Theory of Economic Relativity: Solution to Monetary Crises, a Critique of Current Economic Theories

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Theory of Economic Relativity: Solution to Monetary Crises, a Critique of Current Economic Theories 1 Author’s Note: By axiom (ex ante and ex post): S ≠ I In irregular monetary (currency) systems by axiom (ex ante and ex post): i ≡ p www.carlosbondone.com Translator Note: The distinction between money and currency is essential in this work. The author places the term “currency” as a more general categorization than that implied in “money”. Thus, currency can acquire whether the form of money or of credit, and this last can be regular or irregular. Carlos Bondone, Theory of Economic Relativity: solution to monetary crises, a critique of current economic theories. Copyright © 2006 by Carlos Bondone. All rights Reserved. ISBN 978-987-05-2700-8 2 THEORY OF ECONOMIC RELATIVITY Solution to MONETARY CRISES A critique of current economic theories: Austrian, Keynesian, and Quantitativist Carlos A. Bondone www.carlosbondone.com 3 CONTENTS Introduction 8 Part I SCIENCE 13 Chapter I Introductory Concepts 14 Epistemology 14 Sets 17 Physical Relativity 21 Part II ECONOMIC SCIENCE 24 Chapter II Economic Causality 25 Chapter III Economic Agent 29 Chapter IV Economic goods 34 Types of economic goods 34 How Economic Science Deals With Economic Goods 39 The Value Of Economic Goods 46 Chapter V Intertemporal Exchange 52 Economic Time 52 Intertemporal Exchange Of Economic Goods – “Theory of Economic Relativity” 54 Chapter VI Interpersonal Exchange 58 Types Of Interpersonal Exchange 62 Non-Compliance In Interpersonal Exchange 65 Interpersonal Price Of Economic Goods 66 Economic Calculation 71 Quality And Quantity In Economics 73 Chapter VII Cash 75 Money 78 4 Money Substitutes 89 Other Aspects Of Money 99 The Value Of Money 103 Virtual Money 110 The Money Regression Theorem 111 Variation Of The Value Of Money 114 The Price Of Money 115 Real (Relative) And Monetary (Absolute) Prices 116 Neutrality Of Money 117 Trust In Money – Monetary Devaluation 121 Quality And Quantity Of Money 122 Chapter VIII Credit 124 The Value Of Credit 125 The Price Of Credit –“Interest” 125 Other Aspects Of Credit 126 Credit Types 128 Accounting Consolidation As Corroboration Of The Theory Of Credit 136 Is Manipulating Circulation, Virtual, Or Bank Credit Necessary? 137 Quality And Quantity Of Credit 138 The Dangerous Credit Chain 140 Causality Of Credit 140 Chapter IX Credit And Liquidity 142 The Economy Without Money 147 Economic Relativity Revisited 148 The Theory Of Liquidity And Economic Measure 149 The Dangerous Credit Chain (Continued) 150 Consequences Of The Causality Of Credit 150 Liquidity And Economic Cycles 151 The Needs For Liquidity And Measure 152 Neutrality Of Credit 152 Paradox Of Interest 153 Part III CORROBORATION OF THE ECONOMIC THEORY ACCOUNTING 154 Chapter X Accounting As An Economic Model 155 Chapter XI Cash 161 Direct Interpersonal Exchange –“Barter” 161 Indirect Interpersonal Exchange – “Money” 164 Rigid Materialization (CID, Similar To “Barter”) 165 Monetary Accounting 166 5 Chapter XII Credit 177 Flexible Materialization – Irregular Credit (Pc) 177 Monetary Revaluation Of Economic Goods 185 Analysis Of PC As Credit 186 Flexible Materialization – PC 190 “Regular” Credit 192 Circulating Or Bank Credit – FM 193 The End Of The Corroborations 213 Part IV Synthesis, expansion and comparison of THE THEORY OF ECONOMIC RELATIVITY 215 Chapter XIII Synthesis Of The Theory Of Economic Relativity 216 The Chain Of Economic Causality 216 Interpersonal Exchange – Currency 218 The Most Relevant Aspects Deriving From “TER” 219 (Economic-accounting) Wealth Of An Economic Agent 220 The Total Wealth Equation (Micro And Macro) 222 Chapter XIV Comparative Study And Extension Of The Theory 224 Chapter XV Quantity Theory 236 Chapter XVI Keynes 251 A Synthesis of Keynes’ ideas 251 Keynes’ Ideas 267 The 45 Degree Curve 268 Total Wealth Graph 271 IS And LM Curves 273 Aggregates 277 Phillips Curve 281 Keynes Underconsumption 284 Chapter XVII Hayek 286 Hayek’s Theory 287 Part V Solution to MONETARY CRISES 312 Chapter XVIII 6 Diagnosis Of Monetary Crises 313 Chapter XIX Treatment Of Monetary Crisis 318 __________________________ Appendix – Monetary Institutions Final Words 329 Glossary Of Concepts 330 Criticized Concepts 335 Bibliography 336 Analytical Index 346 7 INTRODUCTION ▓ Object The object of this book is to present a new economic theory related to the role of time in the economy; more concretely, I can say that it is the theory of economic time. Since time transcends all existents, inevitably we shall see that from the economic theory of time derive others, such as exchange, monetary, price, money, credit, interest, and wealth theory (its existence and variations), the theory of equality (distribution of wealth), the theory of accounting as an irreplaceable model for economics, and many more. The object of this work from a social point of view, is to present an