indicates that the lottery tax is progressive, an income elasticity equal to one indicates the lottery tax is proportional, and an income elasticity less than one (including negative values) indicates that the lottery tax is regressive. If the income elasticity is less than one and is declining (increasing) over time, then the lottery tax is becoming more (less) regressive. 78 Inter–temporal Differences in the Income Elasticity of Demand for Lottery Tickets lottery regressivity or progressivity is affected the income elasticity of demand time dependent. Our annual estimates is uncertain. also provide a picture of the long–term Consider how advertising expenditures revenue prospects of the state lotteries might affect the income elasticity of lottery studied here, an important issue for all demand. Increased lottery–related adver- lottery states and programs funded by tising should lead to increased spending lottery revenue. Our evidence suggests on lottery tickets; however, the effect of that the long–term revenue prospects of increased advertising expenditures on state lotteries are unfavorable compared the income elasticity of lottery demand to other sources of state tax revenue. depends on how the spending patterns of individuals change.6 The income elas- ticity could increase, decrease, or remain INCOME ELASTICITIES OVER TIME: 7 THEORY unchanged. Many advertising campaigns are targeted to certain groups, so specifi c Numerous reasons exist that suggest advertising campaigns are undertaken the income elasticity of demand for lottery with an expectation of affecting groups tickets is likely to change over time. The differentially.8 A campaign targeting most general is that consumer income has low–income players should tend to reduce generally increased over time. A consis- the income elasticity of lottery demand, tent empirical fi nding is that as income while a campaign targeting high–income rises, individuals spend a smaller share players should tend to increase the income of their budgets on lottery tickets (i.e., elasticity of lottery demand. A fi nal obser- the income elasticity is less than one). vation is that an advertising campaign is Thus, as incomes tend to rise over time, often tied to the introduction of a new the income elasticity of lottery demand game, which itself might be targeted to should decline. appeal to a certain audience. In addition to changes in income, New games may also result in chang- the competitive environment in which ing income elasticities of demand over lotteries operate is ever–changing. time. Many states have added instant and Relative to the mid 1980s, today’s envi- online games that offer higher jackpots. ronment includes different advertis- For example, many states participate ing campaigns, new lottery games, in multi–state online lottery games that more gaming alternatives (e.g., casino generate much larger jackpots than could gaming and lotteries in neighboring be offered from relying on lottery sales states), and increased information about in a single state. In addition, starting games. Precisely how these changes have in the 1990s many states began to offer

6 Because our empirical analysis uses counties rather than individuals as our unit of observation, the specifi c change must cause different percentage changes in lottery spending across counties. Such a difference does not invalidate the argument. 7 To illustrate, assume two individuals whose spending on lottery tickets and incomes are as follows: player #1—$100 spending with $10,000 income, and player #2—$150 spending with $20,000 income. In this case, the income elasticity is 0.5. Assume an advertising campaign that causes both players to spend an additional ten percent on lottery tickets. With player #1 spending $110 and player #2 spending $165, the income elastic- ity remains at 0.5. If, however, the percentage change in spending differs between the two players, then the income elasticity will change. If spending by player #1 increased from $100 to $105 and spending by player #2 increased from $150 to $165, then the income elasticity would be greater than 0.5. On the other hand, if spending by player #1 increased from $100 to $115 and spending by player #2 increased from $150 to $165, then the income elasticity would be less than 0.5. 8 The has placed Spanish–language ads in Hispanic newspapers, radio stations, and websites. See “Marketing Is the Ticket for Massachusetts State Lottery,” Boston Globe (April 2, 2008): A1. 79 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL

$2, $5, or even $10 and $20 instant lottery pertains to casino gaming in that, for games that offer much higher jackpots ($1 a specific state, spending on lotteries or $2 million) and payout rates (above 60 in counties with casinos is likely to be percent) than the traditional $1 instant affected more than counties without casi- game (payout rates averaging 50 percent).9 nos. The key to any change in the income Research by Mikesell (1989) and Oster elasticity of lottery demand is whether (2004) suggests that large–jackpot online spending in the border (or casino) coun- lottery games may attract a wealthier ties is affected differently. For example, if player than lower–jackpot instant games lottery spending in each border county is and, thus, may increase the income elastic- affected identically in percentage terms ity of demand.10 by the introduction of a lottery in a border Furthermore, the magnitude of the state, then the income elasticity of lot- change in the income elasticity of lottery tery demand will be unchanged for both demand likely differs for instant lottery the border counties and the entire state. games and online lottery games. Instant However, even when the individual bor- lottery games typically offer prizes ranging der counties and the casino counties are from about $100,000 to $250,000, with some affected differently relative to each other, offering a top–prize of $1 or $2 million.11 it is uncertain how the income elasticity Although these amounts have increased for the entire state will change.12 If the over time, the top–prize amounts for online income elasticity of the border or casino lotto games have increased much more— counties increases, the state’s income elas- top prizes in the 1980s and early 1990s were ticity may increase, decrease, or remain typically several million dollars, whereas unchanged. today top prizes reach hundreds of mil- In sum, changes in the income elasticity lions of dollars. of demand for lottery tickets likely depend Income elasticities of lottery demand upon various factors, such as income may also change over time due to the growth, lottery advertising, the introduc- introduction of lotteries in neighboring tion of new games, whether a neighboring states and by the introduction of casino state has a lottery or has introduced a gaming. The start of a lottery by a neigh- lottery, and the extent of casino gaming. boring state is likely to have larger effects Because these factors differ across states, on lottery spending in a state’s counties it seems reasonable to assume that the that border the state than on other (i.e., levels and trends of the income elasticity internal) counties. A similar comment of lottery demand also differ across states.

9 Contacts at state lottery agencies confi rm that higher–priced instant games have, on average, higher payout rates than traditional $1 instant lottery games. 10 Because we have aggregated game data (online and instant), it is diffi cult to examine how changes in payout rates affect the distribution of lottery players for two reasons. First, payout rates are only changed for on- line pari–mutuel games on an infrequent basis, usually by worsening the odds of winning by adding more combinations. Second, the expected return to players can change drawing to drawing for pari–mutuel online games when roll–overs occur and the jackpot grows. These high frequency events cannot be captured with our annual data. However, the effect that the introduction of an online game that has different payout rates over time (e.g., ) has on the distribution of lottery players can be captured by our annual income elasticity estimates. 11 This information is based on a search of state lottery websites. 12 This can be demonstrated as follows: Assume a simple regression of lottery sales on income (both in logs) for a cross section of counties. The OLS estimate of the income elasticity of demand is ∑x y /∑x 2, where x = – – i i i i (X – X) and y = (Y – Y). Assuming no change in county income (X ), an exogenous increase in lottery sales i i i i – for a set of border counties would increase the respective Y as well as Y. For those counties in which income – i increased, the difference (Y – Y) could be positive or negative depending upon the relative changes in Y and – i i Y. Thus, the effect on the income elasticity estimate is ambiguous. 80 Inter–temporal Differences in the Income Elasticity of Demand for Lottery Tickets

