Estimation of Employee Stock Option Exercise Rates and Firm Cost⇤

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Estimation of Employee Stock Option Exercise Rates and Firm Cost⇤ Estimation of Employee Stock Option Exercise Rates and Firm Cost⇤ Jennifer N. Carpenter Richard Stanton Nancy Wallace New York University U.C. Berkeley U.C. Berkeley December 1, 2017 Abstract We develop the first empirical model of employee-stock-option exercise that is suitable for valu- ation and allows for behavioral channels in the determination of employee option cost. We estimate exercise rates as functions of option, stock and employee characteristics in a sample of all employee exercises at 89 firms. Increasing vesting date frequency from annual to monthly reduces option value by 10-16%. Men exercise faster than women, reducing option value by 2-4%. Top employees exercise more slowly than lower-ranked, increasing value by 2-10%. Finally, we develop an analytic valuation approximation that is much more accurate than methods used in practice. ⇤Financial support from the Fisher Center for Real Estate and Urban Economics and the Society of Actuaries is gratefully acknowledged. For helpful comments and suggestions, we thank Daniel Abrams, Terry Adamson, Xavier Gabaix, Wenxuan Hou, James Lecher, Kai Li, Ulrike Malmendier, Kevin Mur- phy, Terry Odean, Nicholas Reitter, Jun Yang, David Yermack, and seminar participants at Cheung Kong Graduate School of Business, Erasmus University, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Fudan University, Lancaster University, McGill University, New York University, The Ohio State University, Oxford Univer- sity, Peking University, Rice University, Securities and Exchange Commission, Shanghai Advanced Institute of Finance, Temple University, Tilburg University, Tsinghua University, and the 2017 Western Finance As- sociation meetings. We thank Terry Adamson at AON Consulting for providing some of the data used in this study. We also thank Xing Huang for valuable research assistance. Please direct correspondence to [email protected], [email protected], or [email protected]. 1 Introduction Employee stock options (ESOs) are a major component of corporate compensation and a material cost to firms. Murphy (2013) reports that options represented 21% of CEO pay in 2011, and the 2010 General Social Survey of the National Opinion Research Center found that 9.3 million employees hold options. As a fraction of outstanding shares of common stock, the median number of shares underlying outstanding options at S&P 1500 firms was 4.4% in 2010, with almost 1% of outstanding shares allocated to new option grants annually, according to Equilar (2011). At the same time, accounting valuation methods for ESOs significantly a↵ect corporate decisions about compensation structure and allocation, and thus a↵ect both employee incentives and firm cost. For example, the 2005 change in accounting valuation precipitated a decline in the granting of options from previous levels and an increase in the allocation to top managers.1 Valuation methods for employee stock options are therefore an important issue for investors. ESO valuation remains a challenge in practice, as illustrated by the recent controversy over the value of options granted to the CEO of IBM, in which Institutional Shareholder Services valued the options at more than twice the company’s valuation (see Melin, 2017). The valuation of these long-maturity American options is very sensitive to assumptions about how they will be exercised, and because employees face hedging constraints, standard option- exercise theory does not apply. For example, employees systematically exercise options on non-dividend-paying stocks well before expiration2 and this substantially reduces their cost to firms. The modifications to Black Scholes used to address this in practice are inadequate because they ignore key features of employee exercise patterns. At the same time, existing empirical descriptions of option-exercise behavior based on OLS or hazard rate models, such as Heath, Huddart, and Lang (1999), Armstrong, Jagolinzer, and Larcker (2007), and Klein and Maug (2011), are not appropriate as an input for option valuation. In this paper we develop the first empirical model of employee option exercise suitable for valuation and apply it in a sample of all employee exercises at 89 publicly traded firms from 1981 to 2009 to show empirically how employee exercise patterns a↵ect option cost to firms. We develop a GMM-based methodology that is robust to both heteroskedasticity and correlation across option exercises to estimate the rate of voluntary exercise as a function 1For example, Equilar (2011) reports that the median number of shares underlying outstanding options at S&P 1500 firms fell from 6.1% in 2006 to 4.4% in 2010, while the fraction of options allocated to CEOs and named executives rose from 21% to 26%. Murphy (2013) finds that as a fraction of total CEO pay, option compensation of 21% in 2011 is down from 53% in 2001. Other estimates of the fraction of CEO pay in the form of options include 33% in 1991 from Yermack (1995) and 25% in 2008 from Frydman and Jenter (2010). 