economic theory that will allow people to coexist in a society with more wealth and equality, in which each and everyone is in a better situation, with a framework of individual intellectual honesty in which each person lives by his or her own effort and not by appropriating others’ goods. This appropriation may have a monetary origin -which will be analyzed here- and/or a moral origin, which has to do with adopting the posture of an invalid and not taking on the economic responsibility that each one should. Marx proposes: from each according to his capacity, to each according to his need. We will have the opportunity to analyze this from other perspectives, as soon as we correct the scientific mistakes his moral proposal incurs in; that is, we will see how science leads us to that goal but not following the path he proposed. So, from the point of view of the social object of this book, I may also say that it seeks to attain wealth in peace; just as the wealth of nations avoids military conflict, the wealth of individuals works in the same sense, avoiding violence among them. Nevertheless, it must be clear that the main object of this book is the study of economic science and theories derived from it; the social conclusions I have summarized are a corollary or result of the scientific investigations expounded here. Before ending these brief paragraphs on the object of this book, I want to say that one way of expressing my state of mind in relation to economic theory before beginning my investigations –from which I derived the theories I present here- is to refer the reader to a paragraph in the Introduction to the Spanish edition by José Antonio de Aguirre, of the book “Monetary nationalism and international stability” by F. Hayek, edited by Ediciones Aosta. Near the end of the introduction (p. 35), de Aguirre says: “Everything seems to indicate that the most urgent task in the coming years will be to probe how we can reestablish the three pillars of economic policy that were subverted by the scientific optimism of these years, these being: a) monetary discipline, b) fiscal discipline, and c) commercial discipline. This is a congruent totality that survives as a whole when its three elements are engaged or inevitably collapses when any one of them is disengaged”. Though in this work I deal, directly or indirectly, with all three aspects, the point of monetary discipline will be prevalent. ▓ Whom this book is oriented to The fact that the present work is full of scientific theories, many of which I believe are new, does not imply that it is beyond the reach of people involved in the economy, as we all are in every instant of our existence. But it is especially within the reach of those whose work is related to economic activity. A case I especially wish to make is that the theories presented here conclude that the economy runs on accounting and financial tracks more than it does on those presented traditionally in economic models. This derives in a reformulation of econometrics and all the statistical studies used at the present time that do not consider accounting the essence of their investigations. 8 The language used in the text is simple enough so that the essential points of the theory can be understood by anyone interested in grasping the basic postulates, both the hypothesis and their corroborations, along with the immediate applications in different fields. To those not specialized in economics, and who wish to understand the basic postulates in simple form, I suggest that when coming to complicated technical sections, they should continue reading. In the end they will find it possible to grasp the essentials of the theories presented here. It will evidently be very useful for those in fields related to economic science, be they scientists, experts, specialists, advisors or teachers, to understand the whole scientific process included in a theory with greater precision, beginning with the hypotheses, their corroboration, and comparison with other existing theories, to see if it includes or surpasses them, and ending with the phase of applying science to the laboratory of life, seeking solutions for concrete problems. It should be no surprise that a scientific theory can be directed both to scientists and non scientific readers. This is due to the faster forms of knowledge transmission that we have grown used to, thanks to the information revolution. Estimates say that today the amount of knowledge at our disposal doubles every five years, while up to a few decades ago it took humanity a century to do the same. We must also consider that in one way or another all human beings are “experts” in economics, since it is the central problem for most people, in the same sense that every fan is a great coach of his or her favorite sport. I can conclude this point by saying that this book is directed to scientists, accountants, experts, advisors, investors, teachers, students, businessmen and women, statisticians and all those interested in the fate of one or more economic agents.