INCOME ELASTICITIES OVER TIME: fornia, and Minnesota—and increased in PREVIOUS EVIDENCE two states—Oregon and Florida. It is possible that differences in product mix Few studies have explored how the contributed to the varied results across income elasticity and tax regressivity of states; however, these possibilities, along lottery sales have changed over time. For with the possibility of income differences, those few studies, the time period covered were neither discussed nor controlled for has been too short to allow definitive econometrically. conclusions about changes over time.13 Collectively, the results of Mikesell Mikesell (1989) used annual data for a (1989), Jackson (1994) and Hansen et al. subset of counties in Illinois from 1985– (2000) illustrate that the income elasticity 1987.14 Three major findings emerged. can take on a range of values with no con- First, the income elasticity for instant sistent trend over time. However, when no lottery games tended to be less than for time series exceeding ten years has been online games. Second, all income elastici- examined for a specifi c state, any attempt ties did not differ statistically from one, to make meaningful comparisons over so there was no evidence of tax regressiv- time is problematic. Our data and empiri- ity. Third, the income elasticity for total cal methodology allow us to address this lottery sales always exceeded one and shortcoming. increased from 1985 through 1987. Jackson (1994) examined lottery sales, in total and for three separate games, for DATA AND EMPIRICAL METHODOLOGY 1983 and 1990 in cities with 15,000 or more residents in Massachusetts. He found that We require an adequate time series the estimated income elasticities declined of lottery sales and personal income signifi cantly for total sales and for each of data to capture meaningful trends in the the three games. The declines in each case income elasticity of demand for lottery were so large that the lottery changed from tickets. We use county–level lottery sales being a highly progressive tax in 1983 to because county–level data is the most a regressive tax in 1990. In addition, the disaggregated unit of observation for income elasticities for instant games were which annual data are available, unlike less than those for online games. data at the zip–code or census–tract level. A final study using multiple years The desired minimum length for our and county–level data for fi ve states was time series is 15 to 20 years prior to 2005 conducted by Hansen et al. (2000). They because this period of time includes two found that the lottery tax for the fi ve states recessions, a rapid economic expansion, tended to be regressive, but no consistent the introduction of many multi–state fi nding emerged with respect to changes online lottery games such as PowerBall in the income elasticity of lottery demand. and the Big Game (now ), The income elasticity of lottery demand and the introduction of higher–prize decreased in three states—Indiana, Cali- instant lottery games.15

13 Similar to our study, the studies discussed in this section include additional control variables. Each study includes a measure of educational attainment and a measure of racial composition. Jackson (1994) and Hansen, Miyazaki, and Sprott (2000) also include the percentage of county population that is greater than 65 years old. Each study also includes a control variable not used in the other studies: Mikesell (1989)—percentage living in urban areas; Jackson (1994)—city population; and Hansen et al. (2000)—a linear time trend. 14 Mikesell (1989) removed counties that either bordered another state or had an employment–to–residents ratio exceeding 1.1. As a result, 58 of the 102 counties in Illinois were used. 15 PowerBall began in 1992 and was formerly called (started in 1988). The Big Game started in 1996 and became Mega Millions in 2002. 81 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL

We contacted the 17 states that have αγβ δη [1] SalesIit X itt Incomeit had a lottery since at least 1990 and have T−1 a minimum of 30 counties (to ensure an + η ⋅ ⋅δε+ ∑ t InI comeit tit t , adequate number of cross–sectional units t=1 on which to estimate annual income elasticities).16 Many states do not main- where Salesit is the natural logarithm of tain records of county–level lottery sales real per capita instant lottery sales, online (instant and online) for years prior to lottery sales, or total lottery sales in county the late 1990s or early 2000s. Only West i in year t, Incomeit is the natural logarithm Virginia, Iowa, and Florida were able to of real per capita income in county i in provide us with county–level lottery sales γ δ year t, i and t denote county dummy (instant and online) for each year begin- variables and year dummy variables, ning in the late 1980s. We use county–level ε 19 respectively, and it is the error term. data for these three states with each We follow past literature and include sample starting with the fi rst complete economic and demographic control vari- year of lottery operations. Specifi cally, the ables on an annual basis in matrix X, such analysis for West Virginia uses county– as the percent of the county population level data (55 counties) for the period that is white and the county unemploy- 1987 to 2005, the analysis for Iowa uses ment rate.20, 21 Variables that capture the county–level data (98 counties) for the age and educational attainment of each period 1987 to 2005, and the analysis for county’s population, such as the percent Florida uses county–level data (67 coun- of the population over age 65 and the ties) for the period 1989 to 2005.17 percent of the population with a high Because we wish to explore how the school diploma, are not included because income elasticity of demand has changed they are only available for each decennial over time, our empirical model is structured census and intercensal estimates at the to provide estimates of the difference in the county level vary too little year to year to income elasticity in any year t relative to a allow meaningful estimation. The county base year. We chose 2005, the latest year in dummy variables are likely to pick up our three samples, as our base year.18 We some of the variation in lottery sales related estimate the following model for each of the to differences in age and educational three lottery states and for total lottery sales, attainment. The county dummy variables instant lottery sales, and online lottery sales: will also capture the effects of cross–border

16 Lottery agencies in New York, Pennsylvania, Michigan, Illinois, Ohio, Colorado, Washington, California, Iowa, Missouri, West Virginia, Montana, Florida, Kansas, South Dakota, Virginia, and Wisconsin were contacted. 17 Start dates for the three lotteries are: West Virginia—January 9, 1986; Iowa—August 22, 1985; Florida—January 12, 1988. Our sample period ends in 2005 because county–level demographic data, including income, was not available for later years at the time of this writing. Lyon County, Iowa was omitted due to extreme outlier problems and questionable data reliability. 18 The computed income elasticities will be the same regardless of the base year. 19 We considered several different covariance matrices to account for possible heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation. All models were estimated using White’s heteroscedastic standard errors, Beck and Katz panel–corrected standard errors (to account for groupwise heteroscedasticity), and Prais–Winsten adjusted standard errors to account for autocorrelation. The empirical estimates and conclusions drawn from the estimates were not qualitatively different across covariance matrices. The presented results have White’s heteroscedasticity–corrected standard errors. 20 County population was obtained from the Bureau of Economic Analysis and the unemployment rate was obtained from the Bureau of Labor Statistics. The percent of county population that is white was obtained from the U.S Census, Intercensal County Population Estimates by Age, Sex, and Race (1980–1989, 1990–1999, and 2000–2005). 21 Mikesell (1994) also included the unemployment rate as a control variable. He argued that personal income might not be suffi cient to capture the cyclical condition of a state economy because personal income included transfer pay- ments to soften the cyclical decline. He found a positive relationship between unemployment and lottery spending. 82 Inter–temporal Differences in the Income Elasticity of Demand for Lottery Tickets shopping (Garrett and Marsh, 2002; Tosun elasticities over time. Obtaining the actual and Skidmore, 2004) and of casino gaming income elasticities for each year t is done η η 24 facilities and pari–mutuel racetracks (Elliot by calculating 2005 + t. and Navin, 2002).22 The year and county dummy variables RESULTS AND DISCUSSION are included to capture the effect of changes in lottery product mix, market- Equation [1] is estimated separately for ing, and lottery game payout structure West Virginia, Iowa, and Florida. For each (i.e., price changes) on state lottery sales. state and game type (total sales, instant The year dummy variables will capture sales, and online sales), we also estimate a the effect of these changes on lottery single income elasticity of demand for the sales because these changes occur at the entire sample period to allow for a compari- state level and would, thus, be expected son of this average elasticity for the sample to affect all counties in the state. Any dif- with the annual income elasticity estimates. ferential effect across counties resulting As a reference, a history of online games from these changes will be captured in in each of the three states is provided in the county dummy variables. Table 1 since we wish to see how the esti- The per capita income variable is multi- mated income elasticities may differ in plied by each of the year dummy variables response to changes in the lottery product except the 2005 dummy variable to gener- line.25 We did not obtain a history of instant ate T – 1 variables such that each contains games since at least a dozen different per capita income for a specifi c year t and instant games are offered simultaneously zero for all other years.23 The coeffi cients with each having different and relatively on these year–specifi c income variables, short life spans (about six months). How- η each denoted as t, refl ect the difference ever, we did obtain the start dates for in the income elasticity of demand in various higher–priced ($2, $5, $10, and year t compared to the estimated income $20) instant lottery games and will refer η η elasticity of demand for 2005 ( = 2005). to these start dates when discussing the The t–statistic on each year–specifi c elas- results for instant lottery games. ticity estimate will reveal whether the income elasticity of demand in any year t The West is signifi cantly different than the income elasticity of demand in 2005, thereby pro- The empirical results for the West Vir- viding direct evidence of changing income ginia lottery are shown in Table 2.26,27 The

22 Casino gambling is available in Iowa and Florida. Racetrack casinos are available in Iowa, Florida, and West Virginia. See www.americangaming.org. 23 Per capita income was obtained from the Bureau of Economic Analysis. 24 An income elasticity less than one suggests that the lottery is a normal good and that the lottery tax is regres- sive, a negative income elasticity suggests an inferior good and a tax that is regressive, and an income elasticity greater than one refl ects a luxury good and a tax that is progressive. 25 A history of online games in each state was provided by the respective state lottery agency. 26 The coeffi cients on the county and year dummy variables are not listed, but will gladly be provided for each regression and each state upon request. The majority of the county and year dummy variable coeffi cients in the regressions for West Virginia are statistically signifi cant. 27 As seen in Table 2, the coeffi cient on the unemployment rate varies in sign and statistical signifi cance. Because we include income and unemployment in the same regression equation, a change in the unemployment rate holding income constant reveals how changes in the distribution of county income affect county lottery sales. A negative coeffi cient on the unemployment rate may refl ect an increase in the upper distribution of income, which, if lotteries are regressive, would imply lower sales. We consistently fi nd a negative coeffi cient on the unemployment rate in the Iowa and Florida regressions presented later.

