Men Make Their Own History, but They Do Not Make It Just As They Please; They Do Not Make

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Men Make Their Own History, but They Do Not Make It Just As They Please; They Do Not Make

THE UNIVERSITY IN TIMES

OF REVOLUTION

Lessons From The Industrial Revolution.

By Matt Tilling

School of Commerce

Flinders University

South Australia

School of Commerce Research Paper Series: 01-8 ISSN: 1441-3906

This paper is very much a work in progress, please be kind. All comments will be gratefully accepted. I would like to thank Dr. Carol Tilt for her patience and many helpful comments. Any mistakes are purely the responsibility of the author. As this paper is still being developed you are kindly requested not to quote without permission. Abstract

“Men* make their own history, but they do not make it just as they please; they do not make it under circumstances chosen by themselves, but under circumstances directly encountered, given, and transmitted from the past” (Marx cited in Feuer, 1969, p. 360).

This paper provides a background against which to consider the future role of the University in these times of the Global Revolution. It examinations the role played by the University during the Industrial Revolution in the United Kingdom. The methodology and approach are essentially Marxist, focusing on the interface of conflict between technological change, society and industry, and where the University fitted into this class conflict. Marx’s own observations, along with others, of the time are drawn on to frame the social change wrought by the Industrial Revolution. English Universities are then examined to see how they responded and legitimated their position within society. “The object of education within the colleges was to produce intellectuals and gentlemen who could be relied upon in a world constantly threatened, it was thought, by revolution” (Kearney, 1970, p. 22). From this base comment is made on the argument that society is in a new phase of revolution, both a technological (the information) revolution and a social (globalisation) revolution. Based on past record, and a comparative social examination, discussion of the possible future directions of the University can be better framed. The Industrial Revolution brought about massive change to the institution of the University, there is no reason why it should not be expected to happen again. What directions this change will take are intrinsically unknowable. But the past often provides a window, if glassed somewhat darkly, on the future. “Hindsight greatly assists in the identification of the chain of cause and effect and the belated and ineffective nature of the remedial action taken at the time” (Bartlett, 2000, p. 17).

“Come writers and critics Who prophesize with your pen And keep your eyes wide The chance won't come again And don't speak too soon For the wheel's still in spin And there's no tellin' who That it's namin'. For the loser now Will be later to win For the times they are a-changin'” Bob Dylan.

*Important Note: This paper draws heavily on citations of original documents produced during the last two centuries. As was the nature of the times the language employed in places in this article is not what could necessarily be termed ‘gender neutral’. The use of ‘male-centric’ language does not reflect the authors own belief about gender roles or importance. In this present debate on the future of the University it is vital that views from all sections of the community are equally considered and acknowledged.

2 “Men make their own history, but they do not make it just as they please;

they do not make it under circumstances chosen by themselves, but under

circumstances directly encountered, given, and transmitted from the past”

(Marx cited in Feuer, 1969, p. 360).

Introduction

The future of the University, and the academics’ own role within it, is an extremely important area for every member of the institution to consider. The problem with such prediction however is that it is so easy to go down the path of baseless opinion and summation, and arrive at no sustainable, consistent or justifiable conclusion. What is required then is to accept and extrapolate a deeper epistemology, consider the past in light of this choice and use that to guide speculation about the future.

Using a Marxist perspective of social change and adaptation the paper examines the role of the University during a time of great social change, the Industrial Revolution.

At this point the paper will make only very general predictions as to what this means for the future of the University. But it is hoped that this aspect of the paper can eventually be more strongly developed.

“The value derived from the re-examination of the past is determined by

the integrity and objectivity of the examiner. Hindsight greatly assists in

the identification of the chain of cause and effect and the belated and

ineffective nature of the remedial action taken at the time. If viewed

clearly, political expediency can be seen for what it was unless the post-

3 event analysis is coloured by current politics which dilute any real benefit

to be gained from the research into the past.” (Bartlett, 2000, p. 17)

Methodological Approach

There seems to be much currency in a the Marxist methodology for examining institutions in times of change and for that reason some time will be taken to examine the underlying philosophy of the historical methodology being employed. Also again considering the nature of the work, historic-predictive as it could be termed, it is important that a consistent underpinning be demonstrated or else it is too easy to fall to

‘historical mining’ for the sake of supporting opinions about the future. The Marxist paradigm has been much used and misused within academic circles. This paper will not address or review the history of this debate with in academia.

A Marxian Model of Society.

The Marxian model is ideally suited to examining society in times of change. By focussing on social structures and classes a picture of the underlying forces and motivations of change can be brought into sharper focus. A rich tapestry of human relations and social institutions can be wrought from this warp of social interactions, bound together by the weft of economics. “The origin of all social processes should be sought in the constitution of social classes and in the relationships among them, in their relative strength, and the state of class consciousness. More importantly, it is the class struggle that decides the transition of society from one evolutionary stage to another”

(Jordan, in Jordan (ed.), 1972, p. 21).

4 It is important to remember that ‘class struggle’ is more than just a simple story of economic forces as it has often been cast in some of the Marxist literature. Class struggle consists of a number of systems, or layers, that are integrally linked (Tosh, 1991, p. 164).

At the heart of society are the forces of production, these are the apparatus, skills and raw materials that are utilised by labour for production. The forces of production are linked with the Relations of Production, which is indicative of the underlying economic structure of society (whether Capitalist, Socialist, Feudal, etc.). Upon this foundation rests a much more visible Superstructure which consists of the institutions of society

(legal, political, educational, religious).