Recommended publications
  • A Historical Sketch of Profit Theories in Mainstream Economics
    International Business Research; Vol. 9, No. 4; 2016 ISSN 1913-9004 E-ISSN 1913-9012 Published by Canadian Center of Science and Education A Historical Sketch of Profit Theories in Mainstream Economics Ibrahim Alloush Correspondence: Ibrahim Alloush ,Department of Economic Sciences, College of Economics and Administrative Sciences, Zaytouneh University, Amman, Jordan. Tel: 00962795511113, E-mail: [email protected] Received: January 4, 2016 Accepted: February 1, 2016 Online Published: March 16, 2016 doi:10.5539/ibr.v9n4p148 URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.5539/ibr.v9n4p148 Abstract In this paper, the main contributions to the development of profit theories are delineated in a chronological order to provide a quick reference guide for the concept of profit and its origins. Relevant theories are cited in reference to their authors and the school of thought they are affiliated with. Profit is traced through its Classical and Marginalist origins into its mainstream form in the literature of the Neo-classical school. As will be seen, the book is still not closed on a concept which may still afford further theoretical refinement. Keywords: profit theories, historical evolution of profit concepts, shares of income and marginal productivity, critiques of mainstream profit theories 1. Introduction Despite its commonplace prevalence since ancient times, “whence profit?” i.e., the question of where it comes from, has remained a vexing theoretical question for economists, with loaded political and moral implications, for many centuries. In this paper, the main contributions of different economists to the development of profit theories are delineated in a chronological order. The relevant theories are cited in reference to their authors and the school of thought they are affiliated with.
    [Show full text]
  • Marginal Revolution
    MARGINAL REVOLUTION It took place in the later half of the 19th century Stanley Jevons in England, Carl Menger in Austria and Leon walras at Lausanne, are generally regarded as the founders of marginalist school Hermann Heinrich Gossen of Germany is considered to be the anticipator of the marginalist school The term ‘Marginal Revolution’ is applied to the writings of the above economists because they made fundamental changes in the apparatus of economic analysis They started looking at some of the important economic problems from an altogether new angle different from that of classical economists Marginal economists has been used to analyse the single firm and its behavior, the market for a single product and the formation of individual prices Marginalism dominated Western economic thought for nearly a century until it was challenged by Keynesian attack in 1936 (keynesian economics shifted the sphere of enquiry from micro economics to macro economics where the problems of the economy as a whole are analysed) The provocation for the emergence of marginalist school was provided by the interpretation of classical doctrines especially the labour theory of value and ricardian theory of rent by the socialists Socialists made use of classical theories to say things which were not the intention of the creators of those theories So the leading early marginalists felt the need for thoroughly revising the classical doctrines especially the theory of value They thought by rejecting the labour theory of value and by advocating the marginal utility theory of value, they could strike at the theoretical basis of socialism Economic Ideas of Marginalist School This school concentrated on the ‘margin’ to explain economic phenomena.