83 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL

TABLE 1 ONLINE LOTTERY GAME HISTORY Online Games Start Date End Date Multi–State Game Daily 3 Feb–87 No Daily 4 Feb–87 No Cash 25 Feb–90 No Travel Keno Dec–92 No Lotto Dec–86 Jan–90 No

Daily Millions Sep–96 Mar–98 Yes (replaced with Cash 4 Life) Mar–98 Sep–00 Yes (replaced with Rolldown) Sep–00 Apr–02 Yes (replaced with ) Apr–02 Yes

Lotto America Feb–88 Apr–92 Yes (replaced with PowerBall) Apr–92 Yes Iowa Lotto May–86 Oct–93 No Pick 3 Jul–98 No Pick 4 Sep–03 No Freeplay Replay Mar–00 Sep–03 No Daily Deal Feb–91 Jan–92 No $100,000 Daily Cash Jan–92 No Lucky Day Oct–93 Oct–94 No Super Cash Oct–94 Jun–98 No Dream Draw Jun–96 Nov–96 No

Daily Millions Sep–96 Mar–98 Yes (replaced with Cash 4 Life) Mar–98 Nov–00 Yes (replaced with Rolldown) Sep–00 Apr–02 Yes (replaced with Hot Lotto) Apr–02 Yes

Lotto America Feb–88 Apr–92 Yes (replaced with PowerBall) Apr–92 Yes Florida Lotto Apr–88 No Cash 3 Apr–88 No Fantasy 5 Apr–89 No Play 4 Jul–91 No Mega Money May–99 No Note: Game histories provided by lottery agencies. See text for start dates for higher–priced instant tickets. calculated annual income elasticities are games, both over time and in a given plotted in Figure 1. The estimated income year. The income elasticities for instant elasticities reveal that the West Virginia games in early years were not statistically lottery is regressive and that there are different than one, suggesting that the statistically signifi cant differences in the lottery tax associated with instant games degree of regressivity over the sample was initially proportional rather than period. In addition, the annual income regressive. However, instant games have elasticity estimates are generally differ- become more regressive over time, having ent than the sample income elasticity annual income elasticities between 0.78 coeffi cient estimated for specifi cations (1), in 1987 and –0.33 in 2005. Online games (3), and (5). are generally more regressive than (and There are differences in the income inferior to) instant games, and the annual elasticity of demand for instant and online income elasticities are more variable than

84 Inter–temporal Differences in the Income Elasticity of Demand for Lottery Tickets

TABLE 2 REGRESSION RESULTS: WEST VIRGINIA LOTTERY Total Lottery Sales Instant Lottery Sales Online Lottery Sales Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Constant 8.886** 12.223** –0.081 6.727** 12.03** 11.591** (3.31) (3.89) (0.04) (2.20) (3.31) (3.16) Percent White –0.108 0.247 1.522 –0.213 –1.422 0.334 (0.08) (0.17) (1.53) (0.18) (0.84) (0.23) Unemployment Rate 0.006 0.008 –0.009** 0.004 0.029** 0.020** (1.07) (1.26) (2.14) (0.77) (3.17) (2.04) η Income ( 1987–2005) –0.552** — 0.220 — –0.903** — (2.10) (0.95) (2.72) η Income ( 1987) — 0.128 — 1.112** — –0.551 (0.29) (3.29) (0.81) η Income ( 1988) — 0.589* — 0.939** — 0.414 (1.94) (3.50) (1.10) η Income ( 1989) — 0.087 — 0.871** — –0.635 (0.22) (3.34) (1.19) η Income ( 1990) — 0.721** — 1.032** — 0.0008 (2.77) (4.14) (0.00) η Income ( 1991) — 0.418 — 0.727** — –0.151 (1.59) (3.27) (0.50) η Income ( 1992) — –0.361 — 0.610** — –1.035 (0.64) (2.51) (1.42) η Income ( 1993) — 0.392* — 0.607** — –0.221 (1.68) (2.62) (0.84) η Income ( 1994) — 0.577** — 0.598** — –0.025 (2.72) (2.81) (0.11) η Income ( 1995) — 0.967** — 0.550** — 1.172** (4.42) (2.62) (3.94) η Income ( 1996) — 0.626** — 0.511** — 0.412* (2.69) (2.40) (1.73) η Income ( 1997) — 0.580** — 0.538** — 0.523** (2.84) (2.80) (2.02) η Income ( 1998) — 0.737** — 0.505** — 0.720** (3.54) (2.62) (3.03) η Income ( 1999) — 1.024** — 0.401** — 1.066** (4.16) (1.99) (3.78) η Income ( 2000) — 0.617** — 0.327 — 0.603** (2.87) (1.55) (2.80) η Income ( 2001) — 0.627** — 0.321 — 0.700** (2.95) (1.52) (3.33) η Income ( 2002) — 0.701** — 0.112 — 0.950** (2.95) (0.56) (3.53) η Income ( 2003) — 0.174 — 0.074 — 0.258 (0.89) (0.38) (1.49) η Income ( 2004) — 0.129 — 0.026 — 0.078 (0.63) (0.13) (0.41) η Income ( 2005) — –0.946** — –0.334 — –1.031** (3.02) (1.15) (2.98) Adjusted R2 0.758 0.768 0.841 0.847 0.784 0.798 Observations 1,045 1,045 1,045 1,045 1,045 1,045 Note: Absolute t–statistics are in parentheses and were computed using White’s heteroscedasticity–corrected standard errors. * denotes signifi cance at 10 percent, ** denotes signifi cance at 5 percent or better. County and year dummy variables are included in each specifi cation. The income elasticity estimates for 1987 to 2004 are each relative to the income elasticity for 2005.

85 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL

Figure 1. West Virginia Lottery: Income Elasticities, 1987–2005 1 0.5 0 -0.5 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 -1 -1.5 Income Elasticity -2 -2.5

Total Instant Online those for instant games in the earlier years convergence of instant and online income of the lottery.28 Online games have become elasticities is the addition of two multi– less regressive over time, especially since state lottery games to West Virginia’s 1992. As seen in Figure 1, the upward lottery portfolio—PowerBall in 1992 and trend in the income elasticity of online Daily Millions in 1996. Iowa has had an games begins in 1992—the same year identical experience with multi–state PowerBall began. This fact lends some game introduction (same games, same support to Oster’s (2004) fi nding that a lot- years of introduction), so its experience tery game having a larger jackpot may be will provide additional evidence for or less regressive. However, the regressivity against this hypothesis. of online games has increased after 2002, and the income elasticity of demand for The Iowa Lottery instant games has not noticeably increased as a result of the introduction of higher– The empirical results for the Iowa prize instant games in the 1990s ($2 and lottery are shown in Table 3 and the $5 instant games were introduced in 1994 calculated annual income elasticities are and 1998, respectively). plotted in Figure 2. Similar to the West In addition, Figure 1 shows that the Virginia lottery, the estimated annual income elasticities for instant and online income elasticities of demand for the games have become more similar since the Iowa lottery as a whole are different over mid 1990s. Although we have no a priori time, although statistically significant expectations on the income elasticities of differences in annual income elasticities demand for instant and online games, only occur in the early years of the lottery, perhaps one explanation for the apparent which appears to be less regressive than

28 In our prior discussion of studies examining income elasticities over time, we noted that Mikesell (1989) and Jackson (1994) found that the income elasticity for instant games was less than for online games. On the other hand, in addition to our fi nding, Stover (1987) fi nds that online games are more regressive (and inferior) than instant games using a sample of U.S. states. Hansen (1995), Hansen, Miyazaki, and Sprott (2000), and Price and Novak (1999) also provide evidence that lottery games can be inferior goods. Survey data from the Na- tional Opinion Research Council, which is reviewed in Kearney (2005), suggests that instant games are more regressive than online games.

