<<

EJRR 1|2015 Symposium on Evaluation in the EU 1

Impact Assessment in the European Union: Lessons from a Research Project* Claire A. Dunlop and Claudio M. Radaelli**

In this article, we present some major lessons drawn from a recently completed research project. Our research dealt with ex-ante evaluation, mainly impact assessment (IA). We shed new light on research questions about the control of bureaucracy, the role of IA in decision- making, economics and policy learning, and the narrative dimension of appraisal. We iden- tify how our findings stand in relation to conventional arguments about these issues, and reflect on their normative implications. We finally reason on the possible extensions of our arguments to the wider field of policy evaluation, connecting IA and ex-post evaluation.

In the late 1990s, the rare studies of ex-ante policy is in synch with the Organisation for Economic Co- evaluation found it difficult to report on any concrete operation and Development (OECD). The OECD has development within the European Commission out- recently adopted an integrated framework for policy side financial planning and the structural funds. Take evaluation5 where several concepts and even indica- for example Pelkmans, Labory, Majone1 who were tors developed in the practice of ex-ante assessment unable to report on the number of fiches d’impact are transferred to ex-post analysis, with the aim of (the instrument used at the time to appraise the like- encouraging a common evaluative approach to reg- ly effects of policy proposals of the Commission), ulation and more generally. what they contained, and who was using them. But This reflects the of attention in regulatory today this topic has gained a stable place on the re- evaluation: in the 1990s, only a few Member States search agenda of social scientists, for example in po- were pushing a reluctant Commission to activate sys- litical science2 and .3 As Smismans’ notes in the tematic for the integrated appraisal of EU introduction to this volume,4 nowadays research on legislation, be it ex-ante or ex-post. These years wit- ex-ante policy appraisal falls within the wider field nessed the of the concepts of business im- of policy evaluation, broadly defined to cover the pact assessment, compliance cost measurement, and whole policy cycle – from ex-ante analysis to ex-post better law-making, but there was no integrated re- appraisal. On this core idea, the European Union (EU) sponse from the EU institutions.6 Radaelli reviewed

* The article arises out of original research funded by the European Appraisal: Biofuels Policy in the UK”, 43 Policy Sciences (2010), Research Council (ERC) project Analysis of Learning in Regulatory pp. 343 et sqq.; Claire A Dunlop, Oliver Fritsch and Claudio M (ALREG), see: http://socialsciences.exeter.ac.uk/ Radaelli, “The Appraisal of Policy Appraisal – Learning About politics/research/centres/ceg/ (#230267). We thank Christie Smith Impact Assessment”, 149 Revue Française D'Administration for all her help in formatting the and the editor of this Publique (2014), pp. 163 et sqq.; John Turnpenny, Måns Nilsson, special issue and two anonymous referees for their insightful Duncan Russel et al., “The policy and politics of policy appraisal: comments made on earlier drafts of the work. The usual dis- Emerging trends and new directions", 16 Journal of European claimer applies. (2009), pp. 640 et sqq. ** Claire A. Dunlop, University of Exeter, UK and Claudio M. 3 Anne CM Meuwese and Stijn van Voorst, “Impact Assessment in Radaelli, University of Exeter, UK. Legal Studies”, in Claire A Dunlop and Claudio M Radaelli (eds.), Handbook of Regulatory Impact Assessment, (Cheltenham: 1 Jacques Pelkmans, Sandrine Labory S and Giandomenico Ma- Edward Elgar, forthcoming). jone, “Better EU regulatory quality: Assessing current initiatives and new proposals”, in Giampaolo Galli and Jacques Pelkmans 4 Stijn Smismans, “Introduction to this volume”, European Journal (eds.), Regulatory Reform and Competitiveness in , Volume of Risk (2015), this issue. 1: Horizontal Issues (Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2000), pp. 461 et 5 OECD, Framework for Regulatory Policy Evaluation, (Paris: OECD sqq. Publications, 2014); see Anne CM Meuwese, Michiel Scheltema and Lynn van der Velden, “The OECD Framework for Regulatory 2 Camilla Adelle, Andrew Jordan and John Turnpenny, “Proceeding Policy Evaluation: an initial assessment”, European Journal of Risk in Parallel or Drifting apart? A Systematic Review of Policy Ap- Regulation, this issue. praisal Research and Practices”, 30 Environment and Planning C: and Policy (2012), pp. 401 et sqq.; Claire A Dunlop, 6 Julie Froud, Rebecca Boden, Anthony Ogus et al., Controlling the “The Temporal Dimension of Knowledge and the Limits of Policy Regulators, (Basingstoke, Hampshire: Macmillan, 1998). 2 Symposium on Policy Evaluation in the EU EJRR 1|2015