    [Show full text]
  • Hayek on Wiesner
    '- \ ~#'~ The Development A WILEY PUBLICATION -------------oF----- IN ECONOMICS Kenneth E. Boulding Economic Thought Consultant in Economics GREAT ECONOMISTS IN PERSPECTIVE Edited by HENRY WILLIAM SPIEGEL Professor of Economics The Catholic University of America JOHN WILEY & SONS, INC., NEW YORK CHAPMAN & HALL, LIMITED, LONDON lf77?-- ~ , '- Hayek on Wieser WESER INSPIRED an admiration coming close to worship among all who came under the spell of his powerful personality. Read­ ers of his works cannot fail to be impressed by his human greatness and universality. Those who have never met him in person will appreciate Friedrich von Wieser (1851-1926) was educated at Vienna these characteristics more fully when they are shown in the light of all and at several German universities. He held a teaching posi­ his accomplishments, including those which lie outside the field of tion in Prague until he succeeded to Menger's chair at the Uni­ economics. I shall try in the fo1lowing to combine a brief review of versity of Vienna after the latter's resignation in 1903. Wieser Wieser's work in economics with an appraisal of the whole man. is the author of the only systematic treatise on economics turned Friedrich von Wieser, an offspring of an old family of Austrian public out by the founders of the Austrian school, Social Economics servants, was born in Vienna on July 10, 1851. His father, a high (1914; English translation 1927). In this work, Wieser proves government employee, had originally intended to become a painter, and himself a master of the method of successive approximation, Wieser inherited from both parents a pronounced artistic disposition.
    [Show full text]
  • Imputation and Value in the Works of Menger, Böhm-Bawerk and Wieser
    E-LOGOS/2005 ISSN 1121-0442 _____________________________________________ Imputation and Value in the works of Menger, Böhm-Bawerk and Wieser Šimon Bi ľo University of Economics, Prague [email protected] Alford Fellow, The Ludwig von Mises Institute, July 21, 2004 Version January 10, 2005 1 Abstract: Analysis of the discussions within the first two generations of the Austrian school of economics constitutes an inevitable cornerstone of every further inquiry on the fields of the theory of value and imputation theory. Only with knowledge of Menger’s, Wieser’s and Böhm-Bawerk’s understanding of cardinalism and problems related with utility, value and their interdependence, we are apt to understand correctness or incorrectness of their positions and also positions of their followers. Thus, we could trace back cardinalist notions of utility seeded by Menger and understand later Mises’- Čuhel reformulation of the whole value theory into an ordinalistic one. Mises fully escaped the Mengerian tradition in this point and also transformed the whole theory of imputation into the theory of pricing of the factors of production. The only exception, from the point of view of imputation theory of highest importance, is his insistence on the value equation of means and ends that confused his successors and was investigated only recently. Within the context of present state of value and imputation theories, two related problems arise: “What constitutes theory of imputation, theory of value and valuation of the factors of production, today?” and “Is Menger-Böhm-Bawerkian solution of imputation theory really suitable for the explanation of the pricing process and isn’t Wieser’s objection of circularity of the imputation theory applied in price-creation justified?” These are the questions that are badly needed to be answered in order to clarify the theory in the field.
    [Show full text]
  • Epistemological Problems of Economics
    EPISTEMOLOGICAL PROBLEMS OF ECONOMICS THIRD EDITION Ludwig von Mises Translated by George Reisman Introduction to the Third Edition by Jörg Guido Hülsmann Grundprobleme der Nationalökonomie: Untersuchungen über Verfahren, Aufgaben und Inhalt der Wirtschafts- und Gesellschaftslehre (1933) Epistemological Problems of Economics Translated from the German by George Reisman Published simultaneously in the United States and Canada by D. Van Nostrand Co., 1960 Reprinted 1978 by New York University Press, with Foreword by Ludwig M. Lachmann Copyright © 1976 Institute for Humane Studies Third edition 2003 by Ludwig von Mises Institute Copyright © Bettina Bien Greaves ISBN: 0-945466-36-6 CONTENTS Introduction to the Third Edition . .ix Foreword to the 1978 Edition . .lvii Preface to the English-Language Edition . .lxv Preface to the German Edition . .lxxi 1 THE TASK AND SCOPE OF THE SCIENCE OF HUMAN ACTION . .1 I. The Nature and Development of the Social Sciences . .1 1. Origin in the historical and normative sciences . .1 2. Economics . .3 3. The program of sociology and the quest for historical laws . .4 4. The standpoint of historicism . .5 5. The standpoint of empiricism . .8 6. The logical character of the universally valid science of human action . .13 7. Sociology and economics: Some comments on the history of economic thought . .18 II. The Scope and Meaning of the System of A Priori Theorems . .24 1. The basic concept of action and its categorical conditions . .24 2. A priori theory and empirical confirmation . .28 3. Theory and the facts of experience . .32 4. The distinction between means and ends: The “irrational” . .33 III. Science and Value .
