Three Years Or Six to Audit? Substance and Procedure in Intermountain

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Three Years Or Six to Audit? Substance and Procedure in Intermountain

1 Three Years or Six to Audit? Substance and Procedure in Intermountain

Tax code 6501(a) says that in general the IRS cannot audit a taxpayer more than three years of when the tax is due but the limit is six years if the taxpayer “omits from gross income an amount properly includible therein which is in excess of 25 percent of the amount of gross income stated in the return.”

In Intermountain, the IRS waited more than three years but less than six to tell Intermountain it had reported too low an asset basis in computing capital gains. After losing in a 13-judge review Tax Court decision unanimous in the result, the IRS issued new regulations making six years the limit and successfully pleaded for Chevron in its appeal to the D.C. Circuit. Lots of other appeals turn on the same issue and the circuits are split, so the Supreme Court

1 2 will likely hear the case.

ISSUES

ISSUE ONE: Is “to state too low a basis” included in “to omit from gross income”?

ISSUE TWO. Did the D.C. Circuit correctly give Chevron deference to the new rules, as opposed to using its best judgement as to how the statute should be interpreted?

2 3

MY ANGLE: In looking at both issues, it is crucial to think about the costs and benefits of changing to the six-year rule.

Doing so helps show that “to omit from gross income” means “to leave out” and not “to include but falsely report” because there are sound reasons to have a shorter audit time for tax return items that require taxpayer recordkeeping than for those that do not.

The DC Circuit wrongly gave Chevron deference because it is clear the executive branch made no attempt to evaluate cost and benefits, so its rulemaking procedure was invalid and fails. In addition, the sloppy executive decisionmaking provides an argument against Chevron deference itself as opposed to mere prudent consideration

3 4 by the courts of executive-branch arguments.

WHAT I NEED TO DO TO WRITE THE PAPER The trickiest part of writing the paper is to do or talk about doing the cost-benefit analysis. It is easy to show that the IRS didn’t do it, which is all that the law part of the paper really requires. But it seems nobody in law-and-economics or law has seriously thought about how long statutes of limitations should be, so I’d like to do that in this paper. Thus, I want to list the costs and benefits, generally and for tax laws, and I want to do at least a back-of-the- envelope calculation.

4 5

QUESTIONS FOR THE AUDIENCE

1. How should I estimate the increased cost of recordkeeping from increasing the statute of limitations to 6 years for capital gains?

2. What are the costs and benefits of a longer statute of limitations for tax, civil, and criminal law?

3. Has anyone ever written on the optimal statute of limitations (a) in any area of law, and (b) in tax?

5 6

4. What are the recordkeeping requirements for capital gains basis? 5. Can an administrative law APA challenge be made to IRS rules that do not go through notice and comment?

6 7

II. The 6-Year Limit Is a Hasty and Ill-Considered Rule.

Tax Advisors and Even the IRS Website Thinks the Statute of Limitations Is Three Years for Capital Gains Basis, Not Six.

The most compelling example is from the IRS itself, on the main taxpayer information webpage dealing with record-keeping:

“How long should the records related to a business or other long-term asset be kept? In the case of an asset, records related to the asset should generally be kept for as long as you have the asset plus three years.”

7 8

WHAT IS THE COMMON LAW?

If we thought of using the logic of the common law, which is to look at the customs of the nation, the market, or the industry, a judge who is “discovering the law” would fail to find any support for the 6-Year Limit. It is an unfilled gap in the law only insofar as the issue has never been formally written down in a court reporter; many many people have looked at the specific issue of how long the statute of limitations is for underestimating capital gains and failed to see any gap at all.

8 9 Millions of Taxpayers Will Have Trouble Justifying the Incomes They Have Truthfully Reported.

142 million personal income tax returns filed.

8 million had a net gain reported on Schedule D, 12 million a net loss.

5 million with net gains and 8 million with net losses had incomes of less than $100,000.

This does not include corporations and trusts. So we have 20 million total returns. Assume 30 million people over 3 years, lots of overlap. 10 million people will have positive costs of keeping extra stuff.

9 10 Even Once Taxpayers Have Adjusted, the 6-Year Limit Will Impose Heavy Costs

MENTAL COSTS (a) some records need to be kept for six years, some for three (b) in particular, capital gains records need to be kept for six years, and everything else for three. This is more than a doubling of the complexity of the recordkeeping time rules. I should find out how many steps the two regimes cost, using the methodology Turing developed for computer science to measure the size of a computer program (the necessary preliminary to his proof that particular tasks are “computable” or not).

