Understanding the Generalized Median Stable Matchings∗

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Understanding the Generalized Median Stable Matchings∗ Understanding the Generalized Median Stable Matchings∗ Christine T. Cheng† Department of Computer Science University of Wisconsin–Milwaukee, Milwaukee, WI 53211, USA. [email protected] March 31, 2009 Abstract Let I be a stable matching instance with N stable matchings. For each man m, order his (not necessarily distinct) N partners from his most preferred to his least preferred. Denote the ith woman in his sorted list as pi(m). Let αi consist of the man-woman pairs where each man m is matched to pi(m). Teo and Sethuraman proved this surprising result: for i = 1 to N, not only is αi a matching, it is also stable. The αi’s are called the generalized median stable matchings of I. Determining if these stable matchings can be computed efficiently is an open problem. In this paper, we present a new characterization of the generalized median stable matchings that provides interesting insights. It implies that the generalized median stable matchings in the middle – α(N+1)/2 when N is odd, αN/2 and αN/2+1 when N is even – are fair not only in a local sense but also in a global sense because they are also medians of the lattice of stable matchings. We then show that there are some families of SM instances for which computing an αi is easy but that the task is NP-hard in general. Finally, we also consider what it means to approximate a median stable matching and present results for this problem. 1 Introduction In the stable marriage problem (SM), there are n men and n women each of whom has a list that ranks all individuals of the opposite sex. A matching is a set of man-woman pairs where each individual appears in at most one pair. The objective of the problem is to find a matching µ that has n pairs and has no blocking pairs – i.e., a man and a woman who prefer each other over their partners in µ. The rationale behind the stability condition is that if a blocking pair exists, the man and the woman will likely leave their partners and thereby compromise the integrity of the matching µ. A celebrated result by Gale and Shapley states that every instance of SM has a stable matching that can be found in O(n2) time [13]. Today, centralized stable matching algorithms match medical residents to hospitals [24], students to schools [1, 2], etc. In this paper, we focus on a set of stable matchings that is due to Teo and Sethuraman [27]. Let I be an SM instance, and M(I) its set of stable matchings. Let pµ(a) denote the partner of a in stable matching µ. By formulating the stable matchings problem as a linear program, they discovered the following surprising result: ∗A preliminary version [8] of this paper was presented at LATIN 2008. †Supported by NSF Award No. CCF-0830678. 1 Theorem 1 [27] Suppose that Z ⊆ M(I) and z = |Z|. For each man m, sort the multiset of women {pµ(m),µ ∈ Z} from m’s most preferred to least preferred woman. Let pi,Z(m) denote the ith woman in this sorted list. Do the same for each woman w. Let αi,Z consist of the man-woman pairs where each man m is matched to pi,Z(m). Similarly, let βi,Z consist of the man-woman pairs where each woman w is matched to pi,Z(w). For i = 1,...,z, αi,Z and βi,Z are stable matchings; moreover, αi,Z = βz−i+1,Z . When Z = M(I) and N = |M(I)|, we denote αi,Z and βi,Z as αi and βi respectively. We also follow Klaus and Klijn’s [18] terminology and call αi = βN−i+1 the ith generalized median stable matching of I. The most interesting of the generalized median stable matchings are the ones in the middle – α(N+1)/2 when N is odd, and αN/2 and αN/2+1 when N is even – because they match every participant to his/her (lower or upper) median stable partner and, thus, are fair in a very strong sense. Since Teo and Sethuraman’s work, several authors [22, 12, 18] have proven the existence of the generalized median stable matchings. However, determining if these stable matchings can be computed in polynomial time remains open. Simply using the definition can be inefficient because there are instances whose number of stable matchings is exponential in the input size. Our goal is to fill this gap. It is well known that M(I) forms a distributive