    [Show full text]
  • The Methodology of the Austrian School Economists
    The Methodology of the Austrian School Economists by Lawrence White First published in 1977 by the Center for Libertarian Studies, 200 Park Avenue South, New York, New York 10003. Revised edition copyright © 1984 by Lawrence H. White. Online edition copyright © 2003 by The Ludwig von Mises Institue. Contents I. Introduction 4 II. Carl Menger 6 III. Böhm-Bawerk and Wieser 10 IV. Ludwig von Mises 13 V. Friedrich A. Hayek 19 VI. Ludwig M. Lachmann 22 VII. Kirzner, Rothbard, and the Modern Austrian School 25 VIII. Notes 28 I. Introduction Until recently the Austrian School of Economics was a topic studied almost solely by historians of economic thought interested in the development of marginal utility theory in the late nineteenth century. Not only has the life span of the school been longer than those few decades, however, but marginalism as such has never been its real focus. Today the tradition of Austrian economics, never completely dormant, is enjoying a resurgence. Austrian economists are engaged in theoretical and applied research on a wide array of topics. What unifies this school of thought—what might be called its theme—is the methodological outlook of its members: subjectivism. The subjective approach to economic phenomena builds economic analysis upon the insight that every individual chooses and acts purposively, i.e. in pursuit of his purposes and in accordance with his perception of his options for achieving them. This approach has been the hallmark of the Austrian School from its inception in the 1870s to the present day, though different members have defended their method in different ways.
    [Show full text]
  • Phases of the Marginalist Revolution
    Phases of the Marginalist Revolution ________________________________________________________ "The conclusion to which I am ever more clearly coming is that the only hope of attaining a true system of Economics is to fling aside, once and for ever, the mazy and preposterous assumptions of the Ricardian School. Our English Economists have been living in a fool's paradise. The truth is with the French School, and the sooner we recognize this fact, the better it will be for the world." (William Stanley Jevons, Theory of Political Economy, 1871: p.xliv-xlv). "If, instead of welcoming inquiry and criticism, the admirers of a great author accept his writings as authoritative, both in their excellences and in their defects, the most serious injury is done to truth. In matters of philosophy and science, authority has ever been the great opponent of truth. A despotic calm is usually the triumph of error. In the republic of the sciences, sedition and even anarchy are beneficial in the long run to the greatest happiness of the greatest number." (William Stanley Jevons, Theory of Political Economy, 1871: p.275-6) ________________________________________________________ Contents (A) Scarcity and Utility in the Classical Schema (B) The Franco-Italian Tradition: Subjective Scarcity (C) The Holy Grail: Marginal Utility (D) The Revolution of 1871-4. (E) Consolidation: the Great Flood. (F) Aftermath: the Great Drought. (G) The Paretian Revival Selected References Back The crux of the Neoclassical theory of value is the notion of subjective scarcity. The Neoclassical answer to the famous "water-diamond" paradox is that diamonds are naturally more valuable than water not because diamonds are costlier to produce (the Classical answer), but rather because diamonds are more scarce than water.