We have replaced the rule “all records need to be kept for three years” with the rule “all but one kind of tax record need to be kept for three years, and that one has to be kept for six.” 140 million personal income tax returns , so if $1`/extra mental effort is $1/return, $140million/year.

10 11

The other part of the record-keeping cost is the cost of keeping records for an additional 3 more years. Part of this cost is the cost of the physical space or the computer disk space, but most of it is the mental cost of having to look over extra records to find particular information needed for any objective and the mental cost of remembering which records to retain and which can be thrown away.

Using our estimate of 30 million taxpayer-years of extra record-keeping, if the cost per taxpayer-year, if these two costs amount to $3/taxpayer-year, the total cost is $90 million/year, which when capitalized at 5% amounts to $1.8 billion dollars.

The total cost of the 6-year rule is $4.6 billion, at a very rough estimate.

11 12 D. The Optimal Statute of Limitations Trades Off Detecting More Cheating against Incurring More Record-Keeping Costs.

Does anyone know of articles on the optimal length of statutes of limitations?

The optimal statute of limitations will trade off the cost of record-keeping against the injustice of unpaid taxes and the loss of legitimate government revenue.

E. The Tradeoff between Compliance and Costs Is Good Reason For a Three-Year Limit for Tax Items that Require Taxpayer Recordkeeping and Six-Year for Items that Don’t.

12 13

Colony said:

“We think that, in enacting § 275(c), Congress manifested no broader purpose than to give the Commissioner an additional two years to investigate tax returns in cases where, because of a taxpayer's omission to report some taxable item, the Commissioner is at a special disadvantage in detecting errors. In such instances, the return, on its face, provides no clue to the existence of the omitted item. On the other hand, when, as here, the understatement of a tax arises from an error in reporting an item disclosed on the face of the return, the Commissioner is at no such disadvantage.”

Courts that have reached to the issue (instead of using Chevron deference) have reasoned that “to omit” does not mean “to understate”.

13 14 F. The Rulemaking Process Followed Here Has Been So Flimsy that Nobody Has Even Noticed These Arguments, Much Less Addressed Them.

The IRS didn’t do the cost-benefit analysis that “significant regulatory actions” require, even though millions of people are affected by this regulation.

“It has been determined that this notice of proposed rulemaking is not a significant regulatory action as defined in Executive Order 12866. Therefore, a regulatory assessment is not required. It also has been determined that section 553(b) of the Administrative Procedure Act (5 U.S.C. chapter 5) does not apply to these regulations and because these regulations do not impose a collection of information on small entities, the Regulatory Flexibility Act (5 U. S.C. chapter 6) does not apply. Pursuant to section 7805(f) of the Internal Revenue Code, these regulations have been submitted to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small Business Administration for comment on their impact on small business.” i

14 15

Justice Scalia, unlike the other Justices in Brand-X, confronts the big question directly: Must the Supreme Court itself defer to the executive agency?

“Imagine the following sequence of events: FCC action is challenged as ultra vires under the governing statute; the litigation reaches all the way to the Supreme Court of the United States. The Solicitor General sets forth the FCC's official position (approved by the Commission) regarding interpretation of the statute. Applying Mead, however, the Court denies the agency position Chevron deference, finds that the best interpretation of the statute contradicts the agency's position, and holds the challenged agency action unlawful. The agency promptly conducts a rulemaking, and adopts a rule that comports with its earlier position--in effect disagreeing with the Supreme Court concerning the best interpretation of the statute. According to today's opinion, the agency is thereupon free to take the action that the Supreme Court found unlawful. ” (Scalia dissent, Brand-X)

15 16 Could Congress to write as part of a statute that it is to be interpreted by a panel of nine members chosen by the President? The Courts would be left only with the authority to declare the panel’s rulings arbitrary and capricious.

16 17

Intermountain and the 2011 Stern v. Marshall bankruptcy case make for an interesting comparison. In Stern v. Marshall, a federal Bankruptcy Judge decided a claim of state tort law that was peripherally relevant to a bankruptcy case. Afterwards, the state court decided the claim differently. The question is which decision the federal District Court should take as the final judgement. That decision was appealed up to the U.S. Supreme Court. The majority decided the case narrowly, saying that the Bankruptcy Court could not enter final judgement in a state law counterclaim:

Thus, Stern v. Marshall says that a Bankruptcy Court’s findings on state law counterclaims, at least (it was a narrow holding),cannot constitutionally be final judgements.