“ Through the base/superstructure model Marxism offers a particularly

useful way of conceiving the totality of social relations in any given

society. It is not just that the political, social, and economic and

technological all have their place; in a full-scale Marxist analysis these

familiar distinctions lose their force. Social and economic history become

inseparable” (Tosh, 1991, p. 168)

It is also important to remember that this model is not a simple one-way relationship from (economic) base to (institutional) superstructure. There is constant pressure from the superstructure back to the foundation. This is perhaps one of the strengths of the Marxian philosophy. This positive feedback model represents a much more fundamental belief that social equilibrium is not the norm. There are both reinforcing and destabilising elements inherent in the model. Revolutions occur, society changes, when these disruptive forces overcome the existing superstructure, and replace

5 it with a new order. “Historians have found the notion of the dialectic to be an invaluable tool in analysing social change of varying intensity, from the barely perceptible movement within a stable social formation to periods of revolutionary ferment.” (Tosh,

1991, p. 172)

It is this basic view that provides us with an opportunity to place the core question of this paper in perspective. As a social institution, how was the University affected by changes in the economic and social ‘foundations’ during the Industrial Revolution, and what lessons can we begin to draw from this in relation to its future. But before considering these questions in a little more detail it is worth considering the place that history plays in the Marxist philosophy.

Marx’s View of History

“ History does nothing, it ‘possesses no immense wealth’, it ‘wages no

battles’. It is man, real living man, that does all that, that possesses and

fights; ‘history’ is not a person apart, using man as a means for its own

particular aims; history is nothing but the activity of man pursuing his

aims.” (Marx in Jordan (ed.), 1972, p. 192, italics in original)

This powerful statement from Marx needs to be remembered in its context. It was made in a time when Hegel’s Philosophy of History was the seminal work. And although

Hegel was instrumental in redefining the concept of the Dialectic1 he had shackled the

1 Dialectics considers all phenomena as being in movement, in a process of continual change. It views the developement of nature itself as a result of the struggle between contradictions within nature.

6 development of human society to some ‘idealist’ concept of guided (perhaps even by

‘God’) evolution in all forms of history. Marx strongly objected.

In Marx’s view, history was the story of Man’s struggle to make his life ‘better’.

The fundamental needs of Man are food; clothing; and shelter. Psychological needs come only after these needs are satisfied. “We must begin by stating the first premise of all human existence and, therefore, of all history, the premise, namely, that men must be in a position to live in order to be able to ‘make history’” (Marx in Jordan (ed.), 1972, p. 94).

Over time mankind has developed better and more efficient means to satisfy immediate needs through the exploitation of nature. History itself is about the growth of human productive power enabling the satisfaction of our basic (physiological) needs more easily, and leaving more time to pursue the more fulfilling (psychological) needs.

“In maintaining that the only true, objective view of the historical process was rooted in the material conditions of life, Marx sharply distinguished himself from the main currents of nineteenth-century historiography with their choice of nationalism, freedom or religion as the defining themes of history” (Tosh, 1991, p. 164). The Marxist view of history was later to become known, quite appropriately, as ‘historical materialism’, a phrase coined by Fredrich Engels.

“The first historical act is thus the production of the means to satisfy these

needs, the production of material life itself. And indeed this is an historical

act, a fundamental condition of all history, which today, as thousands of

years ago, must daily and hourly be fulfilled merely in order to sustain

human life... Therefore in any interpretation of history one has first of all

to observe this fundamental fact in all its significance and all its

7 implications and to accord it its due importance” (Marx in Jordan (ed.),

1972, p. 94)

But just as Marx denies some supernatural or external determinant of history, he is also careful to point out that the individual human, no matter how great, powerful or important, is not capable of individually influencing history, only participating to some greater or lesser part. “Marxism rejects as obscurantist all notions that would reduce history to a succession of unique, unpredictable events, occasioned by the conflicting wills of men. It holds that this is a shallow approach, confining itself to surface appearances” (Selsam & Martel, 1963, p. 183). Instead of viewing individuals as driving the social structure and change, social structure and change drive the individual. It is a subtle but fundamental difference. An alternative way of viewing it is to say that we are all a product of our environment, “the will and passions of men could be explained only by an investigation of the underlying driving forces of social development” (Selsam &

Martel, 1963, p. 183). This must influence how history is examined. Instead of focusing on the people of history, the institutions and underlying conditions become much more important. It is these underlying factors that write the immediate lines that the ‘actors’ play, though humanity as a whole is the director.

“Men make their own history, whatever its outcome may be, in that each

person follows his own consciously desired end, and it is precisely the

resultant of these many wills operating in different directions and of their

manifold effects upon the outer world that constitutes history ... But, on

the one hand, we have seen that the many individual wills active in history

8 for the most part produce results quite other than those they intended -

often quite the opposite; their motives therefore in relation to the total

result are likewise of only secondary significance. On the other hand, the

further question arises: What driving forces in turn stand behind these

motives? What are the historical causes which transform themselves into

these motives in the brains of the actors?” (extract from Engles’ Ludwig

Feuerbach (1888) cited in Selsam & Martel, 1963, p. 193).

Marx believed that dominant or hegemonic themes could be picked up in society in given times. “Each principle has had its own century in which to manifest itself. The principle of authority, for example, had the eleventh century, just as the principle of individualism had the eighteenth century. In logical sequence, it was the century that belonged to the principle, and not the principle that belonged to the century” (Marx in

Jordan (ed.), 1972, p. 192). It was these dominant themes that determined history. In order to uncover the themes it may be useful to examine specific people in history. But

(again in veiled rebuke of Hegelian reasoning) Marx has commented, “what is this but to draw up the real, profane history of men in every century and to present these men as both the authors and the actors of their own drama? But the moment you present men as the actors and authors of their own history, you arrive - by detour - at the real starting point, because you have abandoned those eternal principles of which you spoke at the outset” (cited in Jordan (ed.), 1972, p. 192).