2See, for example, Huddart and Lang (1996); Bettis, Bizjak, and Lemmon (2005). 1 of the stock price path and of firm, contract, and option-holder characteristics. We show that these characteristics significantly a↵ect exercise behavior, in a manner consistent with both portfolio theory and results from the behavioral literature, such as those in Barber and Odean (2001). We then value options using the the estimated exercise function and show how sensitive option values are to the exercise factors. For example, the passage of vesting dates triggers exercises, so vesting structure has a large impact on option value: Increasing vesting-date frequency from annual to monthly reduces option value by as much as 16% for typical option holders. In addition, men exercise options significantly faster than women, resulting in a 2-4% lower option value. Consistent with both standard option theory and utility-maximizing theory, the rate of voluntary option exercise is positively related to the level of the stock price and the imminence of a dividend. However, the exercise rate is also higher when the stock price is in the 90th percentile of its distribution over the past year, which may reflect behavioral e↵ects. We also proxy for employee portfolio e↵ects using the employee’s Black-Scholes option wealth and option risk, and we find that, consistent with theory, employees with greater wealth tend to exercise more slowly, and employees with greater risk tend to exercise faster. In contrast to the existing academic literature, our proprietary dataset contains all em- ployee exercises at a large number of firms.3 Since estimation of exercise behavior requires a large sample of stock price paths, and thus a large number of firms, our paper can investigate di↵erential option-exercise patterns and option cost across top and lower-ranked employees. We define top-ranked employees as those among the top ten option holders at a given firm. To the extent that options are granted where their performance incentives have greatest benefit, the top option holders within a firm are likely to be the key decision makers. Con- sistent with Bettis et al. (2005), Armstrong et al. (2007) and Klein and Maug (2011), we find that top-ten option holders exercise slower than lower-ranked holders within a given firm. Similarly, in a subsample with data on employee titles, senior executives tend to exercise at slower rates than lower-ranked employees. We then show that this pattern implies that the options of top employees are typically worth 2-10% more than those of lower-ranked employees. These results may stem from greater wealth among top employees, although we do try to control for this. Finally, our methodology permits us to test for di↵erential exercise factor e↵ects across top and lower-ranked employees. We find that top employees are less responsive to the passage of vesting dates and the passage of the stock price to a new high, but the gender e↵ect is more pronounced among top employees than among the lower-ranked. 3For example, the samples of Heath et al. (1999) and Armstrong et al. (2007) contain only seven and ten firms, respectively, while the sample of Klein and Maug (2011) contains only top executives. 2 We compare option values calculated using the empirically estimated exercise function with option valuations based on methods used in practice. While FAS 123R outlines a range of potentially acceptable methods, the vast majority of firms use one of two Black- Scholes-based approximations with a downward adjustment to the option’s expiration date to account for early exercise. The SEC’s Sta↵Accounting Bulletin (SAB) 110 permits firms with limited exercise data to use the Black-Scholes formula with the stated expiration date replaced by the average of the vesting date and stated expiration date. This adjustment is simple to make, and does much better than the traditional Black-Scholes formula, but it takes no account of the stock return and employee characteristics that a↵ect exercise patterns and the approximation errors can be quite large. The modified Black-Scholes method permitted by FAS 123R replaces the option’s stated expiration date with the option’s expected term. Unfortunately, this expected term must be estimated from historical firm data on option outcomes, and can entail significant error, since option outcomes depend on a firm’s stock price path and a given firm has option data based only on its own realized stock price path. We show, moreover, that even in the hypothetical ideal case where the option’s expected term is estimated perfectly, this method creates systematic biases. In particular, we calculate the option’s expected term exactly from the estimated exercise function to get the Modified Black Scholes value and show that the approximation error still varies widely and systematically with firm characteristics. Finally, recognizing the practical appeal of a Black-Scholes-based approximation, we develop an analytic approximation of the implied Black-Scholes maturity, which, when used as the expiration date in the Black-Scholes formula, delivers option values that much more closely approximate the correct option value than the existing methods.