17 18

Combining Stern v. Marshall with Brand-X gives us this view of current Supreme Court thinking: We can trust those guys in ATF and the FBI to be prudent and intelligent, and we can trust those guys in the IRS to be restrained in their claims for executive authority, but when it comes to the court-appointed bankruptcy judges --- reckless, emotionally involved, power-mad, and pea- brained--- watch out!

The Supreme Court thinks it can decide policy questions such as whether homosexuality and abortion should be legal, and operational questions, such as the fine details of police search procedure, but it is neither qualified nor empowered to interpret the words of statutes. If a court is objective and wise enough to decide when human life begins, surely it can figure out what “omits from gross income” means.

What are appellate judges good at, if not at figuring out the meaning of words?

18 19

I suspect that the reason the Supreme Court was willing to adopt Chevron was at least partly that the Justices do think their personal opinions on abortion and homosexuality are more reliable than their personal opinions on tax law and telecommunications.

Tax law, like mathematics and accounting, is an unmerciful subject. It is easy to show that someone is objectively wrong and make them look stupid.

Or, putting it differently, it is easy to demonstrate one’s own stupidity, to oneself and to others. There is no royal road to geometry, but nobody ever said that about political opinions.

Lots of people say they are no good at math, but nobody says they just can’t make good political judgements.

19 20 Yet it is perhaps in tax cases—particularly business tax cases--- that even those judges have the most advantage over the median voter.

A judge may find tax cases boring and difficult, but he has a better chance of understanding them than most people, which is not so clear when it comes to the more glamorous areas of the law where justice matters more and close reading matters less.

It is, moreover, in the boring areas of the law that we can expect judges to face the least temptation to impose their own preferences instead of trying to follow the law. “The more boring the case, the better the law.”

Politicians, in contrast, while also having neutral ideological preferences, can use the opacity of tax law to transfer large sums of money to sophisticated supporters or to conceal extravagance with public funds.

20 21

21 22

Cases Intermountain Insurance Service of Vail v. Commissioner of Internal Revenue Service, 134 T.C. No 11 (2010) reversed, No. 10-1204 (June 21, 2011) (DC Circuit, 2011) Crowell v. Benson, 285 U.S. 22 (1932) Mayo Foundation v. U S., 131 S.Ct. 704 (2011) Dobson v. Commissioner, 320 U.S. 489 (1943) Grapevine Imports, Ltd. v. United States, 636 F.3d 1368 (Fed. Cir. 2011) Skidmore v. Swift & Co., 323 U.S. 134 (1944) Home Concrete & Supply, LLC v. United States, 634 F.3d 249 (4th Cir. 2011) Colony Inc. v. Commissioner, 357 U.S. 28 (1958) Burks v. United States, 633 F.3d 347 (5th Cir. 2011) Simon v. E. Ky. Welfare Rights Org., 426 U.S. 26 (1975) Stern v. Marshall, (U.S., No. 10–179, June 23, 2011) Northern Pipeline Constr. Co. v. Marathon Pipe Line Co. , 458 U.S. 50 (1982)

Chevron UNIVERSITY OF S.A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, 467 U.S. 837 References (1984) Robert A. Anthony (1996) “The Supreme Court and the APA: Sometimes They Just Don't Finlay v. Canada (Minister of Finance), [1986] 2 S.C.R. 607 Get It,” 10 Administrative Law Review, 1.

Hemmings v. Barian, 822 F.2d 688 (7th Cir.1987, Posner, J.) Kenneth A. Bamberger & Peter L. Strauss (2009) “Chevron’s Two Steps,” 95 Virginia Law Review, 611. Smiley v. Citibank, 517 U.S. 735 (1996) Eric M. Braun (1987) “Note: Coring the Seedless Grape: A Reinterpretation of Chevron th First Chicago NBD Corp. v. Commissioner, 135 F.3d 457 (7 Cir., Posner. J., 1998) aff’g U.S.A. Inc. v. NRDC,” 87 Duke Law Journal, 986. 96 T.C. 421 (1991) Estate of McLendon v. Commissioner, T.C. Memo 1996-307 (quoting Stubbs, Overbeck & th Sanford N. Caust-Ellenbogen (1991) “Blank Checks: Restoring the Balance of Powers in Assocs. v. United States, 445 F.2d 1142, 1146-47 (5 Cir. 1971)) the Post-Chevron Era,” 32 Boston College Law Review, 757.

Patrick D. Hoctor v. United States Department of Agriculture, 82 F.3d 165 (7th Cir. 1996, Linda R. Cohen & Matthew L. Spitzer(1994) “Solving the Chevron Puzzle,” 57 Law & Posner, J.) Contemporary Problems, 65.