Based on the belief that production is the major driving force of history, Marx concluded that to understand history and ultimately the future, one should focus on the

9 “stage in the development of [the] means of production and of exchange” (Marx in

Jordan (ed.), 1972, p. 199). It is changes in productive forces that rend apart old society and build new. Just as the Industrial Revolution completely destroyed the feudal agricultural system, as the old system had ‘fettered’ society’s development in line with new productive techniques. These fetters “had to be burst asunder; they were burst asunder” (Marx in Jordan (ed.), 1972, p. 199).

History as a Science

The History of Mankind can be seen as a very confusing and tumultuous story.

Wars, and alliances, revolution and conservatism, stagnation and rapid growth. Marx’s analysis of history allows us to “discover the laws governing this seeming labyrinth and chaos, namely, the theory of class struggle” (Lenin’s Teachings of Karl Marx, pp. 16 f. cited in Selsam & Martel, 1963, p. 183). The apparent contradictions within history are not symptomatic of an underlying inadequacy of our historical understanding

(necessarily) but are instead indicative of the fact that society is inherently full of conflict. It is this conflict that provides the energy for change. The study of this conflict can be far more illuminating in providing an underlying sense of the path of history, rather than the lives of the ‘historic greats’ which ignores the important and defining role played by the plebeians. It is in times of revolution, such as the Industrial Revolution, that the contradictions and conflicts, so long hidden below the surface, are exposed and can be properly examined. As Marx wrote (cited in Jordan (ed.), 1972, p. 290) when considering the massive changes in society during the later part of the nineteenth century:

10 “ The so-called Revolutions of 1848 were but poor incidents - small

fractures and fissures in the dry crust of European society. However, they

denounced the abyss. Beneath the apparently solid surface, they betrayed

oceans of liquid matter, only needing expansion to rend into fragments

continents of hard rock. Noisily and confusedly they proclaimed the

emancipation of the Proletarian, i.e., the secret of the nineteenth century,

and of the revolution of that century.”

Summative Comments

Marx’s focus, not on the actors of history, but the underlying and fundamental driving forces is ideal not only for examining the past but also for considering the future.

The script may be impossible to guess, but the plot is conceivable. This is why the methodology and philosophy are considered appropriate for considering the question at hand. This paper will focus on the changes in the role and function of the University during the Industrial Revolution, not focusing on the people, but the conflicts that became so apparent in that time, and the role played by the institution.

It is to be expected that there is not be a consistent institutional response, but that the pressures brought to bear by various elements in society will result in “the implementation of varied and contradictory policies within the life-span of a single social formation” (Tosh, 1991, p. 175). Far from being seen as failure of the theory it in fact reinforces the utility of Marx and provides opportunities to re-examine and, perhaps, understand more fully the undercurrents of institutional response to times of change.

11 “So with all the other accidents, and apparent accidents, of history. The

further the particular sphere which we are investigating is removed from

the economic sphere and approaches that of pure abstract ideology, the

more shall we find it exhibiting accidents in its development, the more

will its curve run in a zigzag. So also you will find that the axis of this

curve will approach more and more nearly parallel to the axis of the curve

of economic development the longer the period considered and the wider

the field dealt with” (Engels in a Letter to Heinz Strakenburg (1894) cited

in Selsam & Martel, 1963, p. 203).

The Industrial Revolution

Marx noted that “the division of labour which has characterized every mode of production since ancient society results in the creation of classes whose interests are mutually antagonistic” (cited in Tosh, 1991, p. 167). The combination and interaction of these working relationships give rise to the economic structure of a society. “The mode of production of material life conditions the general process of social, political and intellectual life. It is not the consciousness of men that determines their existence, but their social existence that determines their consciousness” (Marx, cited in Tosh, 1991, p.

164). As has been discussed an underlying driver of social change then is technology. A technical revolution will give rise to fundamental changes of the material productive forces of society. These changes must, according to Marx, eventually come into conflict with the existing relations of production, which have become a straightjacket (‘fetters’) to development. “Then begins an era of social revolution. The changes in the economic

12 foundation [brought about by changes in technology] lead sooner or later to the transformation of the whole immense superstructure.” (Marx, cited in Tosh, 1991, p.

167).

One of the more recent and most profound times of massive technological, economic and social upheaval was the Industrial Revolution. When discussing the

Industrial Revolution it is necessary to pick a time frame. This essay is choosing 1850 as the start of the ‘main’ Revolution, this is supported by Barraclough (1982, p. 98) who states that “the speed of change should not be exaggerated... its impact was limited before

1850 to a few industrial enclaves, and it was not until the last quarter of the nineteenth century... that the great surge forward occurred”. Also the focus is on Britain for the

Industrial Revolution “was more extensive in Britain than else where in Europe or the world, and industrialisation was to make Britain’s economy the most powerful in the world” (Black, 2000, p. 34).

The Industrial Revolution provides us with a chance to examine the role the

University plays in these times of change. Before considering specifically the University it is worth examining in some detail the technological, economic and social changes that occurred during this time.

England: Pre-Industrial Revolution

England in the time leading up to the Industrial Revolution had become relatively stagnant both in economic and social terms. There were in effect two (arguably three, if the church is accounted for separately) classes, aristocrats and peasants. Not wanting to romanticise the period but it has been argued that, although there was great inequity in

13 the system, stagnation had brought with it an amount of stability. “The system had its evils but it offered the peasants certain rights in return: he could look to his landlord for help and support in time of trouble, and his place was secure in the scheme of things”

(Burchell, 1973, p. 73).