Recommended publications
  • Valuation of Stock Options
    VALUATION OF STOCK OPTIONS The right to buy or sell a given security at a specified time in the future is an option. Options are “derivatives’, i.e. they derive their value from the security that is to be traded in accordance with the option. Determining the value of publicly traded stock options is not a problem as the market sets the price. The value of a non-publicly traded option, however, depends on a number of factors: the price of the underlying security at the time of valuation, the time to exercise the option, the volatility of the underlying security, the risk free interest rate, the dividend rate, and the strike price. In addition to these financial variables, subjective variables also play a role. For example, in the case of employee stock options, the employee and the employer have different reasons for valuation, and, therefore, differing needs result in a different valuation for each party. This appendix discusses the reasons for the valuation of non-publicly traded options, explores and compares the two predominant valuation models, and attempts to identify the appropriate valuation methods for a variety of situations. We do not attempt to explain option-pricing theory in depth nor do we attempt mathematical proofs of the models. We focus on the practical aspects of option valuation, directing the reader to the location of computer calculators and sources of the data needed to enter into those calculators. Why Value? The need for valuation arises in a variety of circumstances. In the valuation of a business, for example, options owned by that business must be valued like any other investment asset.
    [Show full text]
  • Stock Options and Credit Default Swaps in Risk Management
    Stock Options and Credit Default Swaps in Risk Management Bassam Al-Own Faculty of Finance and Business Administration Al al-Bayt University Mafraq 25113, Jordan Email: [email protected] Marizah Minhat* The Business School Edinburgh Napier University Edinburgh EH14 1DJ, United Kingdom Email: [email protected] Simon Gao The Business School Edinburgh Napier University Edinburgh EH14 1DJ, United Kingdom Email: [email protected] Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money (forthcoming) * Corresponding author. Acknowledgement: This paper was presented at the 2016 Cross Country Perspectives of Finance conferences held in Taiyuan and Pu’er, China. The authors would like to thank Professor Gady Jacoby, Professor Zhenyu Wu, anonymous reviewers, and the conferences’ participants. i Stock Options and Credit Default Swaps in Risk Management 1 ABSTRACT The use of stock options and credit default swaps (CDS) in banks is not uncommon. Stock options can induce risk-taking incentives, while CDS can be used to hedge against credit risk. Building on the existing literature on executive compensation and risk management, our study contributes novel empirical support for the role of stock options in restraining the use of CDS for hedging purposes. Based on data of CEO stock options and CDS held by 60 European banks during the period 2006-2011, we find a negative relationship between option-induced risk- taking incentives (vega) and the proportion of CDS held for hedging. However, the extent of CDS held for hedging is found to be positively related to default risk in the period leading to the financial crisis that erupted in 2007.
    [Show full text]
  • Should We Expense Stock Options
    Options Pricing and Accounting Practice Charles W. Calomiris American Enterprise Institute R. Glenn Hubbard Columbia University and the National Bureau of Economic Research AEI WORKING PAPER #103, JANUARY 8, 2004 www.aei.org/workingpapers www.aei.org/publication20882 #17198 I. Introduction In the wake of the recent corporate scandals that have damaged investor confidence, policymakers, academics, and pundits have taken aim at accounting rules as one of the areas in need of reform. Proposals for changing the rules governing the accounting for the granting of stock options has become one of the most hotly contested areas. Advocates of reform argue that options are a form of compensation and that granting options entails real costs to stockholders. They argue that it follows that options should be included as an expense item in the firm’s financial statements. In this article, we consider the potential benefits and costs of requiring the expensing options. First, we show that the potential benefits of developing rules for expensing options would be small, even if the valuation of the options were straightforward. Second, we review practical problems that make it extremely difficult to create a set of accounting conventions that would properly value the options. We conclude that the establishment of new accounting rules for expensing options would likely do more harm than good. II. How Big Are Potential Gains from Establishing a Standard for Expensing Options? At the outset, it may be useful to review the purpose of regulating accounting conventions and to distinguish that regulation from the regulation of the disclosure of information. Financial economists typically argue for the irrelevance of accounting measures of earnings for the purpose of valuing stock prices.