Christiansen v. Harris County, 529 U.S. 576 (2000) Frank B. Cross & Emerson H. Tiller (1998) “Essay, Judicial Partisanship and Obedience to Legal Doctrine: Whistleblowing on the Federal Courts of Appeals,” 107 Yale Law Journal, United States v. Mead Corp., 533 U.S. 218 (2001) 2155.

Nat’l Cable & Telecomms. Ass’n v. Brand X Internet Servs., 545 U.S. 967 (2005) Davidson, Beth (2011) “Tax Policy or Treasury Policy? Treasury’s Conflicted Position in Its Ownership Stakes under TARP.” Long Island Care at Home, Ltd. v. Coke, 551 U.S. 157 (2007) Maureen B. Callahan (1991) “Must Federal Courts Defer to Agency Interpretations of Salman Ranch Ltd. v. United States, 573 F.3d 1362 (Fed. Cir. 2009) Statutes?: A New Doctrinal Basis for Chevron U.S.A. v. Natural Resources Defense Council,” 1991 Wisconsin Law Review, 1275. Salman Ranch v. United States, ___ F.3d ___, 2011 WL 2120044 (10th Cir. May 31, 2011) John F. Duffy (1998) “Administrative Common Law in Judicial Review,” 77 Texas Law Bakersfield Energy Partners v. Commissioner, 128 T.C. 207 Review,113. (2007), aff’d, 568 F.3d 767 (9th Cir. 2009)

22 23 William N. Eskridge, Jr. & Philip P. Frickey (1992) “Quasi-Constitutional Law: Clear Orin S. Kerr (1998) “Shedding Light on Chevron: An Empirical Study of the Chevron Statement Rules as Constitutional Lawmaking,” 45 Vanderbilt Law Review, 593. Doctrine in the U.S. Courts of Appeals,” 15 Yale Journal on Regulation, 1.

William N. Eskridge, Jr. (1991) “Overriding Supreme Court Statutory Interpretation Douglas W. Kmiec (1988) “Judicial Deference to Executive Agencies and the Decline of Decisions,” 101 Yale Law Journal, 331 (presenting evidence that Congress monitors the Nondelegation Doctrine,” 2 Administrative Law Journal, 269. judicial statutory interpretation decisions closely and often overrides such decisions). Gary Lawson (1996) “Outcome, Procedure and Process: Agency Duties of Explanation for Cynthia R. Farina (1989) “Statutory Interpretation and the Balance of Power in the Legal Conclusions,” 48 Rutgers Law Review,313. Administrative State,” 89 Columbia Law Review, 452. Gary S. Lawson (1997) “Comment, Reconceptualizing Chevron and Discretion: A Mitchell M. Gans (2002) “Deference and the End of Tax Practice,” Real Property Probate Comment on Levin and Rubin,” 72 Chicago-Kent Law Review, 1377. & Trust Journal 36:731-xxx. Gary Lawson (1992) “Proving the Law,” 86 Northwestern University Law Review, 859. Ernest Gellhorn & Paul Verkuil (1999) “Controlling Chevron-Based Delegations,” 20 Cardozo Law Review, 989. Ronald M. Levin (1985) “Identifying Questions of Law in Administrative Law,” 74 Georgia Law Journal, 1. Sanford N. Greenberg (1996) “Who Says It's a Crime?: Chevron Deference to Agency Interpretations of Statutes That Create Criminal Liability,” 58 University of Pittsburgh Ronald M. Levin (1997) “The Anatomy of Chevron: Step Two Reconsidered,” 72 Chicago- Law Review, 1. Kent Law Review, 1253.

Marci A. Hamilton (1999) “Representation and Nondelegation: Back to Basics,” 20 Jerry L. Mashaw (1991) “Textualism, Constitutionalism, and the Interpretation of Federal Cardozo Law Review, 807. Statutes,” 32 William & Mary Law Review, 827.

Steve Johnson (1998) “The Phoenix and the Perils of the Second Best: Why Heightened Jonathan Masur (2007) “Judicial Deference and the Credibility of Agency Commitments,” Appellate Deference to Tax Court Decisions Is Undesirable,” Oregon Law Review, 77: 60 Vanderbilt Law Review, 1021. 385. Thomas W. Merrill (1994) “Textualism and the Future of the Chevron Doctrine,” 72 Lederman, Leandra (2011) “Hold the Mayo…” March 2011. Washington University Law Quarterly, 351.

Lederman, Leandra & Stephen W. Mazza (2010) “Limitation by Regulation: Heads the Thomas W. Merrill & Kristin E. Hickman (2001) “Chevron’s Domain,” 89 Georgia Law Service Wins, Tails Taxpayer Loses?” ABA Section on Taxation News Quarterly, 30:7. Journal, 833.