Then there was a technological revolution. “Steam, electricity, and the self-acting mule were revolutionists of a rather more dangerous character than even citizens Barbes,

Raspail and Blanqui [notorious French revolutionaries]” (Marx in Jordan (ed.), 1972, p.

290). These technologies upset the previous balance by introducing surplus wealth into the economy.

“At first, the large majority of households continue to live on the

brink of subsistence, without the means that would enable or incline them

to claim their place in the political arena, and the ruling classes continue to

exploit their hold on government to garner a disproportionate share of the

gains from growth. Both the surge of new resources cannot be fully

controlled and some of the gains seep out. Increasing numbers are able to

rise from the depths of poverty, securing resources substantially beyond

the basic needs of bare subsistence, which allows them to gain a

respectable place in society.” (Moshe and Gradstein, 1999, p. 111)

But this revolution also shifted the focus of work from the land to the cities. New and more efficient farming techniques, coupled with mechanisation, reduced the labour requirements for agricultural production, and at the same increased the required technical skills for those who were to stay. Rural serfdom was effectively abolished. Though this

14 act in itself was arguably a positive thing, the reason behind it can be cynically addressed as not a sudden realisation of the humanity of man, but instead, much more likely, a way to abrogate the responsibility of the feudal lord from the requirement of providing for the welfare of his surfs. “Unable to make a living on the land, and deprived of his traditional income from craft-work, the peasant sought work in industry. Factories and mines offered a living, however precarious, plus the attraction of being paid in wages rather than in kind” (Burchell, 1973, p. 74).

Technology had not only changed the nature of farming but had also had its effect on industry. As Marx had identified, change in technology had led to change in the forces of production, which led ultimately and unassailably to a change in society.

Revolutionary England in the Late 19th Century

“There is one great fact, characteristic of this our nineteenth century, a fact

which no party dares deny. On the one hand, there have started into life

industrial and scientific forces, which no epoch of the former human

history had ever suspected. On the other hand, there exists symptoms of

decay, far surpassing the horrors recorded of the latter times of the Roman

Empire. In our days everything seems pregnant with its contrary...

Machinery, is gifted with the wonderful power of shortening and

fructifying human labour... [yet] we behold starving and overworking it.”

(Marx in Jordan (ed.), 1972, p. 290 - 2)

15 Societal structure was fundamentally changed during the industrial revolution, not just the make up of the constituent classes. There remained an ‘aristocracy’, but instead of blood, it was money that counted. Wealth was accumulated to the capitalist, who had invested in the technology and labour of others. Buoyed by Darwin’s assertions of the unassailable right of the fittest to survive, along with the recently gained rights to operate outside of strict government controls, capitalistic aristocracy asserted their right to treat labour as a commodity. To be used as required and then left to find its own way in the world as best it could. The owner had to offer his employees no kind of security, hiring and firing at will. His only aim was to make a profit and this meant keeping costs as low as possible. Labour was still the most expensive part of any venture, hence bargaining down wages was a constant aim (for some interesting notes on the cost of labour and accounting practices during the Industrial Revolution see Fleischman and Parker, 1997).

With so many poor and unemployed it was relatively easy to drive down wages in many unskilled occupations.

“Thus there was a Natural Law of Supply and Demand, a Natural Law of

Diminishing Returns, an Iron Law of Wages, which made labour a

commodity, subject to the fluctuations of supply and demand. The owners

of capital believed that these laws were immutable and that if they were

permitted to function without restrictions they would eventually lead to the

greatest good for the greatest number. In practice, they led to great profits

for a very few and to great misery for countless others.” (Burchell, 1973,

p. 77).

16 There also came into existence an intrinsically new class, the so-called middle- class, “men engaged in the professions, in manufacture, in commerce, in civil service or in shopkeeping; they worked for their living but earned sufficient surplus to participate in the capitalistic adventure” (Burchell, 1973, p. 56). Marx’s bourgeoisie.

Finally there were those at the bottom of the social pyramid. Though there had always been the poor, the class was reconstituted from the serf (land based) to the proletariat (city based). “... artisans, miners, skilled mechanics and unskilled labourers, most of them uprooted peasants and craftsmen, who struggled to survive on precarious wages, and who had neither share in ownership nor surplus earnings to spend for investment or amusement” (Burchell, 1973, p. 56). The situation of the poor had hardly changed, only the location. In some ways it can be argued the situation had worsened, freed from the bondage of serfdom, they also lost any of the former security offered by the village arrangement.

The capitalist exploited the labour of the workers to gain more wealth. The proletariat, without any means of production of their own, was dependent on the capitalist to continue to pay and employ them. Marx’s predictions about the inevitability of class conflict seemed likely to be realised.

“Of all the social problems faced by the Victorians, this perception, that

society was becoming rapidly divided into classes of people separated

from and hostile to each other, was felt to be the most fundamental...

England seemed an 'enchanted' land, cursed by the gods, flowing with

wealth from improved agricultural and industrial invention yet unable to

17 solve, even perhaps incapable of comprehending, the terrible problem of

poverty that such wealth had brought with it” (Keating, 1976, p. 11).

The irony of this disparity in times of such huge technological progress was not lost on the writers of the time.

“ It is to increased wealth and to increased civilization that we owe the

wide gulf which today separates well-to-do citizens from the masses. ... It

is the increased civilization of this marvelous age which has made life a

victory only for the strong, the gifted, and the specially blest, and left the

weak, the poor, and the ignorant to work out in their proper persons the

theory of the survival of the fittest to the bitter end” (George R. Sims

(1889) in How the Poor Live, cited in Keating, 1976, p. 67).