    [Show full text]
  • Employee Stock Options: Tax Treatment and Tax Issues
    Employee Stock Options: Tax Treatment and Tax Issues James M. Bickley Specialist in Public Finance June 15, 2012 Congressional Research Service 7-5700 www.crs.gov RL31458 CRS Report for Congress Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress Employee Stock Options: Tax Treatment and Tax Issues Summary The practice of granting a company’s employees options to purchase the company’s stock has become widespread among American businesses. Employee stock options have been praised as innovative compensation plans that help align the interests of the employees with those of the shareholders. They have also been condemned as schemes to enrich insiders and avoid company taxes. The tax code recognizes two general types of employee options, “qualified” and nonqualified. Qualified (or “statutory”) options include “incentive stock options,” which are limited to $100,000 a year for any one employee, and “employee stock purchase plans,” which are limited to $25,000 a year for any employee. Employee stock purchase plans must be offered to all full- time employees with at least two years of service; incentive stock options may be confined to officers and highly paid employees. Qualified options are not taxed to the employee when granted or exercised (under the regular tax); tax is imposed only when the stock is sold. If the stock is held one year from purchase and two years from the granting of the option, the gain is taxed as long-term capital gain. The employer is not allowed a deduction for these options. However, if the stock is not held the required time, the employee is taxed at ordinary income tax rates and the employer is allowed a deduction.
    [Show full text]
  • Employee Stock Option Valuation with an Early Exercise Boundary
    Employee Stock Option Valuation with an Early Exercise Boundary Neil Brisley, University of Western Ontario Chris K. Anderson, Cornell University Many companies are recognizing that the Black-Scholes formula is inappropriate for employee stock options (ESOs) and are moving toward lattice models for accounting or decision-making purposes. In the most influential of these models, the assumption is that employees exercise voluntarily when the stock price reaches a fixed multiple of the strike price, effectively introducing a "horizontal" exercise boundary into the lattice. In practice, however, employees make a trade-off between intrinsic value captured and the opportunity cost of time value forgone. The model proposed here explicitly recognizes and accounts for this reality and is intuitively appealing, easily implemented, and compliant with U.S. accounting standards. Another assumption that Lehman made in valuing Mr. Fuld's pay in 2000 was that he would exercise the options two and a half years after receiving them. But Mr. Fuld had a history of holding onto his options until they were about to expire. Indeed, all 2.6 million options that Mr. Fuld has exercised since November 2003 were in the last year of their life when he did so. —Patrick McGeehan (2006) The need to value employee stock options (ESOs) for accounting and economic purposes makes the modeling of employee early exercise behavior relevant for corporate financial officers, security analysts, and those involved in determining option awards. Early exercise by employees reduces the cost of the ESO to the company in relation to an otherwise identical European option (which can be exercised only at the end of its life), so ESO-pricing models must make assumptions to describe in what circumstances an employee will exercise an option before expiration.
    [Show full text]
  • The Effect of Employee Stock Options on Bank Investment Choice, Borrowing, and Capital
    Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports The Effect of Employee Stock Options on Bank Investment Choice, Borrowing, and Capital Hamid Mehran Joshua Rosenberg Staff Report no. 305 October 2007 Revised June 2008 This paper presents preliminary findings and is being distributed to economists and other interested readers solely to stimulate discussion and elicit comments. The views expressed in the paper are those of the authors and are not necessarily reflective of views at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors. The Effect of Employee Stock Options on Bank Investment Choice, Borrowing, and Capital Hamid Mehran and Joshua Rosenberg Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, no. 305 October 2007; revised June 2008 JEL classification: G21, G28, G32, J33, M41 Abstract In this paper, we assess the effects of CEO stock options on three key corporate policies for banks: investment choice, amount of borrowing, and level of capital. Using a sample of 549 bank-years for publicly traded banks from 1992 to 2002, we find that stock option grants lead CEOs to undertake riskier investments. In particular, higher levels of option grants are associated with higher levels of equity and asset volatility. Consistent with the role of options as a nondebt tax shield, we also show that option grants reduce the banks’ incentive to borrow as evidenced by lower levels of interest expense and federal funds borrowing. Furthermore, we demonstrate that increases in CEO and employee stock option grants result in increased bank capital levels, perhaps because option grants create a contingent liability for the firm that needs to be funded in advance.