in 1999 the initiatives for ex-ante evaluation of poli- reader can find and data therein – and con- cy proposals (excluding structural funds and finan- centrate on the conceptual lessons. In the remainder, cial planning) and concluded that the various pilot our main concern is the EU level, but when neces- initiatives with policy instruments had not produced sary we add observations on the situation is the Mem- an integrated template and a coherent instrumenta- ber States, since the two levels co-exist and interact. tion – much ado about nothing.7 In the conclusions we elaborate on the implications Now there is a full range of initiatives for policy of our lessons for a critical research agenda in this evaluation in the so-called smart regulation agenda field14 and for our wider theoretical understanding of the EU and in the Member States. This evaluation of the politics of bureaucracy, learning and diffusion turn has affected policy-makers’ understandings of of policy instruments. the nature of EU law and its role in larger architec- tures for integrating policy and law, as shown by Smismans.8 Even the language and the labels used I. What is impact assessment for? by policy-makers accompany this rise in attention – alongside the by-now traditional impact assessment 1. Control instrument, tool of bureaucratic of legislative and non-legislative proposals of the Eu- empowerment or just a symbol? ropean Commission, we see an emerging policy agen- da concerned with ex-post evaluation and post-im- At the outset, any appraisal of the experience with plementation review, including projects to re-fit Eu- IA and smart regulation in the EU has to start with ropean legislation to changing structural conditions9 a theoretical proposition about the rationale for pol- and carry out ex-post evaluations.10 The attention for icy adoption.15 This rationale lies in the- the problems created by administrative obligations ory. The original intuition by McCubbins, Noll and has remained high since 2004, with several ‘wars’ on Weingast16 was that by saddling United States (US) red tape endorsed by successive EU presidencies, the Commission, and stakeholders.11 All this activity is supposed to connect with the more established tra- 7 Claudio M Radaelli, "Steering the Community regulatory system: the challenges ahead", 77 (1999), pp. 855 dition of evaluation of expenditure programmes, to et sqq. create a coherent evaluation culture across EU insti- 8 Stijn Sismans, “From Harmonization to Co-ordination? EU Law in tutions – this, at least, is the stated aim of the Com- the Lisbon Governance Architecture", 18 Journal of European Public Policy (2011), pp. 504 et sqq. mission. 9 Commission Communication on the Regulatory fitness and In short, a neglected issue has become familiar ter- performance programme (REFIT): of play and outlook, ritory for researchers and policy-makers. The year COM(2014)368. 2002 signals the moment when the Commission took 10 Commission Communication on Strengthening the foundations of Smart Regulation – improving evaluation, Communication, the commitment to use a single integrated template COM(2013)686. (Impact Assessment, IA) to evaluate new proposals 11 Paola Coletti, Evidence for Public Policy Design: How to Learn (beyond what was already done for expenditure pro- from Best Practice, (Basingstoke: Palgrave, 2013). 12 Commission Communication on Impact assessment, grammes), to implement common standards for con- COM(2002)276; Commission Communication Towards a rein- sultation, and to articulate an action plan for better forced culture of consultation and dialogue. General principles 12 and minimum standards for consultation of interested parties by regulation. After almost fifteen years, researchers the Commission, COM(2002)704; Commission Communication have sufficient evidence to review the experience Action plan: Simplifying and improving the regulatory environ- ment, COM(2002)278. with ex-ante evaluation and IA in particular. We un- 13 Details available on the internet at http://socialsciences.exeter.ac dertake this task by drawing lessons from a four-year .uk/politics/research/centres/ceg/research/projects/alreg/. project on Analysis of Learning in Regulatory Gover- 14 See John Turnpenny, Claudio M Radaelli, Andrew Jordan et al., 13 "The policy and politics of policy appraisal: Emerging trends and nance, funded by the European Research Council. new directions", 16 Journal of European Public Policy (2009), In this contribution, we focus on some important pp. 640 et sqq. conceptual findings rather than data on individual 15 Fabrizio De Francesco, Transnational Policy Innovation: The OECD and the Diffusion of Regulatory Impact Analysi, (Colch- policy instruments or episodes to contribute to the ester: ECPR Press, 2013). research questions on policy evaluations that inform 16 Mathew D McCubbins, Roger G Noll and Barry R Weingast, our special issue. Consequently, we will draw on a "Administrative procedures as instruments of political control", 3 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization (1989), pp. 243 et number of articles produced within ALREG – the sqq. EJRR 1|2015 Symposium on Policy Evaluation in the EU 3