As the industrial revolution swept out of the United Kingdom and through

Europe, and similar conditions came into existence throughout the continent, the obvious differences between rich and poor did lead to violent clashes, amongst these are the Paris

Commune rising of 1871, and of course first the 1905 and later the 1917 Russian

Revolutions. With all of these changes in society, it seems inevitable that the institutions would have to be affected. Against this background it is time to consider the University.

The Commercialisation of the University during the Industrial Revolution

Changes in technology brought on by the Industrial Revolution caused a shift in the foundation of relations of production. Marx had hypothesized this would have

18 significant effects on social institutions. Although on the surface it can be argued that the institution of the University remained relatively stable, this hides the fact that there was significant internal structural realignment, which can be related to power shifts in society.

The University that emerged from this time bears little resemblance to that which had been for the previous three hundred years. It is this mould struck during the Industrial

Revolution that remains with us to this day, still significantly influencing the thinking of our time. It is relevant to also consider that it has been argued that during the height of the Industrial Revolution the University was in fact ‘rescued’ by the forces of commercialisation from descending into obscurity and insignificance. It is also of no small matter that this change was driven by the newly enfranchised middle-classes.

Going into the Industrial Revolution the University in Britain as a social institution reflected the society at large. Class divisions were maintained, with almost impenetrable barriers, between ‘commoner’ and ‘lord’. As the revolution progressed the

University system initially resisted the changes that were happening in society even as other institutions were changed through class struggle and shifts in power distributions.

“The object of education within the [English] colleges was to produce intellectuals and gentlemen who could be relied upon in a world constantly threatened, it was thought, by revolution” (Kearney, 1970, p. 22). This can be contrasted with situation in Europe where far more bloody uprisings were occurring, many led and fueled by University graduates.

“The expense of getting to Oxford and Cambridge and the fact that they

were not necessary avenues to the secular professions in the first half of

the nineteenth century helped save Britain from the over production of an

19 underpaid and underemployed University graduate class which helped fuel

Continental revolutionary movements” (Sanderson (ed.), 1975, p. 4).

This aversion to revolution was also implicit in the teaching at the Universities of the time “Historians reared [during this time]... took for granted the truth of Tennyson's judgement, that freedom slowly broadened down from precedent to precedent. This gave a comforting re-assurance that rebellions had been justly, if bloodily, repressed in earlier centuries, because they were out of due time” (Kearney, 1970, p. 178). Rothblatt (1968, p. 266) also picks up on this point

“ International trade, but especially imperial and colonial government,

fortunately rescued the University graduate, mitigating the effects of a

limited homemarket by carrying off potentially unhappy and distraught

graduates to overseas positions. Britain's imperial possessions, it appeared,

may have helped prevent the formation of an intellectual proletariat, a

functionless and therefore alienated group with forced leisure in which to

scheme against the social order”.

So although it can be said that the Industrial Revolution was approaching its height, and had indeed been underway for some time in the 1850’s, the institution of the

University itself was, quite understandably, slow to change. It is not possible to draw a line and to say that before this time all things were pre-industrial and all after were post- industrial. “There are societies within societies. Pre-industrial values survive amid industrialization. And universities may play their part as the educational organs of sub-

20 societies” (Kearney, 1970, p. 191). The changes in society led to changes in the

University, but the course of this change is not clear or easy to chart. But it is worth considering, not only as it throws light on the role of the University during times of revolution, but also provides a touchstone for considering the future of the University in these new revolutionary times. The role of the University changes, the change is driven, slowly perhaps, by the underlying state of society in which it is situated.

“ In social institutions as in living organisms, form and function are

inextricably bound together. If function changes, then form must adapt

itself or the organism - and the institution - will perish.” (Ashby, 1959, p.

67)

The Beginnings of Discontent

Much has been written on the extended history of the University and it is not the intention of this essay to review it all again. What is clear is that by the 18th Century the

University was the domain of the gentry and the church. Exclusions had been slowly introduced, when the University was first opened in the 12th Century it had been a public institution open to all (see for example Gloucester, 1980), but over time various restrictions had come into force severely limiting those who could gain entry. Two of the most alienating of these being strict religious requirements and the requirement for students to board in institutions charging high fees (the University itself kept very modest fees) (see Statement by the Council of London Explanatory of the Nature and Objectives of the Institution (1827) cited in Sanderson (ed.), 1975, p. 60). This system came under increasing scrutiny as the nineteenth century moved on.

21 “To monopolise those institutions for the rich, as is done now, is to violate

both the spirit and the letter of the foundations; ... The letter is kept - the

spirit is thrown away. You refuse to admit any who are not members of

the Church of England, say, rather, any who will not sign the dogmas of

the Church of England, whether they believe a word of them or not.

Useless formalism! which lets through the reckless, the profligate, the

ignorant, the hypocritical; and only excludes the honest and the

conscientious, and the mass of the intellectual working men... the real

reason for our exclusion, churchmen or not, is, because we are poor.”

(Charles Kingsley's Aton Locke (1850) cited in Sanderson (ed.), 1975, p.

54-5)

In addition to these ‘physical’ barriers there were deeper, underlying, social attitudes precluding those of lower socio-economic status for the University. Writers from the upper-classes attacked those of the middle-classes who tried to enter the education system. Arguments of an economic nature were employed to hold the gates of the University shut. There was a strong feeling that allowing those of the middle-classes entry would devalue education.