    [Show full text]
  • CONTANGO ORE, INC. (Exact Name of Registrant As Specified in Its Charter)
    UNITED STATES SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION Washington, D.C. 20549 FORM 10-Q ☒ QUARTERLY REPORT PURSUANT TO SECTION 13 OR 15(d) OF THE SECURITIES EXCHANGE ACT OF 1934 For the quarterly period ended September 30, 2020 OR ☐ TRANSITION REPORT PURSUANT TO SECTION 13 OR 15(d) OF THE SECURITIES EXCHANGE ACT OF 1934 For the transition period from to Commission file number 001-35770 CONTANGO ORE, INC. (Exact name of registrant as specified in its charter) DELAWARE 27-3431051 (I.R.S. Employer (State or other jurisdiction of incorporation or organization) Identification No.) 3700 BUFFALO SPEEDWAY, SUITE 925 HOUSTON, TEXAS 77098 (Address of principal executive offices) (Zip code) (713) 877-1311 (Registrant’s telephone number, including area code) Securities registered pursuant to Section 12(b) of the Act: Title of each class Trading Symbol(s) Name of each exchange on which registered Common Stock, Par Value $0.01 per share CTGO OTCQB Indicate by check mark whether the registrant (1) has filed all reports required to be filed by Section 13 or 15(d) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 during the preceding 12 months (or for such shorter period that the registrant was required to file such reports), and (2) has been subject to such filing requirements for the past 90 days. Yes ☒ No ☐ Indicate by check mark whether the registrant has submitted electronically every Interactive Data File required to be submitted pursuant to Rule 405 of Regulation S-T (§ 232.405 of this chapter) during the preceding 12 months (or for such shorter period that the registrant was required to submit such files).
    [Show full text]
  • Accounting for Employee Stock Options Eyewire/Gettyimages
    CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES CONGRESSIONAL BUDGET OFFICE A CBO PAPER APRIL 2004 Accounting for Employee Stock Options Eyewire/GettyImages A CBO PAPER Accounting for Employee Stock Options April 2004 The Congress of the United States O Congressional Budget Office Preface In March 2003, the Financial Accounting Standards Board (FASB) began reconsidering the accounting standard for equity-based compensation. The accounting board released an expo- sure draft for a revised standard on March 31, 2004. That revised standard would require firms to recognize the fair value of employee stock options as an expense, as was first proposed by FASB more than 10 years ago. This Congressional Budget Office (CBO) paper assesses whether, under the current account- ing standard, firms that grant employee stock options without recognizing an expense over- state their reported income. The paper presents the relevant issues, describes the current standard for employee stock options, compares the intrinsic value and fair value methods of measurement, and weighs the potential economic effects of revising the current standard. The report was prepared at the request of Congressman Brad Sherman in his capacity as a member of the House Committee on Financial Services. Judith S. Ruud of CBO’s Microeconomic and Financial Studies Division prepared the paper under the direction of Roger Hitchner and Marvin Phaup. Early investigation of the subject was conducted by Douglas Gruener, a summer intern at CBO. George J. Benston of Emory University and Deborah Lucas of Northwestern University reviewed a draft of the paper and provided valuable suggestions. Wendy Kiska, Angelo Mascaro, David Torregrosa, Philip Webre, and Thomas Woodward, all of CBO, also provided helpful comments.
    [Show full text]
  • Employee Stock Options: Tax Treatment and Tax Issues
    Employee Stock Options: Tax Treatment and Tax Issues James M. Bickley Specialist in Public Finance June 15, 2012 Congressional Research Service 7-5700 www.crs.gov RL31458 CRS Report for Congress Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress Employee Stock Options: Tax Treatment and Tax Issues Summary The practice of granting a company’s employees options to purchase the company’s stock has become widespread among American businesses. Employee stock options have been praised as innovative compensation plans that help align the interests of the employees with those of the shareholders. They have also been condemned as schemes to enrich insiders and avoid company taxes. The tax code recognizes two general types of employee options, “qualified” and nonqualified. Qualified (or “statutory”) options include “incentive stock options,” which are limited to $100,000 a year for any one employee, and “employee stock purchase plans,” which are limited to $25,000 a year for any employee. Employee stock purchase plans must be offered to all full- time employees with at least two years of service; incentive stock options may be confined to officers and highly paid employees. Qualified options are not taxed to the employee when granted or exercised (under the regular tax); tax is imposed only when the stock is sold. If the stock is held one year from purchase and two years from the granting of the option, the gain is taxed as long-term capital gain. The employer is not allowed a deduction for these options. However, if the stock is not held the required time, the employee is taxed at ordinary income tax rates and the employer is allowed a deduction.