86 Inter–temporal Differences in the Income Elasticity of Demand for Lottery Tickets

TABLE 3 REGRESSION RESULTS: IOWA LOTTERY Total Lottery Sales Instant Lottery Sales Online Lottery Sales Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Constant 2.084 4.275** 0.193 3.403 2.902** 3.130 (1.51) (2.05) (0.12) (1.44) (1.96) (1.39) Percent White 0.146 –1.101 1.556 0.066 –1.533 –2.200* (0.15) (1.04) (1.38) (0.06) (1.44) (1.93) Unemployment Rate –0.028** –0.026** –0.030** –0.028** –0.020** –0.020** (4.89) (4.55) (4.66) (4.26) (3.32) (3.19) η Income ( 1987–2005) 0.158 — 0.171 — 0.122 — (1.51) (1.44) (1.09) η Income ( 1987) — 0.582** — 0.674** — 0.385 (2.33) (2.37) (1.43) η Income ( 1988) — 0.419* — 0.560** — 0.125 (1.87) (2.20) (0.52) η Income ( 1989) — 0.294 — 0.246 — 0.257 (1.23) (0.91) (1.00) η Income ( 1990) — 0.389 — 0.506* — 0.117 (1.63) (1.86) (0.46) η Income ( 1991) — 0.474** — 0.693** — 0.052 (2.03) (2.62) (0.21) η Income ( 1992) — 0.375 — 0.533** — 0.072 (1.58) (1.98) (0.28) η Income ( 1993) — 0.183 — 0.295 — –0.003 (0.86) (1.22) (0.01) η Income ( 1994) — 0.166 — 0.298 — –0.014 (0.71) (1.12) (0.06) η Income ( 1995) — 0.074 — 0.230 — –0.188 (0.36) (0.98) (0.84) η Income ( 1996) — 0.048 — 0.173 — –0.184 (0.22) (0.69) (0.78) η Income ( 1997) — –0.041 — 0.047 — –0.164 (0.18) (0.18) (0.67) η Income ( 1998) — 0.002 — 0.052 — –0.006 (0.01) (0.21) (0.03) η Income ( 1999) — –0.089 — –0.099 — 0.005 (0.41) (0.41) (0.02) η Income ( 2000) — 0.042 — 0.096 — 0.005 (0.19) (0.38) (0.02) η Income ( 2001) — 0.031 — 0.087 — –0.083 (0.15) (0.36) (0.36) η Income ( 2002) — 0.146 — 0.197 — –0.007 (0.68) (0.81) (0.03) η Income ( 2003) — 0.121 — 0.212 — –0.067 (0.58) (0.89) (0.30) η Income ( 2004) — 0.159 — 0.199 — 0.043 (0.72) (0.80) (0.18) η Income ( 2005) — 0.057 — –0.011 — 0.166 (0.32) (0.06) (0.86) Adjusted R2 0.835 0.835 0.826 0.826 0.839 0.838 Observations 1,862 1,862 1,862 1,862 1,862 1,862 Note: Absolute t–statistics are in parentheses. * denotes signifi cance at 10 percent, ** denotes signifi cance at 5 percent or better. County and year dummy variables are included in each specifi cation. The income elasticity estimates for 1987 to 2004 are each relative to the income elasticity for 2005. Sample period is 1987 to 2005 for 98 counties.

87 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL

Figure 2. Iowa Lottery: Income Elasticities, 1987–2005 0.8

0.6

0.4

0.2 Income Elasticity 0 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 -0.2

Total Instant Online in later years.29 The computed income statistical signifi cance of the coeffi cient elasticities of demand reveal that the Iowa estimates in Table 3, this downward trend lottery is regressive but less so than the is generally signifi cantly different through West Virginia lottery. No lottery games 1992 for instant games and the lottery as in Iowa are (statistically) inferior goods. a whole. The trend in instant game income elastici- Similar to West Virginia’s experience ties and elasticity magnitudes are similar with multi–state games, Iowa introduced to that of the West Virginia lottery. The PowerBall in 1992 and Daily Millions introduction of higher–priced and higher– in 1996. While the income elasticity of payout instant lottery tickets in Iowa ($2 demand for online games in West Virginia in 1992, $3 in 1999, $10 in 2000, and $20 in appears to have increased at the time these 2004) resulted in no apparent decrease in large jackpot games were introduced, the the regressivity of instant lottery games, income elasticity of demand for online but it is possible that the introduction of games in Iowa has not increased. In fact, higher–priced instant games in Iowa (and none of the pre–2005 income elasticities West Virginia) did slow the increase in of demand for online games is statisti- regressivity that has occurred over time. cally different than the 2005 online game Figure 2 reveals that the income elas- income elasticity, which itself is not sta- ticities for instant and online games in tistically different than zero. Finally, the Iowa have trended down over the period relative difference between instant and of 1987 to 1997 and then appear to have online income elasticities has remained increased slightly before remaining rela- much more constant over time than in tively stable since that time. Based on the West Virginia, thus shedding some doubt

29 The majority of the county dummy coeffi cients in each regression are statistically signifi cant, whereas the year dummy coeffi cients are not jointly different than zero. Although lacking in statistical signifi cance, we retained the year dummy variables in the Iowa regression equations because omitting them would provide misleading annual income elasticity estimates since the income elasticity estimates are based on the interaction of a year dummy and per capita income. We desire the income elasticity coeffi cient only to refl ect the effect of income changes on sales, not the year effect also. 88 Inter–temporal Differences in the Income Elasticity of Demand for Lottery Tickets on the idea that multi–state games might to its online lottery game portfolio since explain the convergence of instant and 1991—Mega Money in 1999. The general online income elasticities over time in decrease in the regressivity of online West Virginia. games appears to have begun in the year or two after 1991. During the mid 1990s The Florida Lottery the Florida Lotto and Fantasy Five were restructured to generate higher jackpots, The empirical results for the Florida possibly explaining the decrease in lottery are shown in Table 4 and the regressivity for online games during that calculated annual income elasticities are period. However, the regressivity of the plotted in Figure 3.30 Similar to the West lottery has not continued to (statistically) Virginia lottery and the Iowa lottery, the decrease since the introduction of the fi nal empirical results and computed annual online game in 1999. Finally, the annual income elasticities reveal that the Florida income elasticities of demand for instant lottery is regressive. The regressivity of the and online Florida lottery games are more lottery as a whole has remained relatively similar over time than those for the West stable over time, decreasing slightly in the Virginia lottery or the Iowa lottery. One late 1990s and early 2000s. The income explanation is that the Florida lottery elasticity of demand for online games has has experienced less change in its online decreased over time. The introduction of games over time than the other two state higher–priced instant games in 1993 ($2 lotteries. tickets), 1998 ($5 tickets), 2002 ($10 tick- ets), and 2004 ($20 tickets) had no appar- FURTHER ANALYSIS: CHANGES ent decrease in the regressivity of instant IN THE GAMBLING LANDSCAPE tickets, as the annual income elasticities of demand for instant games over the In this section we explore how the period 1990 to 2004 are not statistically introduction of casino gambling and a different from the 2005 value of 0.617, as state lottery in neighboring states may is evident from the insignifi cant income have changed the income elasticity of coeffi cients in specifi cation (4) of Table 4. demand for lottery tickets in each of The 1989 income elasticity of demand for our three states. Doing so allows us to instant games is not statistically different explore whether changes in the gambling than one. This result, along with similar landscape may have affected the levels fi ndings for instant games in West Virginia of the income elasticities estimated in and Iowa, suggest that instant lottery the earlier analysis. As discussed earlier, games were not (statistically) regressive however, if the income elasticity of the in the early years of the lottery. border counties changes, then the state’s The Florida lottery differs from the lot- income elasticity may also change, but not teries in West Virginia and Iowa in that necessarily in the same direction. there are no multi–state lottery games We re–estimate equation [1], but replace (see Table 1). In addition, the Florida the annual income elasticity estimates lottery has added only one online game with border county and casino county