“Just as capitalists would at once capture education in craftmanship, seek

out what little advantage there is in it, and then throw it away, so they do

with all other education... as soon as it has ceased to be a rarity,

competition takes care that education shall not raise wages; that general

education shall be worth nothing, and that special education shall be worth

22 just no more than a tolerable return on the money and time spent acquiring

it” (William Morris (1888) in Commonweal cited in Golby (1986), p. 233).

As for the working class the arguments employed were psychological in nature

“And then supposing the worker to be really educated, to have acquired

both the information and the taste for reading... how will this treasure of

knowledge and sympathy accord with his daily life? Will it not make his

dull task seem duller? Will it not increase the suffering of the workshop or

the factory to him? And so, may he not strive to forget then strive to

remember...?” (William Morris (1888) in Commonweal cited in Golby

(1986), p. 233)

The Death of a Liberal Education, the Seeds of Commercialisation

The Universities, which at the beginning of the Industrial Revolution meant

Oxford or Cambridge, were for the wealthy, that is the gentry, the landed noble. “... in

England in the first half of the nineteenth century existing universities had merely taken a narrow élite as students and confirmed their status” (Sanderson (ed.), 1975, p. 20). But the technological change of the Industrial Revolution was a catalyst for change in social structures. Wealth accumulated in the hands of those who were best able to take advantage of the new Capitalist system. “Under pressure, the aristocracy agreed to share political power with economically more important middle classes who subsequently nationalised the University... in their own interest” (Rothblatt, 1968, p. 20).

23 Initially the effect this had on the institution of the University was minimal, if not regressive. “Their most important effect was to render the University inaccessible to the poorer classes. Far from being national, Oxford and Cambridge became more socially exclusive than ever before, a step on the climb of the parvenu bourgeoisie to status and influence” (Rothblatt, 1968, p. 20). The University continued to play the same role it had previously, a social acknowledgement that even just attendance conveyed confirmation of a certain position in society. “Increasingly, the criterion of a gentleman became membership of certain professions, the established church, law, medicine, the army, the higher civil service and the Indian civil service, banking as 'the City', and not least, politics. Entrance to these professions was largely governed by a public school education and the possession of an Oxbridge degree” (Kearney, 1970, p. 174). The role of the

Institution of the University was in fact a throw back to a previous time of stability and dependability in a society, confirming echoes of an old hierarchy, in a state of revolution.

“In a sea of rising democracy, the colleges were 'citadels of privilege'” (Kearney, 1970, p.

188). The state of the University was indicative of the slowness of some institutions to make change and “the failure of the nineteenth century to promote the moral and material welfare of the working classes commensurate with some of the more democratic claims of laissez-faire theory” (Rothblatt, 1968, p. 29).

The traditional nature of a University education had been ‘liberal’. That is that it prepared a ‘gentleman’ to think, and act morally, without encumbering him with specific skills, which could be acquired when he entered whichever service, if any, he choose upon leaving the University. The very nature of the education presupposed a level of independence from the requirements of seeking skilled employment in order to survive.

24 “Indeed, such an education fitting for no special livelihood was particularly apt for those who had no need to earn a living or whose position was assured.” (Sanderson (ed.), 1975, p. 1/2).

“ The weight of most articulate opinion concerning University education

up to and in the mid-nineteenth century was firmly against the use of

universities for vocational training as distinct from liberal education. ...

while admitting the utility of 'those arts and studies which relate to the

improvement of manufactures' ... a University education should not relate

to specific employments but should improve the individual by imbuing

him with sound principles of policy and religion.” ( Sanderson, 1972, p. 4)

Yet as has already been identified the University is an institution and therefore it is reflective of the struggle between classes brought about by the fundamental changes to the nature of production brought about by the Industrial Revolution. These changes did occur, if somewhat slowly, as expected. In fact some would argue that the Industrial

Revolution was almost over before the University realised all the changes it would have to undertake to remain relevant. “... scientific thought, which by 1800 was already consolidated in the foundations of modern physics and chemistry... had scarcely influenced the universities of England. The scientific revolution had occurred not through, but in spite of, the English universities” (Ashby, 1959, p. 13). Those who had launched and propelled the Industrial Revolution had not been men from the Universities.

This trend continued throughout most of the nineteenth-century, “innovation came most commonly by the modification of existing technologies by experienced and observant

25 men on the job unattached to any formal organization for the diffusion of science and still less involved with the universities.” (Sanderson, 1972, p. 2)

During this time, and particularly by the middle of the nineteenth century, it was increasingly recognised that a strong scientific grounding was important for national success and prosperity (see for example the Speech by Prince Albert at the opening of the

Great Exhibition, cited in Golby, 1986, p. 1 - 2). Yet the universities refused “to meet the social and educational challenge of industrialism... they showed themselves incapable of necessary self-reform” (Rothblatt, 1968, p. 18). Science, which was so important to

Britain was being ignored by the educated. Instead scientific education was originally restricted to a “small minority of the working classes who could read and write : the craftsman, the foreman, the mechanic” (Ashby, 1959, p. 51). Admittedly there was some interest in the ‘pure sciences’ but the manner of education was very esoteric and theoretical.