lattice under a natural dominance relation . In the early 1960’s, Barbut [5] initiated the study of medians for distributive lattices. Recall that in statistics, the median of a set of test scores is a number that summarizes the entire set. It reflects how good or how bad the scores are as a whole. Specifically, it is one of the numbers whose total distance (or average distance) from all the test scores is the smallest. Extending this idea to distributive lattices, Barbut would define a median of M(I) = (M(I), ) as follows. Let H(I) denote the lattice’s Hasse diagram. For any two stable matchings µ and µ′, define the distance between µ and µ′, d(µ,µ′), as the length of a shortest path between µ and µ′ in the undirected ′ ∗ version of H(I). Let D(µ) = Pµ′∈M(I) d(µ,µ ). A median of M(I) is a stable matching µ such that D(µ∗) = min{D(µ),µ ∈ M(I)}. Just as in statistics, one can think of the medians of M(I) as the stable matchings that best describe the set M(I). An intriguing question is what is the relationship of the generalized median stable matchings of I to the medians of M(I)? To better understand the generalized median stable matchings of I, we make use of I’s rotation poset, a structure related to M(I). Algorithmically, the rotation poset is very useful because it encodes all the stable matchings of I, and, yet, its size is always polynomial in the input size. Our main results are as follows: • We present a new characterization of the generalized median stable matchings of I that provides interesting insights into these stable matchings not apparent from their definition. It implies that when N is odd, α(N+1)/2 is the unique median of M(I), and when N is even, the stable matchings µ such that αN/2 µ αN/2+1 are exactly the medians of M(I). Thus, quite remarkably, a stable matching is “locally median” if and only if it is “globally median”! • We consider the problem of computing a specific αi. We prove that when i = O(log n), αi and αN−i+1 can be computed efficiently. We also note that when I’s rotation poset is a series-parallel poset, an interval order, or a two-dimensional poset in general, computing any of its generalized median stable matchings is easy; and when I’s rotation poset has at most two layers, computing a median of M(I) can be done efficiently. • In spite of these results, however, we show that the task of computing αi is NP-hard in general. In particular, we prove that finding a median of M(I) is NP-hard. 2 • Finally, we consider what it means to approximate a median stable matching of M(I), and present results for this problem. The outline for the rest of the paper is as follows: in Section 2, we define distributive lattices, present important results on the medians of a distributive lattice, and describe rotation posets and their properties. We present the new characterization for the αi’s in Section 3 and complexity results for computing αi in Section 4. We consider the problem of approximating a median stable matching of M(I) in Section 5 and conclude in Section 6. 2 Distributive lattices, medians, and rotation posets Distributive lattices and their medians. Recall that a (finite) lattice L = (L, ≤) is a partially ordered set (or poset) such that every pair of elements x and y of L has a greatest lower bound, x∧y, called the meet of x and y, and a least upper bound, x ∨ y, called the join of x and y. It also implies that any subset L′ of L has a well-defined greatest lower bound, ∧L′, and a well-defined least upper bound, ∨L′. When x ≤ y, let the interval [x,y] = {z : x ≤ z ≤ y}. We say that y covers x when [x,y]= {x,y}; that is, no element of L lies between x and y. The Hasse diagram of L, H(L), is the directed graph formed by letting every element of L be a vertex and every pair (x,y) of vertices be an edge whenever y covers x. Below, we define a median of L and present important results related to it. Our discussion follows the paper of LeClerc [19]. Define the distance between any two elements x and y of L, d(x,y), as the length of the shortest path between x and y in the undirected version of H(L). Let Lk be the k-fold product of L. An k k element X = (x1,x2,...,xk) ∈ L is called a profile. Let DX (x) = Pi=1 d(x,xi). An X-median is an element m of L such that DX (m) = min{DX (x),x ∈ L}.