agencies with formal obligations to carry out and gument in Europe, the findings have been less sup- publish regulatory analysis, information asymmetry portive of the control thesis. IA can be quite blunt as would be reduced, taking the informational advan- instrument of control of the Commission – and, turn- tage away from the agency. Ex-post evaluation fol- ing to the domestic level, in some Member States like lowsasimilarcontrolrationale,althoughtointervene Denmark and Sweden there isn’t evidence for the on an agency when the policy programme is evalu- classic manifestations of bureaucratic control.22 In ated may be too late. Early warnings via administra- another ALREG paper, Radaelli and Meuwese23 con- tive procedures during the drafting process, in con- clude that IA has increased capacity for operational trast, are effective because they capture an agency’s and strategic within the Commission, deviation ‘prior to the agency’s implementation of a thus effectively empowering the bureaucracy, rather change in policy’.17 Damonte, Dunlop and Radaelli18 than controlling it. Other projects have shown that generalise this argument to all instruments based on IA in some EU Member States has symbolic proper- a fire-alarm logic: regulatory analysis is a fire alarm ties – a veneer of rationality on a thick web of infor- instrument that affected interests can pull at an ear- mal decision-making procedures and policy formu- ly stage when a regulatory proposal damages them. lation conventions, hardly affected by the formal re- IA enfranchises these interests and gives a voice to quirements of ex-ante appraisal.24 For some Member affected industries, constituencies of support for the States, the issue is most likely the absence of analyt- elected politicians, and experts like economists, so icalandinstitutionalcapacity.25 Withoutcapacity,the that bureaucratic drift is limited.19 whole idea of using detailed information to control Indeed, much of the US literature on IA stems bureaucracies via fire-alarm instruments cannot pos- from this rationale, with questions on the nature of sible work. control exercised by the Office for Information and All this leads us to conclude that we might have Regulatory Analysis (OIRA) on federal been inspired by the wrong theory: control may be agencies.20 Other US projects have looked at the dif- a correct lens for the US, but in Europe either there ferent ways in which bureaucratic control can be ef- is little capacity to control, or, simply, control is not fectively exercised by pressure groups.21 the main effect of implementation. Arguably, bureau- Briefly, it has become customary to think of eval- cracies like the Commission are empowered by IA, uation, especially in IA, as policy instrument for the whilst national bureaucracies use IA as signal and control of bureaucracy. The Commission being a bu- symbol when they do not have analytical capacity to reaucracy, the extension to the European case seems manage this policy instrument. Normatively, the em- straightforward. But, is it? Indeed, when our team powerment effect may or may not be desirable. It is probed the different implications of the control ar- desirable if we think that accountability in multi-lev-

17 Ibid., at p. 481, emphasis in original; David Epstein and Sharyn making”, 16 Journal of Public Administration Research and Theo- O'Halloran, "Asymmetric Information, Delegation, and the Struc- ry (2006), pp. 103 et sqq. ture of Policy-making", 11 Journal of Theoretical Politics (1999), 22 Claudio M Radaelli, "Rationality, Power, Management and Sym- pp. 37 et sqq. bols: Four Images of Regulatory Impact Assessment", 33 Scandi- 18 Alessia Damonte, Claire A Dunlop and Claudio M Radaelli, navian Political Studies, (2010), pp. 164 et sqq.; on ex-ante “Controlling bureaucracies with fire alarms: policy instruments appraisal in the domain of sustainable development see Duncan and cross-country patterns’, 21 Journal of European Public Policy Russel and John Turnpenny, "The politics of sustainable develop- (2014), p. 1330 et sqq. ment in UK government: what role for integrated policy ap- praisal?", 27 Environment and Planning C: Government and 19 See ibid, for the