“There was practically no exchange of ideas between the scientists and the

designers of industrial processes. The very stratification of English society

helped to keep science isolated from its applications : it was admitted that

the study of science for its useful applications might be appropriate for the

labouring classes, but managers were not attracted to the study of science

except as an agreeable occupation for their leisure.” (Ashby, 1959, p. 51)

Education became a social issue of concern to the state and the universities were forced to begin their transformation “into national institutions providing for national needs and in the service of the entire nation; no longer were they to be useful merely to

26 clergy, gentry and aristocracy” (Rothblatt, 1968, p. 18). The University moved away from a liberal education towards a more practically orientated curriculum. Yet the introduction of science did not immediately change the institution. “By the 1870's Oxford and Cambridge were ready to accept experimental science as an ingredient in education; but they were not prepared to jettison their cherished ideals of a liberal education in favour of the ideal of the University as a research institution” (Ashby, 1959, p. 49). It is interesting to note that the change of the style of education was seen as extremely threatening in some parts of the University system

“ Were research to become accepted alongside teaching as a major

function of the universities then much of the clear-cut traditional authority

of the old subjects would be eroded as students no less than teachers

would be expected to question and inquire as they saw old truths replaced

by new uncertainties” (Sanderson (ed.), 1975, p. 7).

Over time the introduction of science did begin to affect the functioning of the

University for two reasons. First research, or the adjunction of knowledge, became important. No longer was the main function of the University “transmitting a received body of knowledge, in teaching rather than in the creation of new subjects or areas of inquiry through research” (Sanderson (ed.), 1975, p. 6). In addition political pressure was brought to bear, preferencing knowledge that was of practical value to the realm.

Once the change started it happened quickly. Although “the universities were slowly and clumsily aligning themselves to the massive currents of thought which flowed from the scientific revolution”(Ashby, 1959, p. 77), by the end of the nineteenth century

27 the University had fundamentally changed reflecting in many ways the changes in society. “[T]he British universities learned not to drag their feet at the back of the procession of scientific thought” (Ashby, 1959, p. 16). Ashby (1959) goes on to argue that in many ways the University managed to move itself out of a rut it had got into over the preceding three hundred years, and moved back much closer to its ‘truer prototype’.

The pressure of the Industrial Revolution was renewing for the University. Forcing a realignment of the institution with the society it was in. It had to demonstrate “the social flexibility of function requisite for survival” (Sanderson (ed.), 1975, p. 23) in times of revolution. “In accomplishing this adaptation the universities have recovered their prestige and influence without losing their identity” (Ashby, 1959, p. 16).

The industrial revolution and the social changes it brought had, by the end of the nineteenth century greatly affected the institution of the University. At the beginning of the century a liberal education was the preserve of the societal elite. But the increasing importance of new methods of production based on scientific principles and advancements, brought pressure to change both the nature and the purpose of the

University towards research and practical education and also those who were to be educated. “Traditional ideas of the liberal education were eroded and professional and vocational teaching, scientific studies and original research became accepted within the orbit of University activities... The universities as a whole began to become social engines of social mobility rather than confirmers of existing social structure” (Sanderson

(ed.), 1975, p. 22).

During these changes there was also a move towards the comercialisation of the

University. Again initially resisted, “it was never considered that the industrialist, as

28 such, should stand beside the canon lawyer, the gentleman, or the cleric as the proper recipient and creations of a University education” (Sanderson, 1972, p. 1). Those involved in commercial activities were regarded with some suspicion and also as the majority of students were there from the church and “the established Church was traditionally associated with the landed classes, and not with commerce” (Kearney, 1970, p. 177). However “Shifts in social class of intake were also matched by those in final career choice. At Cambridge there was a radical change in the occupations of students with the Church's share falling from 62 per cent to 38 per cent in the second half of the century, and with administration, business and the professions taking up what the church had lost” (Sanderson (ed.), 1975, p. 18). The industrialist with a commercial and practical background was becoming increasingly important.

It should also be noted that it was during this time the monopoly on University education that had been held by Oxford and Cambridge was broken. New universities were established around England to educate the new middle class that was driving the industrial revolution. “The students of the civic universities did tend to come from industrial and commercial backgrounds and more from the middle- and upper- classes than from the working-class” (Sanderson, 1972, p. 119). Manchester University was established in 1851, and based on the philosophy of Arthur Barnes, that has become a foundation of teaching in many University courses.

“I shall imagine to myself a system of education for a commercial

man which shall contain all the parts of science proper for him to

know, as much as possible in practical form and which amidst all

29 the other objects of study shall keep this point continually in view”

(cited in Kearney, 1970, p. 179).

The Institution As It Was - As It Is.

The University emerged for the Industrial Revolution fundamentally changed from the institution that entered. Forces that had sprung from technological change had affected labour relations and consequently recast social structure. In the broadest context it could be argued that two of these forces, which directly acted on the University were the pressures of utility and democracy. Utility was “the conviction that, in an industrial civilisation, higher education should contribute toward economic stability in peace and security in war” (Ashby, 1959, p. 41). Democracy brought with it increased political power to the middle classes, and a weakening of dichotomous social stratification that had previously existed. The joint effect of these pressures was to open up the University, in many ways, to a wider cross section of disciplines and students.

And yet the institution still seems insecure about its position in society. Debates about the nature of education bubble to the surface, with many academics wistfully harking back to the ideas of Cardinal Newman, a University education for its own sake.

Ashby (1959, p. 69 - 70) identifies this as early as the middle of the last century in terms of a split personality:

“ The symptoms are caused simply by the fact that adaptation is

incomplete. The consequences of incomplete adaptation is tension... And

so universities find themselves searching for a compromise. On one hand

they cannot bring themselves to refuse the responsibilities laid upon them

30 by modern society, nor the large financial grants which accompany these

responsibilities. On the other hand, they cling to their traditional

organisation and curricula in the hope that the values for which

universities stood in the Middle Ages may be preserved among the

automatic factories and social planning and satellite-ridden stratosphere of

the third millennium”

Yet it may not just be that the adaptation is incomplete. The world moves on.