30 The majority of the county dummy coeffi cients in each regression are statistically signifi cant. As with the Iowa lottery, we retained the insignifi cant year dummy variables to ensure that the annual income coeffi cients only refl ect the effect of income on sales and not also the year effect. The coeffi cient on percent white was not statistically signifi cant in the West Virginia and Iowa regressions, but it is negative and signifi cant in the Florida specifi cations. One hypothesis is that the variation in the percent of Florida county population that is white is much greater than in West Virginia and Iowa. For example, the standard deviation of the percent white variable is 0.10 in Florida and only 0.03 and 0.02 in West Virginia and Iowa, respectively.

89 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL

TABLE 4 REGRESSION RESULTS: FLORIDA LOTTERY Total Lottery Sales Instant Lottery Sales Online Lottery Sales Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Constant 1.777 3.072* 0.041 0.274 0.321 0.591 (1.12) (1.79) (0.03) (0.18) (0.20) (0.34) Percent White –2.480** –2.65** –1.921** –2.10** –3.845** –3.01** (3.90) (4.14) (3.41) (3.64) (6.14) (4.80) Unemployment Rate –0.011* –0.009 –0.010** –0.008 –0.012** –0.012** (1.93) (1.56) (2.01) (1.58) (2.03) (2.12) η Income ( 1989–2005) 0.502** — 0.627** — 0.635** — (2.99) (4.34) (3.61) η Income ( 1989) — 0.188* — 0.186* –0.265** (1.66) (1.63) — (2.36) η Income ( 1990) — 0.178 — 0.104 –0.299** (1.45) (0.85) — (2.58) η Income ( 1991) — 0.132 — 0.039 –0.302** (1.06) (0.35) — (2.46) η Income ( 1992) — 0.040 — –0.112 –0.351** (0.32) (1.00) — (2.80) η Income ( 1993) — 0.093 — –0.084 –0.270** (0.78) (0.82) — (2.19) η Income ( 1994) — 0.156 — –0.029 –0.167* (1.63) (0.35) — (1.72) η Income ( 1995) — 0.152* — –0.070 –0.132 (1.71) (0.86) — (1.52) η Income ( 1996) — 0.173* — 0.037 –0.071 (1.92) (0.44) — (0.83) η Income ( 1997) — 0.213** — 0.047 –0.041 (2.37) (0.58) — (0.48) η Income ( 1998) — 0.154* — 0.012 –0.081 (1.65) (0.15) — (0.89) η Income ( 1999) — 0.215** — –0.0006 –0.019 (2.16) (0.01) — (0.19) η Income ( 2000) — 0.269** — –0.004 0.077 (2.62) (0.05) — (0.74) η Income ( 2001) — 0.230** — 0.007 0.053 (2.03) (0.07) — (0.46) η Income ( 2002) — 0.199* — –0.020 0.047 (1.65) (0.18) — (0.40) η Income ( 2003) — 0.086 — –0.022 0.024 (0.73) (0.23) — (0.20) η Income ( 2004) — 0.003 — –0.053 –0.014 (0.03) (0.58) — (0.12) η Income ( 2005) — 0.380** — 0.617** 0.530** (2.14) (3.95) — (2.93) Adjusted R2 0.843 0.843 0.883 0.883 0.906 0.910 Observations 1,139 1,139 1,139 1,139 1,139 1,139 Note: Absolute t–statistics are in parentheses and were computed using White’s heteroscedasticity–corrected standard errors. * denotes signifi cance at 10 percent, ** denotes signifi cance at 5 percent or better. County and year dummy variables are included in each specifi cation. The income elasticity estimates for 1989 to 2004 are each relative to the income elasticity for 2005. Sample period is 1989 to 2005 for 67 counties.

90 Inter–temporal Differences in the Income Elasticity of Demand for Lottery Tickets

Figure 3. Florida Lottery: Income Elasticities, 1989–2005 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3

Income Elasticity 0.2 0.1 0 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005

Total Instant Online income elasticities. For each of our three lottery in a neighboring state. Coeffi cient states, we create a border dummy variable equality tests will reveal whether there is for each border state. Counties that border a signifi cant difference in the (marginal) this state are given a value of one and a income elasticity of demand for lottery value of zero otherwise. We then interact tickets before and after the introduction this border dummy variable with county of a lottery in a border state. We also income. Because we include per capita break the casino county income elasticity income for all counties in the regression, variable into a pre–casino period and a the coeffi cient on each interaction vari- post–casino period to see whether the able refl ects the marginal difference in income elasticity of demand for lottery the income elasticity of demand for lot- tickets in casino counties has changed tery tickets in a particular set of border after the introduction of casino gambling. counties relative to internal counties. A similar procedure is done for the counties The West Virginia Lottery that have introduced casino gambling, but this coeffi cient refl ects the marginal The empirical results for West Virginia difference in the income elasticity of are shown in Table 5. Of the fi ve states demand in casino counties relative to all that border West Virginia, Virginia and other counties. Kentucky introduced a lottery after West Next, for those border counties that Virginia introduced its lottery.31 The coeffi - border a state that introduced a lottery cients on income for the border counties of after the state of interest, we break the Ohio, Pennsylvania, and Maryland reveal interaction variable into two periods— the marginal difference in the income elas- one period is before the introduction of ticity of demand for West Virginia lottery a lottery in the neighboring state and the tickets in these border counties relative other period is after the introduction of a to internal West Virginia counties. This

31 Lottery start dates are: Ohio—August 1974; Kentucky—April 1989; Virginia—September 1988; Maryland—May 1973, Pennsylvania—March 1972; West Virginia—January 1986.

91 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL

TABLE 5 NEW LOTTERY AND CASINO GAMBLING: EFFECT ON INCOME ELASTICITY OF DEMAND

WEST VIRGINIA LOTTERY Total Sales Instant Sales Online Sales Variable (1) (2) (3) Income (η)—All counties in West Virginia –0.097 0.512** –0.467 (0.41) (2.35) (1.53)

Income (η)—OH border counties 0.660** –0.641** 2.064** (2.54) (2.67) (6.51)

Income (η)—PA border counties 1.029** 0.328 1.033** (3.46) (1.36) (3.06)

Income (η)—MD border counties –0.102 –0.413 0.495 (0.27) (1.43) (0.93)

Income (η)—VA border counties < 1989 –0.379 –0.505** –0.154 (1.59) (2.08) (0.50)

Income (η)—VA border counties ≥ 1989 –0.410* –0.545** –0.183 (1.77) (2.27) (0.62)

Income (η)—KY border counties < 1990 –2.401** –2.446** –1.926* (2.55) (3.28) (1.83)

Income (η)—KY border counties ≥ 1990 –2.430** –2.484** –1.962* (2.63) (3.39) (1.90)

Income (η)—Casino counties < 1995 –2.222** –0.863** –2.812** (4.88) (3.07) (4.82)

Income (η)—Casino counties ≥ 1995 –2.180** –0.877** –2.744** (4.86) (3.15) (4.77)