full-length explanation. Policy (2009), pp. 340 et sqq. 20 Steven Croley, "White house review of agency : An 23 Claudio M Radaelli and Anne CM Meuwese, "Hard Questions, empirical investigation", 70 University of Chicago Law Review Hard Solutions: Proceduralisation through Impact Assessment in (2003), p. 821 et sqq,; Winston Harrington, Lisa Heinzerling and the EU", 33 West European Politics (2010), pp. 136 et sqq. Richard D Morgenstern (eds.), Reforming Regulatory Impact Analysis, (Washington DC: Resources for the Future, 2009); 24 Julia Hertin, Andrew Jordan, John Turnpenny et al., "Rationalising Stuart Shapiro, "Evaluating the benefits and costs of regulatory the policy mess? Ex ante policy assessment and the utilisation of reforms: What questions need to be asked?", 31 Evaluation and knowledge in the policy process", 41 Environment and Planning Program Planning (2008), p. 223 et sqq.; William F West, "The A (2009), pp. 1185 et sqq.; Turnpenny et al., "Policy and politics institutionalization of regulatory review: Organizational stability of policy appraisal", supra note 14, at p. 5. and responsive competence at OIRA", 35 Presidential Studies 25 John Turnpenny, Måns Nilsson, Duncan Russel et al., "Why Is Quarterly (2005), p. 76 et sqq. Integrating Policy Assessment So Hard? A Comparative Analysis 21 Susan Webb Yackee, “Sweet-Talking the Fourth Branch: the of the Institutional Capacities and Constraints", 51 Journal of Influence of Interest Group Comments on Federal Agency Rule- Environmental Planning and Management (2008), pp. 759 et sqq. 4 Symposium on Policy Evaluation in the EU EJRR 1|2015

el systems needs high bureaucratic capacity rather cisional value of IA has captured the attention of pol- than weak bureaucratic organisations. It is not desir- icy-makers. This is the reason why stakeholders able if we think that an empowered European Com- lament that very few IAs conclude with a rejection mission can make regulatory trade-offs disguised as of a possible policy intervention by the Commission. technical management rather than discussed in The average IA does not challenge the ‘priors’ of the terms of constitutional values – an issue that is ex- Commission – this is the polemical claim – but sup- plored in Radaelli and Meuwese.26 ports them. The European Parliament in the Niebler report29 complained that there is insufficient over- sight of the IAs of the Commission. This is because 2. An instrument for decision-making the oversight body (the Impact Assessment Board) is processes? made up of high-level Commission officers and is staffed by the Secretariat General – indeed the Junck- A second finding we wish to discuss concerns the role er Commission signalled its intention to open up the of IA in decision-making processes. The guidelines board to external expertise.30 Overall, these critical on IA published by the member states and the Com- opinions claim that the IA ought to be a strong tool missionpresentIAasex-anteevaluationtoolthatsup- for decision-making, but in the real world it may be ports the decision-making process. In a recent reso- used exclusively to support a given policy choice. lution, the European Parliament27 reiterated this po- Empirical evidence sheds different light on the de- sition arguing it is “convinced that IAs are an impor- cisional value of IA. Ex-ante evaluation is not neces- tant means of supporting the decision-making in all sarily used to ‘speak the truth to power’ – shown the EU institutions and an important part of the better case studies in Meuwese’s project.31 In our project, regulation process; recognises, nevertheless, that IAs we found that the IA is not a decisional tool, but its cannot be substitutes for political evaluation and de- role can be to lay out the evidence-based case for a cisions”. Put differently, IA should assist the final de- certain policy preference of the Commission.32 This cision on a proposal – that is, the decision taken by preference is not necessarily the output of IA. It can the College of the Commission, but also decisions be pre-defined, or it can come out of last minute dis- concerning substantive amendments to draft legisla- cussions within the College. And yet, IA still im- tion introduced by the EP and the Council. The Eu- proves policy choice – even if it does not identify ropean Parliament lamented that the scope of IA may what this choice should be. The improvement con- no longer mirror the proposals adopted when these sists of empirical analyses of the effects of the choice, proposals are altered at a final stage once submitted on how the chosen option can be modulated across for approval by the College. The EP therefore request- time and sectors, and on the deeper consideration of ed in its resolution “that the IA should be