Recommended publications
  • Statistical Matching: a Paradigm for Assessing the Uncertainty in the Procedure
    Journal of Of®cial Statistics, Vol. 17, No. 3, 2001, pp. 407±422 Statistical Matching: A Paradigm for Assessing the Uncertainty in the Procedure Chris Moriarity1 and Fritz Scheuren2 Statistical matching has been widely used by practitioners without always adequate theoreti- cal underpinnings. The work of Kadane (1978) has been a notable exception and the present article extends his insights. Kadane's 1978 article is reprinted in this JOS issue. Modern com- puting can make possible, under techniques described here, a real advance in the application of statistical matching. Key words: Multivariate normal; complex survey designs; robustness; resampling; variance- covariance structures; and application suggestions. 1. Introduction Many government policy questions, whether on the expenditure or tax side, lend them- selves to microsimulation modeling, where ``what if'' analyses of alternative policy options are carried out (e.g., Citro and Hanushek 1991). Often, the starting point for such models, in an attempt to achieve a degree of verisimilitude, is to employ information contained in several survey microdata ®les. Typically, not all the variables wanted for the modeling have been collected together from a single individual or family. However, the separate survey ®les may have many demographic and other control variables in common. The idea arose, then, of matching the separate ®les on these common variables and thus creating a composite ®le for analysis. ``Statistical matching,'' as the technique began to be called, has been more or less widely practiced since the advent of public use ®les in the 1960's. Arguably, the desire to employ statistical matching was even an impetus for the release of several of the early public use ®les, including those involving U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • A Machine Learning Approach to Census Record Linking∗
    A Machine Learning Approach to Census Record Linking∗ James J. Feigenbaumy March 28, 2016 Abstract Thanks to the availability of new historical census sources and advances in record linking technology, economic historians are becoming big data geneal- ogists. Linking individuals over time and between databases has opened up new avenues for research into intergenerational mobility, the long run effects of early life conditions, assimilation, discrimination, and the returns to edu- cation. To take advantage of these new research opportunities, scholars need to be able to accurately and efficiently match historical records and produce an unbiased dataset of links for analysis. I detail a standard and transparent census matching technique for constructing linked samples that can be repli- cated across a variety of cases. The procedure applies insights from machine learning classification and text comparison to record linkage of historical data. My method teaches an algorithm to replicate how a well trained and consistent researcher would create a linked sample across sources. I begin by extracting a subset of possible matches for each record, and then use training data to tune a matching algorithm that attempts to minimize both false positives and false negatives, taking into account the inherent noise in historical records. To make the procedure precise, I trace its application to an example from my own work, linking children from the 1915 Iowa State Census to their adult-selves in the 1940 Federal Census. In addition, I provide guidance on a number of practical questions, including how large the training data needs to be relative to the sample. ∗I thank Christoph Hafemeister, Jamie Lee, Christopher Muller, Martin Rotemberg, and Nicolas Ziebarth for detailed feedback and thoughts on this project, as well as seminar participants at the NBER DAE Summer Institute and the Berkeley Demography Conference on Census Linking.
    [Show full text]
  • Stability and Median Rationalizability for Aggregate Matchings
    games Article Stability and Median Rationalizability for Aggregate Matchings Federico Echenique 1, SangMok Lee 2, Matthew Shum 1 and M. Bumin Yenmez 3,* 1 Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences, California Institute of Technology, Pasadena, CA 91125, USA; [email protected] (F.E.); [email protected] (M.S.) 2 Department of Economics, Washington University in St. Louis, St. Louis, MO 63130, USA; [email protected] 3 Department of Economics, Boston College, Chestnut Hill, MA 02467, USA * Correspondence: [email protected] Abstract: We develop the theory of stability for aggregate matchings used in empirical studies and establish fundamental properties of stable matchings including the result that the set of stable matchings is a non-empty, complete, and distributive lattice. Aggregate matchings are relevant as matching data in revealed preference theory. We present a result on rationalizing a matching data as the median stable matching. Keywords: aggregate matching; median stable matching; rationalizability; lattice 1. Introduction Following the seminal work of [1], an extensive literature has developed regarding matching markets with non-transferable utility. This literature assumes that there are agent-specific preferences, and studies the existence of stable matchings in which each Citation: Echenique, F.; Lee, S.; agent prefers her assigned partner to the outside option of being unmatched, and there Shum, M.; Yenmez, M.B. Stability and are no pairs of agents that would like to match with each other rather than keeping their Median Rationalizability for assigned partners. Aggregate Matchings. Games 2021, 12, In this paper, we develop the theory of stability for aggregate matchings, which we 33.