Adjusted R2 0.79 0.87 0.81 Number of Observations 1045 1045 1045 ≥ F–test: H0: VA<1989 = VA 1989 18.96** 48.10** 8.36** F–test: H : KY<1990 = VA≥1990 3.14* 8.37** 2.50 0 ≥ F–test: H0: Casino<1995 = Casino 1995 23.11** 4.04** 32.61** Note: Absolute t–statistics are in parentheses. * denotes signifi cance at 10 percent, ** denotes signifi cance at 5 percent or better. County and year dummy variables are included in each specifi cation, along with a constant term, the unemployment rate, and the percent white. Sample period is 1987 to 2005. Complete regression results will be provided upon request.

is also true for the counties that border ties. These border counties tend to have Virginia and Kentucky, but these income higher per capita income than the internal coeffi cients are specifi c to either the period counties. before border state lottery introduction Focusing on the Virginia and Kentucky or after border state lottery introduction. border county income coeffi cients, we fi nd From Table 5 we see that the income that the income elasticities of demand elasticity of demand in Ohio and Penn- before and after border state lottery sylvania border counties is signifi cantly introduction are very similar, but both are different (in most cases higher) than that quite different than the income elasticity of internal counties. The results suggest of demand for internal counties. Thus, the that the West Virginia lottery is regressive introduction of a lottery in a bordering for internal counties but is progressive state has not resulted in large changes in Ohio and Pennsylvania border coun- in the income elasticity of demand for

92 Inter–temporal Differences in the Income Elasticity of Demand for Lottery Tickets lottery tickets in Virginia and Kentucky border counties appears to be roughly the border counties, but the income elastic- same before and after the introduction of ity of demand in these border counties is the (statistically different different (much more regressive) than the for total sales and instant sales), although income elasticity in internal West Virginia both coeffi cients suggest that the Iowa lot- counties. The F–tests for coeffi cient equal- tery is more regressive in Nebraska border ity reveal that, in most cases, the income counties than in internal counties. A similar elasticity of demand before border state result is found for Minnesota border coun- lottery adoption is signifi cantly different ties, but only for total sales and instant than the income elasticity of demand after sales. Online games were slightly more border state lottery adoption. It is hard to progressive (less regressive) in Minnesota argue, however, that there is any substan- border counties prior to the introduction tive economic difference in the estimates. of the Minnesota lottery. The Wisconsin A similar result is found regarding West results reveal that the income elasticity of Virginia casino counties.32 The income demand in Wisconsin border counties is elasticity for these counties is signifi cantly no different than that of internal counties, smaller (more regressive) than for other and no signifi cant difference exists in these counties, yet there appears to be no eco- counties before and after the introduction nomic difference in the income elasticity of the (except online of demand before and after casino intro- sales prior to the Wisconsin lottery, which duction (–2.22 versus –2.18, respectively). is quite small). The F–test does reveal that these two coef- The income elasticity of demand in Iowa fi cients are statistically different, however. casino counties is less than in other Iowa counties. But there appears to be no sub- The Iowa Lottery stantive economic difference in the income elasticity of demand for lottery tickets in The results for the Iowa lottery are casino counties before and after the intro- shown in Table 6. The income elasticity duction of casino gaming in those counties. of demand in Illinois and Missouri border There is a statistically signifi cant difference counties is generally larger than that of in these coeffi cients for total lottery sales internal Iowa counties, thus suggesting and online lottery sales, however. that the Iowa lottery is less regressive or even progressive (depending upon the The Florida Lottery coeffi cient estimate) in these counties rela- tive to internal counties.33 The results for Florida are shown in The states of Nebraska, Minnesota, and Table 7.34 The income elasticity of demand Wisconsin adopted a lottery after Iowa. The in Alabama border counties is much lower income elasticity of demand in Nebraska than in internal counties. We fi nd that the

32 There are four racinos (casinos at pari–mutuel racetracks) in West Virginia, each in a different county. Two are located in the northern panhandle, one is located in the eastern panhandle, and one is located in the south central part of the state. 33 Lottery start dates are: Nebraska—September 1993; Missouri—January 1986; Illinois—July 1974; Wiscon- sin—September 1988; Minnesota—April 1990; Iowa—August 1985. Only one county in Iowa borders South Dakota (lottery start date of September 1987), so we did not create a South Dakota border dummy variable. Casino gaming began in Iowa in 1991, but did not become widespread until 1994. We, thus, chose 1994 as the break–year for our casino county dummy variable. Thirteen counties in Iowa currently have commercial casino gambling. 34 The Florida lottery began in January 1988 and the began in June of 1993. Five counties in Florida have either Native American gambling or racinos.

93 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL

TABLE 6 NEW LOTTERY AND CASINO GAMBLING: EFFECT ON INCOME ELASTICITY OF DEMAND

IOWA LOTTERY Total Sales Instant Sales Online Sales Variable (1) (2) (3) Income (η)—All counties in Iowa 0.240** 0.244* 0.224* (2.12) (1.94) (1.93)

Income (η)—IL border counties 1.349** 0.259 2.908** (6.17) (1.06) (12.92)

Income (η)—MO border counties 0.499** 0.521** 0.438** (3.18) (2.99) (2.71)

Income (η)—NE border counties < 1994 –0.645** –0.593* –0.745** (2.33) (1.93) (2.61)

Income (η)—NE border counties ≥ 1994 –0.656** –0.605** –0.749** (2.41) (2.00) (2.67)

Income (η)—MN border counties < 1991 –0.001 –0.052** 0.066** (0.16) (7.31) (9.99)

Income (η)—MN border counties ≥ 1991 –0.047** –0.091** 0.009 (7.90) (13.79) (1.45)

Income (η)—WI border counties < 1989 0.008 0.005 0.026* (0.58) (0.30) (1.73)

Income (η)—WI border counties ≥ 1989 0.004 0.009 –0.005 (0.32) (0.50) (0.36)

Income (η)—Casino counties < 1994 –0.518** –0.460** –0.682** (2.48) (1.98) (3.17)

Income (η)—Casino counties ≥ 1994 –0.510** –0.456** –0.668** (2.47) (1.99) (3.14)

Adjusted R2 0.83 0.83 0.85 Number of Observations 1881 1881 1881

F–test: H : NE<1994 = NE≥1994 3.61* 3.53* 0.46 0 ≥ F–test: H0: MN<1991 = MN 1991 211.25** 124.84** 303.08** F–test: H : WI<1989 = WI≥1989 0.31 0.25 14.38** 0 ≥ F–test: H0: Casino<1994 = Casino 1994 4.50** 1.11 14.79** Note: Absolute t–statistics are in parentheses. * denotes signifi cance at 10 percent, ** denotes signifi cance at 5 percent or better. County and year dummy variables are included in each specifi cation, along with a constant term, the unemployment rate, and the percent white. Sample period is 1987 to 2005. Complete regression results will be provided upon request. income elasticity of demand in Georgia demand is lower in casino counties relative border counties is slightly smaller after the to non–casino counties regardless of the introduction of the Georgia lottery than presence of a casino. This result also mimics before, but, as in the case of West Virginia the fi ndings for West Virginia and Iowa. and Iowa, the difference is not of any eco- nomic signifi cance. There also appears to DISCUSSION AND CONCLUDING be no meaningful difference in the income COMMENTS elasticity of demand in casino counties before and after the introduction of casino Some general conclusions regarding the gambling, but the income elasticity of dynamic nature of the income elasticity of 94 Inter–temporal Differences in the Income Elasticity of Demand for Lottery Tickets

TABLE 7 NEW LOTTERY AND CASINO GAMBLING: EFFECT ON INCOME ELASTICITY OF DEMAND

FLORIDA LOTTERY Total Sales Instant Sales Online Sales Variable (1) (2) (3) Income (η)—All counties in Florida 0.939** 1.009** 1.087** (8.08) (8.50) (6.02)

Income (η)—AL border counties –1.385** –1.202** –1.505** (13.47) (10.76) (12.22)