updated to ensure continuity between matters considered in it 26 Claudio M Radaelli and Anne CM Meuwese, “How the regulatory and any proposals finally adopted by the Commis- state differs. The constitutional dimensions of rulemaking in the sion”.28 The relationship with decision-making is European Union and the United States”, XLII Rivista Italiana di slightly ambiguous, because to update an IA, in prac- Scienza Politica (2012), pp. 177 et sqq. 27 European Parliament Motion for a Resolution on the Revision of the tice, may mean to retrofit ex-ante evaluation to match Commission’s impact assessment guidelines (2014), point 6, avail- the political decision taken by the College – as well able on the internet at: http://www.europarl.europa.eu/sides/getDoc .do?type=MOTION&reference=P8-RC-2014-0311&language=EN. as the more benign but arguably unrealistic interpre- 28 Ibid., point 8. tation of carrying out new analysis to check if the fi- 29 European Parliament Report on Guaranteeing Independent nal political decision still delivers net benefits. Impact Assessments, Committee on Legal Affairs A7-0159/2011. The College of Commissioners is not supposed to 30 See European Commission Press Release “President Juncker appoints Dr Edmund Stoiber Special Adviser for Better Regula- react mechanically to the conclusions of an IA, and tion; First Vice-President Timmermans announces reform of the reject or support a proposal automatically. The same Impact Assessment Board”, available on the internet at http:// europa.eu/rapid/press-release_IP-14-2761_en.htm. principle applies to the EP and the Council when sub- 31 Anne CM Meuwese, Impact Assessment in EU , (The stantive amendments are introduced. But neither are Hague: Kluwer Law International, 2008). Commissioners,MEPsandCouncilofficerssupposed 32 Claire A Dunlop, Martino Magetti, Claudio M Radaelli, et al., to simply take note of the IA and treat it as one of "The many uses of regulatory impact assessment: A meta-analysis of EU and UK cases", 6 Regulation & Governance (2012), pp. 23 the many inputs to decision-making. In short, the de- et sqq. EJRR 1|2015 Symposium on Policy Evaluation in the EU 5

administrative compliance costs and implementa- Commission’s decisional process that seem empiri- tion problems. Consultation reveals new issues to be cally important. Consider the following. Within the taken on board. Commission, the preparation of IAs has made poli- Importantly, the process of carrying out an IA cy formulation more complicated than before. The obliges the Commission to give empirical and con- IA steering groups of the Commission include all the ceptual reasons for policy choice – whether the Com- Directorates General affected by a proposal plus the mission would have gone for the same choice with Secretariat General with a co-ordination role. IA as our without IA is not the fundamental issue. process has brought more actors into the process of Indeed this argument does not mean that the IA preparing policy proposal. In an article by Radaelli has limited usage. The IA has an effect after its pub- and Meuwese35 we argued that the preparation of lication, that is, post-decision. After its publication, IAs has limited the silos mentality of the past. It the IA has a post-decisional role when it is used by forces the different interests represented by the offi- the EP or later in the process by the European cers (from different DGs) involved in the IA steering of .33 Majone34 has shown the various effects groups to dialogue and coordinate, using evidence- of post-decisional analysis, exactly mentioning the based argumentation.36 Thus, in a sense, making use in among others. It is also realistic to con- things complicated is a virtue of IA because it allows sider what the IAs of the Commission are about: on the Commission to exploit the benefits of partisan average, they are not about ‘yes’ or ‘no’ decisions like mutual adjustment. Evidence-based bargaining with- ‘shall we regulate the environmental consequences in the Commission’s units working in the IA steer- of steel production or not’ – they are about the mode, ing groups is a way to learn from information timing and details of a certain design of that brought into the policy process by officers with dif- have been elaborated via studies, working parties and ferent policy preferences and interests.37 To con- other preparatory activities through the years. clude, our project provides content to the ambiguous Although we argue that the ‘yes/no’ straightfor- proposition that the IA should support decisions ward decisional role is weak, there are effects on the without being a substitute for political decision-mak- ings. Its supporting role is about improving the qual- ity of the policy formulation process within the Com- mission via partisan mutual adjustment and, beyond 33 Alberto Alemanno, “Impact assessment and Courts”, in Claire A. Dunlop and Claudio M. Radaelli (eds.), Handbook of Impact the Commission, in post-decisional analysis. Assessment, (Edward Elgar, forthcoming). 