Revolutions continue to develop. The end of the last world war saw the beginnings of a new revolution. Then called the Information Revolution. Now recognized as being much broader than that, and talked of in terms of Globalisation. However it is named, the consequences are the same. Technology changes the structure of society and the relations within it, this leads inevitably to new forces pushing change onto institutions. And this can be perceived clearly again in this new century.

The Global Revolution

Few would deny that we appear to be entering a new phase of human development. Driven by technological changes, where once technology multiplied the physical ability of man, it now affects our very ability to think, to create and to innovate.

The ramifications of these changes can only be described as global in their nature and effect. This new revolution will bring about fundamental change to all of human society.

This must also have an effect on human institutions.

31 “We are constantly advised that the internet will have the same impact on

the human race as the Industrial Revolution or, in more distant days, the

invention of the plough. It will involve the creation of new technology

which will be applied to many human activities.

It will not replace unique human capacities such as imagination

and the ability to communicate. It will remain a means to an end, but the

end has to be determined by man. It may turn the world upside down and

force changes far beyond those that are presently foreseen.

Those who wish to control commercial activities must emulate

their predecessors who profited from the Industrial Revolution in

identifying the essential features of the new order and consequently of

their own individual entities and, regardless of the costs, support and

control that which creates the wealth they seek” (Bartlett, 2000, p. 18).

Conclusion Brief Comments on the future of the University

The point of this paper was to consider the future of the University in light of the past. The past history of the University clearly indicates that it is an institution inextricably bound up in the social framework, subject to forces of change. Required to change if it is to remain viable and relevant. Yet the level and direction of change must be carefully considered. As Rothblatt (1968, p. 15) noted “The modern University is like

Proteus, many things at once, and the colour or form it assumes depends on how it is viewed or grasped. The functions it must perform for industrial society are almost beyond imagination”.

32 As the future direction of the University is considered the words of Lord Ashby from nearly 50 years ago seemed to identify the heart of the issue:

“ The social institution we call a University has endured now for seven

centuries. It could have been destroyed, either by resisting pressure to

change and so losing its viability, or by yielding too readily to change and

so losing its integrity. But it has survived by adapting itself to ...

revolution without abdicating its traditional function in society.” (Ashby,

1959, p. 97)

From here it is difficult to identify the future direction of the University. But it seems clear that technological change, that so dramatically affects the way individuals interact with each other, the way society itself is constructed, will drastically influence the institution we call the University. These effects are already being evidenced today.

Academics, the soul of the University, must measure their response. To refuse to accept the requirements for change, or worse still try and hark back to a previous time, would surely condemn the University to a loss of relevance, obscurity and possibly eventual death. Change too quickly, or just for the sake of change, and the University will be in danger of losing its vitality and position within the social structure as it moves too far from the those values which make it so necessary and unique.

What is required is measured change. The future cannot be known. But the past provides valuable insight and must be used to throw light on any debate if it is to be adequately informed and useful.

33 “ Nevertheless, when projecting into the future, objectivity and integrity remain idealistic attributes. The arena in which the play takes place is itself highly competitive and as ruthless as any gladitorial circus. Those who succeed are those who satisfy their superiors. As a consequence their contribution to the task of decision-making is often governed more by political than by economic considerations. Human nature being what it is, it is highly unlikely that objectivity and integrity will be welcomed where its application might cast a shadow over the perceived competence of the senior management. If there is to be a messenger of bad tidings from the past which may adversely affect the future, then it would be better for the company that he should not be dependent upon that company for his living.” (Bartlett, 2000, p. 17)

Ominis Caro Foenum All Flesh is Hay

34 References

Ashby, E. (1959), Technology and the Academics, New York, MacMillan and Co. Ltd.

Barraclough, G. (1982), The Times Atlas of World History, London, Times Books.

Bartlett, A. (2000), “Philosophy and Experience”, Management Accounting, April 2000, pp. 16 – 18.

Black, J. (2000), “Britain 1800”, History Today, November 2000, pp. 29 – 35.

Burchell, S. (1973), Age of Progress, Nederland, Time.

Feuer, L. (ed.) (1969), Marx and Engles: Basic Writings on Politics and Philosophy, UK, Fontana.

Fleischman, R. and L. Parker (1997), What is Past is Prologue: Cost Accounting in the British Industrial Revolution, 1760 – 1850, New York, Garland Publishing.

Golby, J, (1986), Culture and Society in Britain: 1850 – 1890, UK, Oxford University Press.

Gloucester, R. (1980), Oxford and Cambridge, New York, Thames and Hudson.

Jordan, Z. (ed.) (1972), Karl Marx: economy, class and social revolution, London, Nelson.

Keating, P. (1976), Into Unknown England 1866 – 1913, UK, Manchester University Press.

35 Kearney, H, (1970), Scholars and Gentlemen: Universities and Society in Pre-Industrial Britain - 1500 – 1700, UK, Faber and Faber.

Moshe, J. And M. Gradstein (1999), “The Industrial Revolution, Political Transition, and the Subsequent Decline in Inequality in 19th-Century Britain”, Explorations in Economic History, 36(2), pages 109-27.

Rothblatt, S. (1968), The Revolution of the Dons - Cambridge and Society in Victorian England, UK, Faber and Faber Ltd.

Sanderson, M. (1972), The Universities and British Industry 1850 – 1970, London, Routledge & Kegan Paul.

Sanderson, M. (ed.) (1975), The Universities in the Nineteenth Century, London, Routledge & Kegan Paul.

Selsam, H. and H. Martel (1963), Reader in Marxist Philosophy, United States of America, International Publishers.

Tosh, J. (1991), The Pursuit of History, London, Longman.

36

Recommended publications