Income (η)—GA border counties < 1993 –0.778 –0.737* –0.877* (1.56) (1.93) (1.73)

Income (η)—GA border counties ≥ 1993 –0.823* –0.772** –0.925* (1.68) (2.05) (1.85)

Income (η)—Casino counties < 1995 –0.988** –1.059** –0.228 (4.62) (4.75) (1.50)

Income (η)—Casino counties ≥ 1995 –0.992** –1.072** –0.225 (4.68) (4.86) (1.49)

Adjusted R2 0.88 0.91 0.93 Number of Observations 1139 1139 1139

F–test: H : GA<1993 = GA≥1993 165.47** 103.47** 163.50** 0 ≥ F–test: H0: Casino<1995 = Casino 1995 0.94 9.74** 0.41 Note: Absolute t–statistics are in parentheses. * denotes signifi cance at 10 percent, ** denotes signifi cance at 5 percent or better. County and year dummy variables are included in each specifi cation, along with a constant term, the unemployment rate, and the percent white. Sample period is 1989 to 2005. Complete regression results will be provided upon request. demand for lottery tickets can be made • On average, the regressivity of from the empirical results presented in online games appears to be equal the previous sections. to or greater than the regressivity of instant games for the three states • The income elasticity of demand for studied. This result contrasts with lottery tickets changes over time. Mikesell’s (1989) fi nding for Illinois This suggests that empirical esti- that the income elasticity for online mates of income elasticities using games tended to be less than that a single cross–section or a single for instant games, but does support estimate from panel may not accu- Stover (1987) who fi nds that online rately refl ect the income elasticity of games are more regressive than demand over time. instant games in a sample of U.S. • There is some evidence that large states. The instant game tax burden jackpot games, such as multi–state appears to be proportional rather games, decrease (or at least stop regressive in the early years of the the increase in) the regressivity of lottery. online lottery games. The results are • There is some evidence that the less clear regarding this possibil- income elasticities of demand for ity for instant games, which tend instant and online games converge to become more regressive (or after a state’s online lottery product at least not less regressive) over line has remained similar for several time. years. 95 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL

• Not only do the income elasticities gambling or lottery introduction in change over time for a specifi c state, neighboring states. but the relative difference in the degree of regressivity for each state’s Several points follow from our empiri- lottery as a whole is ranked with the cal results regarding changing income income level of each state.35 The West elasticities over time. The regressivity of Virginia lottery is the most regres- state lotteries has been (and likely will sive and the state has the lowest per continue to be) the greatest argument capita income of the three states. The against them. Although one can take the Florida lottery is the least regressive view that regressivity is bad regardless and the state has the highest per of the degree of regressivity, we argue capita income of the three states. that there is a signifi cant difference in the Iowa lies between West Virginia and policy discussion of state lotteries with Florida in terms of lottery regressiv- regards to a lottery having an income elas- ity and per capita income.36 ticity of, say, 0.20 versus 0.90. Certainly • Changes in the gambling landscape the weight of the regressivity argument is external to the state lottery have had dependent upon the degree of regressiv- little effect on the income elasticity ity rather than absolute regressivity, and, of demand for lottery tickets. In as shown here, the degree of regressivity general, for the three states studied can change over time. Thus, any serious here, the income elasticity is slightly policy discussion regarding the regres- smaller after the introduction of a sivity of state lotteries and the respective lottery in neighboring states, but costs and benefi ts of state lotteries should the economic importance of this consider the dynamic nature of lottery tax difference is slight at most. Thus, burdens over time rather than rely on a lottery–game introduction in bor- static income elasticity estimate. dering states is unlikely to have One interesting feature of our analysis significantly changed the income is that the annual income elasticity esti- elasticity of demand for tickets in mates allow an examination of whether the home state. the income elasticity of demand for lottery • The trends in the income elasticity of tickets is sensitive to economic condi- demand over time likely refl ect the tions. One expectation is that the business general growth in consumer income cycles in the individual states and coun- and changes to the home–state lot- ties, which are distinctive to each state tery portfolio rather than any sig- and county, should affect lottery sales nifi cant economic effects from casino (Mikesell, 1994). For the years in which

35 Different income elasticities across the states should not be too surprising. For any individual consumer (which we approximate using county–level data), the income elasticity of demand for a product is (∂x/∂y)·(y/x), where x = quantity of a good and y = income. Ignoring the second part of the product for simplicity, equal income elasticities across consumers implies that the marginal propensity to consume lottery tickets is the same for all consumers (i.e., ∂x/∂y is the same for all consumers). This is highly unlikely given that consumers are het- erogeneous, especially across counties and states. In addition, equal marginal propensities to consume also, imply that the propensities to consume out of different income sources (transfer payments, earnings, etc.) are the same. Numerous studies have shown that the marginal propensities to consume out of different income sources are not the same (Carriker, Langemeier, Schroeder, and Featherstone, 1993; Holbrook and Stafford, 1971; Hymans and Shapiro, 1976). Thus, we attribute differences in income elasticities across the states to heterogeneous consumers, differences in lottery games across the states, and differences in propensities to consume out of different income sources (which vary across counties and states). 36 For the period 1992 to 2005, the average of annual per capita income for the three states is: West Virgin- ia—$21,376; Iowa—$24,485; Florida—$27,246. 96 Inter–temporal Differences in the Income Elasticity of Demand for Lottery Tickets real per capita income growth is less than a less–than–proportionate increase in per one percent, none of the estimated annual capita lottery revenue.38 A more optimistic income elasticities appears to be driven assessment can be reached by focusing on by weak economic conditions.37 We fi nd Florida’s recent experience. Between 2001 no evidence that the income elasticity of and 2005 the growth of real per capita demand for lottery tickets is different in lottery spending exceeded that of real recession and non–recession years. per capita income. However, a slightly Our results have several implications longer perspective reveals that real per for the revenue prospects of states lotter- capita lottery spending was lower in 2005 ies. First consider the long–term revenue than in 1994. Admittedly, the introduction potential of each state’s lottery. The esti- of new lottery products might increase mated income elasticities of demand for substantially the income elasticity of lot- the three states studied here suggest that tery demand and/or generate consistent lottery revenue growth will be much less upward shifts in lottery spending in than income growth. For every year for counties throughout a state. Based on our each state, the point estimates for our estimates and past spending on lotteries, income elasticities are less than one. More- there is little, if any, reason to anticipate over, we fi nd no evidence that the income such a scenario on a sustained basis. elasticity is likely to increase over time so A related issue is the potential growth that it would exceed one. of lottery revenues relative to the revenue In fact, the income elasticities for West growth potential from other signifi cant Virginia are negative, so income growth state taxes, such as personal income, cor- should lead to a decline in per capita lot- porate income, retail sales, and motor fuels. tery revenue over time. As evidence, real These tax bases typically have income elas- per capita lottery revenues in West Virginia ticities near one, except in the case of retail peaked in 1999. The annual income elastici- sales, which is less than one but still greater ties for the Iowa lottery are near zero for than 0.5, and corporate income, which is recent years, so income growth is likely around 3.0 (Holcombe and Sobel, 1996, to generate little growth in Iowa lottery 1997). These income elasticity estimates are revenue. Again, as evidence, real per capita somewhat larger than the income elasticity lottery revenues in Iowa have been roughly of lottery demand estimates found here constant since 1977. The revenue prospects and in prior lottery studies.39 Assuming of the Florida lottery are the most favor- relatively stable tax bases, this suggests able. The income elasticities have been near that the growth potential of state lotteries 0.5 in recent years, so per capita income with respect to income growth is much less growth should produce lottery–revenue than for traditional sources of revenue. On increases at a rate greater than that of the other hand, lottery revenues will not Iowa and West Virginia, although a given fall as much as revenues from traditional increase in per capita income will generate sources in an economic slowdown. The