34 Giandomenico D Majone, Argument and Persuasion in the Policy Process, 1st ed. (New Haven and London: Yale University Press, 1989). II. How ‘good’ is impact assessment? 35 Radaelli and Meuwese, "Hard Questions, Hard Solutions”, supra note 23, at p. 7. 1. Economics logic and modes of learning 36 The same findings appear in Erica Melloni, “Ten Years of Euro- pean Impact Assessment: How It Works, for What and for Whom”, 9 World Review (2013), pp. 263 et sqq. How ‘good’ is a policy instrument? There are differ- 37 Radaelli and Meuwese, "Hard Questions, Hard Solutions”, supra ent answers to this question. In the case of ex-ante note 23, at p. 7. evaluation, we can consider different criteria such as 38 Dunlop et al., “The many uses of regulatory impact assessment”, supra note 32, at p. 10; Hertin et al., “Rationalising the policy whether the IA is used by decision-makers and stake- mess?”, supra note 24, at p. 7; Lorna Schrefler, "The Usage of holders38 or carries out the tests prescribed in the Scientific Knowledge by Independent Regulatory Agencies", 23 39 Governance (2010), pp. 309 et sqq. guidelines. Morefundamentally,wecanraiseissues 39 Robert W Hahn and Patrick M Dudley, “How Well Does the about the robustness of the underlying rationale – Government Do Cost-Benefit Analysis?”, Working Paper 04/01, (AEI Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies, 2004); Andrea the intrinsic social scientific robustness of a given Renda, Impact Assessment in the EU: The State of the Art and the policy instrument for evaluation. The literature on Art of the State, (Brussels: Centre for European Policy Studies, 40 2006); Caroline Cecot, Robert Hahn, Andrea Renda et al., "An policy instruments argues that the instruments Evaluation of the Quality of Impact Assessment in the European adopted by are carriers of specific eco- Union with Lessons for the US and the EU", 2 Regulation & Governance (2008), pp. 405 et sqq. nomic ideas or economic theories. There is no doubt 40 Pierre Lascoumes and Patrick Le Galès, "Introduction: Under- that economics is the main rationale evoked in the standing Public Policy through Its Instruments—From the Nature literature on ex-ante policy formulation. Actually it of Instruments to the Sociology of Public Policy Instrumentation", 20 Governance (2007), pp. 1 et sqq. is exactly for this reason – that is, IA as vehicle of 6 Symposium on Policy Evaluation in the EU EJRR 1|2015

specific economic lenses on a wide range of policy ideas and its assumptions about learning and ratio- issues – that ex-ante appraisal has been criticized by nality. those who oppose the economic quantification of en- vironmental issues, and other types of policy problems.41 2. The narrative components We suggest a different interpretation. True, poli- cy instruments are carriers of economic ideas. But Another way of looking at why regulators write IAs they also carry a view of the world which public man- is to think about policies as theories.46 A policy pro- agers face: this world can be a world of rational-syn- posal is a set of hypothesis about cause-and-effect re- optic agents, that scan a high number of options root- lations. It follows that IA is the place where these and-branches until the find the most efficient one, or cause-and-effect relations are spelled out. In other a world of bounded rationality. Thus, alongside an words, the IA portrays the causal structure of a giv- economic worldview, policyinstruments alsocontain en policy proposal. Since they are used to make the a set of assumptions about how public managers case for a given proposal, IAs are more than reposi- learn from evidence. tories of empirical evidence. They are not review es- In Coletti and Radaelli42 we follow this dual ap- says. Their role is to coordinate discourse within the proach (economic ideas and assumptions about Commission, where the IA steering groups, as ex- learning) and argue that a given regulatory instru- plained above, engage in partisan mutual adjust- ment contains both an economic rationale and a ment; and to communicate to the broader public of learning model, or a ‘logic’ of how and what constel- MEPs, Council working groups, stakeholders and del- lations of actors learn by using the instrument. We egates from the Member States. The IAs have a per- then examine IA and the Standard Cost Model (SCM) suasion function and are written with specific read- used for the identification of the costs of administra- ers over the shoulders of the Commission’s officers. tive