Jonathan T. Molot (2000) “The Judicial Perspective in the Administrative State: Michael Herz (1992) “Deference Running Riot: Separating Interpretation and Lawmaking Reconciling Modern Doctrines of Deference with the Judiciary's Structural Role,” 53 Under Chevron,” 6 Administrative Law Journal American University, 187. Stanford Law Review, 1.

David M. Hasen(2000) “The Ambiguous Basis of Judicial Deference to Administrative Henry P. Monaghan (1983) “Marbury and the Administrative State,” 83 Columbia Law Rules,” 17 Yale Journal on Regulation, 327. Review, 1.

Hickman, Kristen (2008) “A Problem of Remedy: Responding to Treasury’s (Lack of) Note(2006) “Implementing Brand X: What Counts as a Step One Holding?” 119 Harvard Compliance with Administrative Procedure Act Rulemaking Requirements,” George Law Review, 1532. Washington Law Review,76: 1153-1215. Richard J. Pierce, Jr. (1988) “Chevron and Its Aftermath: Judicial Review of Agency Steve R. Johnson (2009) “What’s Next in the Section 6501(e) Overstated Basis Interpretations of Statutory Provisions,” 41 Vanderbilt Law Review, 301. Controversy?, ABA SECTION OF TAX’N NEWSQUARTERLY, Fall 2009, p. 19 (summarizing the cases). Gregg. D. Polsky (2004) “Can Treasury Overrule the Supreme Court?” Boston University Law Review, 84:185.

23 24 Stuntz, William (2006) "The Political Constitution of Criminal Justice,” Harvard Law J. Mark Ramseyer and Eric B. Rasmusen (forthcoming) “Can the Treasury Exempt Its Own Review, 119: 780-851. Companies from Tax? The $45 Billion GM NOL Carryforward,” forthcoming, The Cato Papers on Public Policy, edited by Jeffrey Miron, http://rasmusen.org/papers/gm-ramseyer- Cass R. Sunstein (1990) “Law and Administration After Chevron,” 90 Columbia Law rasmusen.doc) Review, 2071. (July 1, 2011). Cass R. Sunstein (2000) “Nondelegation Canons,” 67 University of Chicago Law Review, Polsky, G. (2004) "Can Treasury Overrule the Supreme Court?" Boston University Law 315. Review, 84: 185--246. Adrian Vermeule (2003) “Mead in the Trenches,” 71 George Washington Law Review, Richards, N. (2001) "The Supreme Court Justice and 'Boring' Cases,” Green Bag 2d, 4: 347. 401--407.

Rogovin, M. and Korb, D. (2008) “The Four R's Revisited: Regulations, Rulings, Reliance, and Retroactivity in the 21st Century: A View from Within,” Duquesne Law Review 46: 223—374.

Antonin Scalia (1989) “Judicial Deference to Administrative Interpretations of Law, 1989 Duke Law Journal, 511.

Peter H. Schuck & E. Donald Elliott (1990) “To the Chevron Station: An Empirical Study of Federal Administrative Law,” 1990 Duke Law Journal, 984.

Sidney A. Shapiro & Richard E. Levy (1995) “Judicial Incentives and Indeterminacy in Substantive Review of Administrative Decisions,” 44 Duke Law Journal, 1051.

Mark Seidenfeld (1994) “A Syncopated Chevron: Emphasizing Reasoned Decisionmaking in Reviewing Agency Interpretations of Statutes,” 73 Texas Law Review, 83.

Laurence H. Silberman (1990) “Chevron--The Intersection of Law & Policy,” 58 George Washington Law Review, 821.

Smith, Patrick J. (2011) “Life after Mayo: Silver Linings,” Tax Notes, 131, p. 1251--1264, June 2011) (http://ssrn.com/abstract=1866497).

Kenneth W. Starr (1986) “Judicial Review in the Post-Chevron Era,” 3 Yale Journal of Regulation, 283.

Staudt, Nancy (2004) “Agenda Setting in Supreme Court Tax Cases: Lessons from the Blackmun Papers,” Buffalo Law Review, 52: 889-922.

Stearns, Maxwell L. (1995) “Standing Back from the Forest: Justiciability and Social Choice,” 83 California Law Review, 1309-xxxx.

Stuntz, William (1997) "The Uneasy Relationship between Criminal Procedure and Criminal Justice,” Yale Law Journal, 107: 1-76.

24 i

Recommended publications