    [Show full text]
  • Report on Exact and Statistical Matching Techniques
    Statistical Policy Working Papers are a series of technical documents prepared under the auspices of the Office of Federal Statistical Policy and Standards. These documents are the product of working groups or task forces, as noted in the Preface to each report. These Statistical Policy Working Papers are published for the purpose of encouraging further discussion of the technical issues and to stimulate policy actions which flow from the technical findings and recommendations. Readers of Statistical Policy Working Papers are encouraged to communicate directly with the Office of Federal Statistical Policy and Standards with additional views, suggestions, or technical concerns. Office of Joseph W. Duncan Federal Statistical Director Policy Standards For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office Washington, D.C. 20402 Statistical Policy Working Paper 5 Report on Exact and Statistical Matching Techniques Prepared by Subcommittee on Matching Techniques Federal Committee on Statistical Methodology DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE UNITED STATES OF AMERICA U.S. DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE Philip M. Klutznick Courtenay M. Slater, Chief Economist Office of Federal Statistical Policy and Standards Joseph W. Duncan, Director Issued: June 1980 Office of Federal Statistical Policy and Standards Joseph W. Duncan, Director Katherine K. Wallman, Deputy Director, Social Statistics Gaylord E. Worden, Deputy Director, Economic Statistics Maria E. Gonzalez, Chairperson, Federal Committee on Statistical Methodology Preface This working paper was prepared by the Subcommittee on Matching Techniques, Federal Committee on Statistical Methodology. The Subcommittee was chaired by Daniel B. Radner, Office of Research and Statistics, Social Security Administration, Department of Health and Human Services. Members of the Subcommittee include Rich Allen, Economics, Statistics, and Cooperatives Service (USDA); Thomas B.
    [Show full text]
  • Alternatives to Randomized Control Trials: a Review of Three Quasi-Experimental Designs for Causal Inference
    Actualidades en Psicología, 29(119), 2015, 19- 27 ISSN 2215-3535 http://revistas.ucr.ac.cr/index.php/actualidades DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.15517/ap.v29i119.18810 Alternatives to Randomized Control Trials: A Review of Three Quasi-experimental Designs for Causal Inference Alternativas a las Pruebas Controladas Aleatorizadas: una revisión de tres diseños cuasi experimentales para la inferencia causal Pavel Pavolovich Panko1 Jacob D. Curtis2 Brittany K. Gorrall3 Todd Daniel Little4 Texas Tech University, United States Abstract. The Randomized Control Trial (RCT) design is typically seen as the gold standard in psychological research. As it is not always possible to conform to RCT specifications, many studies are conducted in the quasi-experimental framework. Although quasi-experimental designs are considered less preferable to RCTs, with guidance they can produce inferences which are just as valid. In this paper, the authors present 3 quasi-experimental designs which are viable alternatives to RCT designs. These designs are Regression Point Displacement (RPD), Regression Discontinuity (RD), and Propensity Score Matching (PSM). Additionally, the authors outline several notable methodological improvements to use with these designs. Keywords. Psychometrics, Quasi-Experimental Design, Regression Point Displacement, Regression Discontinuity, Propensity Score Matching. Resumen. Los diseños de Pruebas Controladas Aleatorizadas (PCA) son típicamente vistas como el mejor diseño en la investigación en psicología. Como tal, no es siempre posible cumplir con las especificaciones de las PCA y por ello muchos estudios son realizados en un marco cuasi experimental. Aunque los diseños cuasi experimentales son considerados menos convenientes que los diseños PCA, con directrices estos pueden producir inferencias igualmente válidas.