obligations.43 They are both used in policy for- These considerations invite a novel exploration of mulation at the EU level, whilst some member states IA by adopting the tools and methods of discourse carry out ex-ante evaluation with the SCM but do not analysis. Given their causal structure (‘we have to do engage with the wider IA. If we look only at the eco- X to reach Y because X will produce this and that ef- nomic robustness of the two instruments, IA should fect leading to Y’), IA can be studied as causal narra- always be preferred to the SCM. The latter is concen- tives of public policy. We followed this approach in trated on a narrow category of costs,44 it does not Radaelli, Dunlop and Fritsch.47 We found that not look at benefits, and may lead to inefficient policy only do the IAs contain ‘policies as theories’ and of- choices – simply put, economically wrong evalua- ten engage with policy narratives. This role of the tions of option. However, if we flip the coin and con- Commission as ‘narrator’ had not been explored in sider the robustness of the two policy instruments in terms of their learning models, the conclusion changes. Economically rudimentary forms of ap- 41 Douglas A Kysar, Regulating from Nowhere: and the Search for Objectivity, (New Haven and London: Yale praisals like the SCM contain more realistic and ef- University Press, 2010). fective learning models than IA. In Coletti and 42 Paola Colettti and Claudio M Radaelli, "Economic Rationales, Radaelli45 we explain how the SCM has triggered Learning, and Regulatory Policy Instruments", 91 Public Adminis- tration (2013), pp. 1056 et sqq. learning processes in some member states, leading 43 See Jacopo Torriti, “The Standard cost model: when better regula- to approaches to map the regulatory process from tion fights against red-tape" in Stephen Weatherill (ed.), Better the point of view of the stakeholders, to the inclusion Regulation, (Oxford: Hart Publishing, 2007). 44 Dieter Helm, "Regulatory Reform, Capture, and the Regulatory in regulatory reform programmes of stakeholders Burden", 22 Oxford Review of (2006), pp. 169 et who had been at the margin until now, to stronger sqq. linkages between ICT initiatives in the 45 Paola Colletti and Claudio M. Radaelli, “Economic Rationales”, supra note 42, at p. 13. and regulatory reform, and to the consideration of 46 Stuart S Blume, “Policy as Theory: A Framework for Understand- wider compliance costs. The conclusion is straight- ing the Contribution of Social Science to Welfare Policy”, 20 forward: when we discuss whether an instrument for Acta Sociologica (1977), pp. 247 et sqq. policy evaluation will work or not, we should consid- 47 Claudio M Radaelli, Claire A Dunlop and Oliver Fritsch, "Narrat- ing impact assessment in the European Union", 12 European er both the robustness of its underlying economic Political Science (2013), pp. 500 et sqq. EJRR 1|2015 Symposium on Policy Evaluation in the EU 7

the past, although the use of IA as communication itively we need more research on the usage of IAs by and persuasion tool features prominently in our own the EU institutions. In another article from our discussions and interviews with policy-makers. Ex- project,50 we have made the case for ‘equifinality’: periments in behavioural economics point to the im- different concatenations of variables lead to out- portance of social trust in the narrator.48 Given the comes like ‘control’ and ‘learning’ – hence we need a current state of trust in EU institutions and the cred- nuanced perspective on these questions. ibility issues surrounding the Juncker Commission, We have also qualified the decisional role of IA. it seems risky (for the Commission) to engage in The latter contributes to the decision-making ‘grand narratives’ and evoke value. And identities too, process, but its merit over time is most likely to lay e.g. who ‘Europeans’ are, what the nature of the Com- out arguments and evidence that can be used after mission is, who is better placed to do what in rela- the decision is taken, by the EP, Courts, stakeholders tion to a given policy issue. And yet, our analysis and perhaps the same bureaucracies that generates shows that IAs are used to reiterate issues of identi- the original IA and go back to the same issue years ty and values that, although they may appear already later in the context of another IA. To illustrate, the in the , are taken to their narrative conclusions Commission has dealt with the issue of regulation of in the IA. In our sample, we found several proposi- trade from seals’ fur in different regulatory interven- tions about what ‘European values’ are and what tions during the last ten years.51 ought to be in the EU and beyond. The fact that val- Further, we argued that