    [Show full text]
  • Fall 2006 VOLUME 12:3
    Fall 2006 VOLUME 12:3 PDV OBSERVATIONS A Quarterly Newsletter for PDV Clients and Friends Share Repurchase Programs By Che H. Lee President Every potential equity investment has both positive and negative attributes. Our job at PDV is to balance these attrib- utes against each other and compare the net overall result to the investment’s prevailing market price to determine valuation. As stock price and business value tend to converge over time, undervalued situations offer potential gains for clients. A company buying back its own shares is almost universally portrayed as a positive investment attribute. But are all stock buy-back programs categorically good? The common perception is that they are because buy-backs reduce the number of shares outstanding. Consider the following illustrative example. Firm A has one million shares outstanding, and generates reported net earnings of $10 million, which equates to $10 per share. Now, assume that Firm A buys back 100,000 shares of its own stock, leaving only 900,000 shares outstanding. Since the amount of reported net income remains at $10 million, this now equates to $11.11 per share of reported net earnings. For each share you own, a higher level of reported net earnings “belongs” to you, as part owner of the company, after the buy-back. Since it is commonly accepted that stock prices over time tend to follow the trend of reported net earnings per share, the common perception is that you have benefited from the buy-back. Unfortunately, the foregoing calculations ignore two critical components of the buy-back equation: 1) the cost of what you gave up to implement the buy-back, and 2) the prospective return from the buy-back.
    [Show full text]
  • To Expense Or Not to Expense Employee Stock Options: the Market Reaction
    To Expense or not to Expense Employee Stock Options: The Market Reaction by Fayez A. Elayan Brock University Kuntara Pukthuanthong San Diego State University Richard Roll Compensation Valuation, Inc. and UCLA Authors’ Coordinates Elayan Pukthuanthong Roll Department of Accounting College of Business Administration The Anderson School at UCLA College of Business Administration San Diego State University 110 Westwood Plaza Address Brock University 5500 Campanile Drive Los Angeles, CA St. Catherines, Ontario San Diego, CA 90095-1481, USA L2S 3A1, Canada 92182-8236, USA Voice 1-905-937-8543 1-619-594-5690 1-310-825-6118 E-Mail [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] Fifth draft: July 2004 To Expense or not to Expense Employee Stock Options: The Market Reaction Abstract During 2002 and 2003, 140 publicly traded U.S. firms announced their intention to recognize an accounting expense when stock options are granted to employees. Many similar firms elected not to expense options. We study the stock market’s reaction. There is no evidence whatsoever that expensing options reduces the stock price. To the contrary, around announcement dates, we find significant price increases for firms electing to expense options and significant price declines for industry/size/performance-matched firms that did not announce expensing at the same moment. The average relative change in market values is 3.65% during a six-day window around the announcement. The magnitude of the market’s reaction to expensing depends on agency costs, the magnitude of option expenses, and financial reporting costs. The market’s reaction does not seem to be affected by contracting costs (e.g., induced by debt covenants), growth opportunities, or potential political repercussions.
    [Show full text]
  • Employee Stock Option Exercise, Equity Award, and Equity Award Center® Agreement Page 1 of 3
    Employee Stock Option Exercise, Equity Award, and Equity Award Center® Agreement Page 1 of 3 1-800-654-2593 This is your agreement with Schwab regarding the use of Schwab’s brokerage services to exercise your employee stock options and equity awards. These important terms and conditions also apply to your equity award center account (“Equity Award Center Account”) with Charles Schwab & Co., Inc. (“Schwab”) for activity related to your employee stock options or other equity compensation grants. These terms are in addition to the Schwab One® Account Agreement and other agreements between you and Schwab. The company name you enter below will be referred to as the “Issuing Company” throughout the remainder of this document. This includes your employer and any spun-off subsidiary, affiliate, or future employer. The Issuing Company that granted the options may also require you to complete (an) internal company form(s) before you can exercise your options. Terms and conditions specifically related to employee stock option plans (“Employee Stock Option Plans”) are provided in Section A; terms and conditions related to employee stock purchase plans, restricted stock award/unit plans, and other equity compensation plans resulting in share positions are provided in Section B. This Agreement is not a substitute for your company’s internal form(s). Please contact your company’s Stock Plan Administrator or Schwab Stock Plan Services at 1-800-654-2593 about your company’s internal form requirements. Please complete, sign, and return this Agreement to: Schwab Stock Plan Services, Charles Schwab, P.O. Box 982602, El Paso, TX 79998-2602.
    [Show full text]