    [Show full text]
  • Matching Via Dimensionality Reduction for Estimation of Treatment Effects in Digital Marketing Campaigns
    Proceedings of the Twenty-Fifth International Joint Conference on Artificial Intelligence (IJCAI-16) Matching via Dimensionality Reduction for Estimation of Treatment Effects in Digital Marketing Campaigns Sheng Li Nikos Vlassis Jaya Kawale Yun Fu Northeastern University Adobe Research Adobe Research Northeastern University Boston, MA, USA San Jose, CA, USA San Jose, CA, USA Boston, MA, USA [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] Abstract units in the control group are interpreted as counterfactuals, and the average treatment effect on treated (ATT) is estimated A widely used method for estimating counterfactu- by comparing the outcomes of every matched pair. als and causal treatment effects from observational data is nearest-neighbor matching. This typically One of the widely used matching methods is Nearest involves pairing each treated unit with its nearest- Neighbor Matching (NNM) [Rubin, 1973a]. For each treated in-covariates control unit, and then estimating an unit, NNM finds its nearest neighbor in the control group average treatment effect from the set of matched to generate a matched pair, and the ATT is then estimated pairs. Although straightforward to implement, this from the set of matched pairs. Different NNM methods are estimator is known to suffer from a bias that in- characterized by the choice of a distance measure for de- creases with the dimensionality of the covariate termining such a match. Some of the popularly used dis- space, which can be undesirable in applications tance measures are Exact Matching and its variant Coars- that involve high-dimensional data. To address this ened Exact Matching (CEM) [Iacus et al., 2011], Maha- problem, we propose a novel estimator that first lanobis distance matching [Rubin, 1979], and Propensity projects the data to a number of random linear sub- Score Matching (PSM) [Rosenbaum and Rubin, 1983].
    [Show full text]
  • Frequency Matching Case-Control Techniques: an Epidemiological Perspective
    Frequency Matching case-control techniques: an epidemiological perspective. Authors: Hai Nguyen, MS (1st and Corresponding Author) Research Assistant Division of Epidemiology and Biostatistics, School of Public Health, University of Illinois at Chicago Phone: 1-312-355-4471 Email: [email protected] Trang Pham, MS Division of Epidemiology and Biostatistics, School of Public Health, University of Illinois at Chicago [email protected] Garth Rauscher, PhD Division of Epidemiology and Biostatistics, School of Public Health, University of Illinois at Chicago [email protected] Abstract In many cohort and case-control studies, subjects are matched to intend to control confounding and to improve study efficiency by improving precision. An often-used approach is to check to see that the frequency distributions in each study group are alike. Being alike in the frequency distributions of key variables would provide evidence that the groups are comparable. However, there are instances where the overall distributions could be alike, but the individual cases could vary substantially. While there are no methods that can guarantee comparability, individual case matching has often been used to provide assurances that the groups are comparable. We propose an algorithm build a macro in SAS to match control for the case given a set of matching criteria, including match exact on site, on the year, exact or 5-year interval match on age. Cases will be matched with a large number of controls. A large dataset from 2000-2017 from Metropolitan Chicago Breast Cancer Registry with more than 485000 women obtaining breast screening or diagnostic imaging (more than 15000 cases:30000 controls) was applied.