IAs have a narrative func- ues and identities are developed within - tion that accompanies, without necessarily substitut- ic documents like the IAs and not in constitutional ing, the function of providing economic analysis of discussions may be disturbing normatively. Pragmat- the proposals under consideration. This narrative ically, it signals a recurrent problem with the behav- function extends to identity building and the defin- iour of the Commission already spotted by Laura ition of values – something that may have desirable Cram:49 when trust and credibility are low, the Com- or undesirable normative implications depending on mission does not go back to its core business and how we approach constitutional politics in the EU. show concrete results. Instead, it tends to scale up in Finally, in terms of policy design diffusion and inter- ambition and engage with grandiose narratives of national transfer, we have argued that best practices ‘governance’. Viewed in this light, the narrative fea- hinder instead of facilitating transfer and the social tures of IA may be part of a bigger problem. construction of lesson-drawing. The implementation and diffusion of IA is sensitive to the learning logic encapsulated in this policy instrument – another ar- III. Conclusion gument that rectifies our conventional views. Throughout the article, we have supported our In this article, we have reflected on a number of ma- modifications of propositions and interpretations jor findings from our recent project. Whilst it is cus- that are quite diffuse in the debate on ex-ante evalu- tomary to think of IA as control instrument, our re- ation – a sort of conventional wisdom. Thus, why did search suggests that this instrument may strengthen we find that the conventional interpretative lens may the bureaucracy in Brussels. We cannot say whether be wrong? One reason is the logic of scientific in- increased capacity for strategic and operational pol- quiry. The vast majority of research that defined the icy design and management within the Commission ‘theory’ of IA in the early days was produced by schol- leads to autonomy and ‘escape from control’ – defin- ars with data from the US case. It is sensible to sug- gest that some conclusions drawn on the US case may not be valid when we consider Europe. What we 48 E.g. Robert B Cialdini, Influence: The Psychology of Persuasion thought was a general theoretical argument about IA (New York, NY: Harper, 2007). was instead a local theory, valid only in certain places 49 Laura Cram, “Governance 'to Go': Domestic Actors, Institutions and the Boundaries of the Possible", 39 Journal of Common and times. Market Studies (2001), pp. 595 et sqq. Another reason is the role played by internation- 50 Dunlop et al., “The many uses of regulatory impact assessment”, al organisations and policy-makers in distilling supra note 32, at p. 10. lessons and conventional propositions that assist 51 Radaelli, Dunlop and Fritsch, “Narrating impact assessment”, supra note 47, at p. 15. their communication, the design of guidance for IA, 8 Symposium on Policy Evaluation in the EU EJRR 1|2015

training and the diffusion of economic analysis in more fragmentary and we lack a body of empirical government and at the Commission. Because of these research. We can only talk at the conceptual level. objectives (diffusion, training, communication, im- Conceptually, indeed, if appraisals strengthen the bu- plementation), complex causal phenomena are re- reaucracy instead of controlling it, the argument duced to simple propositions that can be somewhat could apply to both ex-ante and ex-post. The obser- ‘sloganized’. Some of them have intuitive value, like vations about the decisional role of evaluations can the logic of best practice, and are heuristically attrac- extend to ex-post – the Commission may not use eval- tive. With this article we have shown the dangers of uations to terminate legislation but there may be oth- relying on assumptions that are not exposed to crit- er effects on the decisional process and post-decision- ical empirical and theoretical challenge. al effects. The remarks on narration and best practice One question for the readers of this special issue are conceptually transferrable to the ex-post phase of is whether the arguments we aired can be extended evaluation, and learning may impact on economic to the ex-post evaluation of legislation. Obviously models’ usageboth intheex-anteandtheex-postcase. while the Commission has produced IAs for more Of course, this does not suggest any conclusion ab- thanadecade,theexperienceoftheCommissionwith sent empirical analysis – but it invites an integrated legislative evaluation carried out ex-post is much research agenda for the whole life cycle of evaluation.