37 Our use of annual data is far from ideal in capturing business–cycle effects. The coeffi cients on the year dummy variables (not shown) show no evidence of any business–cycle effects. 38 Similarly, population changes have also been unfavorable for lottery revenue growth. West Virginia’s popula- tion in 2005 was less than in 1987; however, population growth has been slightly positive since 2001. Positive population growth has occurred in Iowa, but at a slower pace than the United States as a whole. Of the three states, Florida has experienced the greatest population growth, and the state’s growth was substantially greater than the United States. 39 One caveat is that most lottery demand studies have used cross–sectional data, whereas Holcombe and Sobel (1996, 1997) used time series data. Mikesell (1994) estimated an income elasticity of demand around 3.0 in his panel study of state–level lottery sales. 97 NATIONAL TAX JOURNAL former may explain state lottery agencies’ Clotfelter, Charles, and Philip Cook. continual updates of their lottery portfolios “Implicit Taxation in Lottery Finance.” Na- to increase consumer participation. The tional Tax Journal 40 No. 4 (December, 1987): fact that we fi nd decreasing income elas- 533–46. ticities over time suggests that, at least for Clotfelter, Charles, and Philip Cook. the states and games studied here, lottery Selling Hope: State Lotteries in America. Cam- revenues have become a relatively more bridge: Harvard University Press, 1989. stable (with respect to changes in income) Cook, Philip, and Charles Clotfelter. source of revenue than traditional revenue “The Peculiar Scale Economies of Lotto.” sources. American Economic Review 83 No. 3 (June, 1993): 634–43. Coughlin, Cletus, and Thomas Garrett. Acknowledgments “Income and Lottery Sales: Transfers Trump We thank the Florida Lottery, the Iowa Income from Work and Wealth.” Public Lottery, and the West Virginia Lottery for Finance Review (forthcoming). providing lottery sales data. The views Coughlin, Cletus, Thomas Garrett, and expressed are those of the authors and Rubén Hernádez–Murillo. do not necessarily refl ect the views of the “The Geography, Economics, and Politics of Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis or the Lottery Adoption.” Federal Reserve Bank of Federal Reserve System. Lesli Ott pro- St. Louis Review 88 No. 3 (May/June, 2006): vided research assistance. 165–80. Davis, J. Ronnie, John Filer, and Donald Moak. “The Lottery as an Alternative Source of REFERENCES State Revenue.” Atlantic Economic Journal Alm, James, Michael McKee, and Mark 20 No. 2 (June, 1992): 1–10. Skidmore. Elliot, Donald, and John Navin. “Fiscal Pressure, Tax Competition, and the “Has Riverboat Gambling Reduced State Introduction of State Lotteries.” National Tax Lottery Revenue?” Public Finance Review 30 Journal 46 No. 4 (December, 1993): 463–76. No. 3 (May, 2002): 235–47. Borg, Mary, and Paul Mason. Farrell, Lisa, Edgar Morgenroth, and “Earmarked Lottery Revenues: Positive Ian Walker. Windfall or Concealed Redistribution “A Time Series Analysis of UK Lottery Sales: Mechanism?” Journal of Education Finance Long and Short–run Price Elasticities.” 15 (Winter, 1990): 289–301. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 61 Borg, Mary, Paul Mason, and Larry Shapiro. No. 4 (November, 1999): 513–26. “The Cross Effects of Lottery Taxes on Al- Filer, John, Donald Moak, and Barry Uze. ternative State Tax Revenue.” Public Finance “Why Some States Adopt Lotteries and Quarterly 21 No. 2 (April, 1993): 123–40. Others Don’t.” Public Finance Quarterly 16 Brown, Ryan, and Jonathan Rork. No. 3 (July, 1988): 259–83. “Copycat Gaming: A Spatial Analysis of Forrest, David, David Gulley, and Robert State Lottery Structure.” Regional Science and Simmons. Urban Economics 36 No. 6 (November, 2005): “Elasticity of Demand for UK National Lot- 795–807. tery Tickets.” National Tax Journal 53 No. 4 Carriker, Gordon, Michael Langemeier, Ted (December, 2000): 853–63. Schroeder, and Allen Featherstone. Garrett, Thomas, and Russell Sobel. “Propensity to Consume Farm Family Dis- “Gamblers Favor Skewness, Not Risk: Fur- posable Income from Separate Sources.” ther Evidence from United States’ Lottery American Journal of Agricultural Economics 75 Games.” Economics Letters 63 No. 1 (April, No. 3 (August, 1993): 739–44. 1999): 85–90. 98 Inter–temporal Differences in the Income Elasticity of Demand for Lottery Tickets

Garrett, Thomas, and Thomas Marsh. Mikesell, John. “The Revenue Impacts of Cross–Border “State Lottery Sales and Economic Activity.” Lottery Shopping in the Presence of Spatial National Tax Journal 47 No. 1 (March, 1994): Autocorrelation.” Regional Science and Urban 165–71. Economics 32 No. 4 (July, 2002): 501–19. Miyazaki, Anthony D., Ann Hansen, and Hansen, Ann. David E. Sprott. “The Tax Incidence of the Colorado State “A Longitudinal Analysis of Income–Based Lottery Instant Game.” Public Finance Quar- Tax Regressivity of State–Sponsored Lotter- terly 23 No. 3 (July, 1995): 385–98. ies.” Journal of Public Policy and Marketing 17 Hansen, Ann, Anthony Miyazaki, and No. 2 (Fall, 1998): 161–72. David Sprott. Novarro, Neva. “The Tax Incidence of Lotteries: Evidence “Earmarked Lottery Profi ts: A Good Bet for from Five States.” Journal of Consumer Affairs Education Finance?” Journal of Education 34 No. 2 (Winter, 2000): 182–203. Finance 31 No. 1 (Summer, 2005): 23–44. Holbrook, Robert, and Frank Stafford. Oster, Emily. “The Propensity to Consume Separate “Are All Lotteries Regressive? Evidence Types of Income: A Generalized Permanent from the PowerBall.” National Tax Journal Income Hypothesis.” Econometrica 39 No. 1 57 No. 2 (June, 2004): 179–87. (January, 1971): 1–21. Price, Donald, and Shawn Novak. Holcombe, Randall, and Russell Sobel. “The Tax Incidence of Three “Measuring the Growth and Variability of Games: Regressivity, Race, and Education.” Tax Bases over the Business Cycle.” Na- National Tax Journal 52 No. 4 (December, tional Tax Journal 49 No. 4 (December, 1996): 1999): 741–51. 535–52. Quiggin, John. Holcombe, Randall, and Russell Sobel. “On the Optimal Design of Lotteries.” Eco- Growth and Variability in State Tax Revenue. nomica 58 No. 1 (February, 1991): 1–16. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1997. Scott, Frank, and John Garen. Hymans, Saul H., and Harold T. Shapiro. “Probability of Purchase, Amount of Pur- “The Allocation of Household Income to chase, and the Demographic Incidence of Food Consumption.” Journal of Econometrics the Lottery Tax.” Journal of Public Economics 42 No. 2 (May, 1976): 167–88. 54 No. 1 (May, 1994): 121–43. Jackson, Raymond. Spindler, Charles. “Demand for Lottery Products in Massa- “The Lottery and Education: Robbing Peter chusetts.” Journal of Consumer Affairs 28 No. to Pay Paul?” Public Budgeting and Finance 2 (Winter, 1994): 313–25. 15 No. 3 (Fall, 1995): 54–62. Kearney, Melissa Schnettini. Stover, Mark. “State Lotteries and Consumer Behavior.” “Revenue Potential of State Lotteries.” Public Journal of Public Economics 89 Nos. 11–12 Finance Quarterly 15 No. 4 (October, 1987): (December, 2005): 2269–99. 428–40. Miksell, John. Tosun, Mehmet, and Mark Skidmore. “A Note on the Changing Incidence of State “Interstate Competition and State Lottery Lottery Finance.” Social Science Quarterly 70 Revenues.” National Tax Journal 57 No. 2 No. 2 (June, 1989): 513–21. (June, 2004): 163–78.

99