    [Show full text]
  • Package 'Matching'
    Package ‘Matching’ April 14, 2021 Version 4.9-9 Date 2021-03-15 Title Multivariate and Propensity Score Matching with Balance Optimization Author Jasjeet Singh Sekhon <[email protected]> Maintainer Jasjeet Singh Sekhon <[email protected]> Description Provides functions for multivariate and propensity score matching and for finding optimal balance based on a genetic search algorithm. A variety of univariate and multivariate metrics to determine if balance has been obtained are also provided. For details, see the paper by Jasjeet Sekhon (2007, <doi:10.18637/jss.v042.i07>). Depends R (>= 2.6.0), MASS (>= 7.2-1), graphics, grDevices, stats Suggests parallel, rgenoud (>= 2.12), rbounds License GPL-3 URL http://sekhon.berkeley.edu/matching/ NeedsCompilation yes RoxygenNote 7.1.1 Repository CRAN Date/Publication 2021-04-13 22:00:15 UTC R topics documented: balanceUV . .2 GenMatch . .4 GerberGreenImai . 11 ks.boot . 13 lalonde . 15 Match . 16 MatchBalance . 22 Matchby . 26 1 2 balanceUV qqstats . 30 summary.balanceUV . 32 summary.ks.boot . 33 summary.Match . 34 summary.Matchby . 34 Index 36 balanceUV Univariate Balance Tests Description This function provides a number of univariate balance metrics. Generally, users should call MatchBalance and not this function directly. Usage balanceUV(Tr, Co, weights = rep(1, length(Co)), exact = FALSE, ks=FALSE, nboots = 1000, paired=TRUE, match=FALSE, weights.Tr=rep(1,length(Tr)), weights.Co=rep(1,length(Co)), estimand="ATT") Arguments Tr A vector containing the treatment observations. Co A vector containing the control observations. weights A vector containing the observation specific weights. Only use this option when the treatment and control observations are paired (as they are after matching).
    [Show full text]
  • A Comparison of Different Methods to Handle Missing Data in the Context of Propensity Score Analysis
    European Journal of Epidemiology https://doi.org/10.1007/s10654-018-0447-z (0123456789().,-volV)(0123456789().,- volV) METHODS A comparison of different methods to handle missing data in the context of propensity score analysis 1 1,2 1,3 Jungyeon Choi • Olaf M. Dekkers • Saskia le Cessie Received: 21 May 2018 / Accepted: 25 September 2018 Ó The Author(s) 2018 Abstract Propensity score analysis is a popular method to control for confounding in observational studies. A challenge in propensity methods is missing values in confounders. Several strategies for handling missing values exist, but guidance in choosing the best method is needed. In this simulation study, we compared four strategies of handling missing covariate values in propensity matching and propensity weighting. These methods include: complete case analysis, missing indicator method, multiple imputation and combining multiple imputation and missing indicator method. Concurrently, we aimed to provide guidance in choosing the optimal strategy. Simulated scenarios varied regarding missing mechanism, presence of effect modification or unmeasured confounding. Additionally, we demonstrated how missingness graphs help clarifying the missing structure. When no effect modification existed, complete case analysis yielded valid causal treatment effects even when data were missing not at random. In some situations, complete case analysis was also able to partially correct for unmeasured confounding. Multiple imputation worked well if the data were missing (completely) at random, and if the imputation model was correctly specified. In the presence of effect modification, more complex imputation models than default options of commonly used statistical software were required. Multiple imputation may fail when data are missing not at random.
    [Show full text]
  • Performance of Logistic Regression, Propensity Scores, and Instrumental Variable for Estimating Their True Target Odds Ratios In
    Performance of Logistic Regression, Propensity Scores, and Instrumental Variable for Estimating Their True Target Odds Ratios in the Absence and Presence of Unmeasured Confounder Tianqi Yu West China Hospital of Sichuan University Chengyu Ke Southern Methodist University Wentao Xu West China Hospital of Sichuan University Jing Li ( [email protected] ) West China Hospital of Sichuan University Research Article Keywords: bias, unmeasured confounder, logistic model, propensity score, instrumental variable Posted Date: December 28th, 2020 DOI: https://doi.org/10.21203/rs.3.rs-133868/v1 License: This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License. Read Full License Yu et al. RESEARCH Performance of logistic regression, propensity scores, and instrumental variable for estimating their true target odds ratios in the absence and presence of unmeasured confounder Tianqi. Yu1, Chengyu. Ke2 , Wentao. Xu1 and Jing. Li1* *Correspondence: [email protected] Abstract 1 Department of Evidence-Based Medicine and Clinical Background: A lot of studies have compared the ability of statistical methods to Epidemiology, Sichuan University control for confounding. However, a majority of studies mistakenly assumed these West China Hospital, Chengdu, China methods estimate the same effect. The aim of this study was to use Monte Carlo Full list of author information is simulations to compare logistic regression, propensity scores and instrumental available at the end of the article variable analysis for estimating their true target odds ratios in terms of bias and precision in the absence and presence of unmeasured confounder. Methods: We established the formula allowing us to compute the true odds ratio of each method. We varied the instrument’s strength and the unmeasured confounder to cover a large range of scenarios in the simulation study.
    [Show full text]
  • An Empirical Evaluation of Statistical Matching Methodologies
    Southern Methodist University SMU Scholar Historical Working Papers Cox School of Business 1982 An Empirical Evaluation of Statistical Matching Methodologies Richard A. Barry Southern Methodist University William H. Stewart Oklahoma State University - Main Campus J. Scott Turner Oklahoma State University - Main Campus Follow this and additional works at: https://scholar.smu.edu/business_workingpapers Part of the Business Commons This document is brought to you for free and open access by the Cox School of Business at SMU Scholar. It has been accepted for inclusion in Historical Working Papers by an authorized administrator of SMU Scholar. For more information, please visit http://digitalrepository.smu.edu. Research and Development Scbool of "P us i ness Administraticm Southern Methodist Univeraitv Dallas. Texas 75275 · AN EMPIRICAL EVALUATION OF STATISTICAL MATCHING METHODOLOGIES Working Paper 82-804* by Richard A. Barr William H. Stewart J. Scott Turner Richard A. Barr Edwin L. Cox School of Business Southern Methodist University Dallas, Texas 75275 William H. Stewart Oklahoma State University Stillwater, Oklahoma J. Scott Turner Oklahoma State University Stillwater, Oklahoma *This paper represents a draft of work in progress by the authors and is bei ng sent to you for inf ormation and review. Responsibility for the contents rests solely wi th the authors . This working paper may not be reproduced or distributed wi thout the written consent of the authors. Please address all correspondence to Richard A. Barr. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS We wish to acknowledge the strong support and cooperation of the follow­ ing organizations: the Office of Evaluation and Technical Analysis, De­ partment of Health and Human Services; the Office of Research and Sta­ tistics, Social Security Administration; the Internal Revenue Service and Office of Tax Analysis, Department of the Treasury; and our home universities.
    [Show full text]
  • The Essential Role of Pair Matching in Cluster-Randomized Experiments, with Application to the Mexican Universal Health Insuranc
    Statistical Science 2009, Vol. 24, No. 1, 29–53 DOI: 10.1214/08-STS274 © Institute of Mathematical Statistics, 2009 The Essential Role of Pair Matching in Cluster-Randomized Experiments, with Application to the Mexican Universal Health Insurance Evaluation Kosuke Imai, Gary King and Clayton Nall Abstract. A basic feature of many field experiments is that investigators are only able to randomize clusters of individuals—such as households, com- munities, firms, medical practices, schools or classrooms—even when the individual is the unit of interest. To recoup the resulting efficiency loss, some studies pair similar clusters and randomize treatment within pairs. However, many other studies avoid pairing, in part because of claims in the litera- ture, echoed by clinical trials standards organizations, that this matched-pair, cluster-randomization design has serious problems. We argue that all such claims are unfounded. We also prove that the estimator recommended for this design in the literature is unbiased only in situations when matching is unnecessary; its standard error is also invalid. To overcome this problem without modeling assumptions, we develop a simple design-based estimator with much improved statistical properties. We also propose a model-based approach that includes some of the benefits of our design-based estimator as well as the estimator in the literature. Our methods also address individual- level noncompliance, which is common in applications but not allowed for in most existing methods. We show that from the perspective of bias, efficiency, power, robustness or research costs, and in large or small samples, pairing should be used in cluster-randomized experiments whenever feasible; failing to do so is equivalent to discarding a considerable fraction of one’s data.
    [Show full text]