    [Show full text]
  • In the Terms of the Interpreters of the Austrian Theory, It Is a Theory Of
    1997 Later published as: Gunning, J. Patrick. (1998) "Herbert J. Davenport's Transformation of the Austrian Theory of Value and Cost." In Malcolm Rutherford (ed.). The Economic Mind in America: Essays in the History of American Economics: London: Routledge. Herbert J. Davenport's Transformation of the Austrian Theory of Value and Cost This paper is about Herbert J. Davenport's contribution to the Austrian theory of value and cost. The term "theory of value," in today's words, means "theory of price."1 "Price" includes the prices of consumer goods and the prices of the factors of production. The theory is distinguished from a theory of barter exchange rates by the assumption that all exchanges entail the use of money. An all-inclusive theory of price would aim to discover every cause of prices in the market economy. No Austrian economist has tried to achieve this aim. The Austrians have excluded theft and deceit. Also, while being careful to recognize that money is not neutral, Austrians have presented the theory of price independently of the theory of money. By doing so, they have disregarded the demand for and supply of cash balances. Besides these, Austrian authors have typically excluded time preference as a cause in order to achieve simplicity. Finally, in this field, the Austrian theory has not tried to account for credit and the money based on credit. My point is only that when we speak of the Austrian theory of value, we are not talking about an all-inclusive theory but a special theory designed to show the relationship between the 1In the terms of the interpreters of the Austrian theory, it is a theory of one species of objective value, as opposed to subjective value (e.g., utility) or other species of objective value (the power of a commodity to produce certain effects).(Bonar, 1888, p.
    [Show full text]
  • Schumpeter and the Old Austrian School Interpretations and Influences
    Schumpeter and the old Austrian school Interpretations and influences Sandye GLORIA-PALERMO University of Saint-Etienne C.R.E.U.S.E.T., 6 rue Basse des Rives 42023 Saint-Etienne Cedex 2 [email protected] Schumpeter is at the roots of the persistent historiographic practice consisting in classifying Menger along with Jevons and Walras together as the three actors of the so-called marginalist revolution. All three are presented as the independent discoverers of very much the same marginal utility principle.1 To Schumpeter, the marginalist revolution boils down to the simultaneous and independent rediscovery of this principle. Schumpeter however acknowledges that it is not the idea of marginal utility per se which is revolutionary. Indeed, it was already formulated before by Gossen and, when expressed in basic terms, it seems to flow from mere introspection, revealing little more but a triviality. In fact, the ‘revolutionary’ label is awarded to the three authors not so much for the exposition they give of the idea that the evaluation of goods depends on the intensity of individual needs, but rather for the radical change in the orientation of economic theory this principle entails. It is a marginalist ‘revolution’ in the particular sense that totally new foundations were proposed to replace those of the classical tradition. In this sense, no doubt Menger is as much a path-breaker than Walras or Jevons.2 What is essential to Schumpeter is the acknowledgement of the marginal utility principle as basement from which the whole economic phenomena may be analysed, the acknowledgement of the primary role of human needs as driving force of economic mechanisms.
    [Show full text]
  • The Place of Mises's Human Action in the Development of Modern
    THE PLACE OF MISES’S HUMAN ACTION IN THE DEVELOPMENT OF MODERN ECONOMIC THOUGHT JOSEPH T. SALERNO he core of any system of economic theory is the explanation of how prices are determined. As Mises (1998, p. 235) himself put it, “Economics is mainly Tconcerned with the analysis of the determination of money prices of goods and services exchanged on the market.” Thus, the core of Human Action is parts three and four (pp. 201–684), entitled, respectively, “Economic Calculation” and “Catallactics or Economics of the Market Society.” In these two parts, comprising 484 pages, there is presented for the first time a complete and systematic theory of how actual market prices are determined. Of course, Mises did not create this theory out of whole cloth. In fact, the theory of price elaborated in Human Action represents the crowning achievement of the Austrian School of economics. It is the culmination of the approach to price theory originated by Carl Menger in 1871 and developed further by a handful of brilliant economists of the generation intervening between Menger and Mises. These latter included especially Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk, J.B. Clark, Phillip H. Wicksteed, Frank A. Fetter, and Herbert J. Davenport. Unfortunately, for reasons to be explained below, the entire Mengerian approach went into decline after World War I and had lapsed into nearly complete dormancy by the mid-1930s. Mises’s outstanding contribution in Human Action was to singlehandedly revive this approach and elaborate it into a coherent and systematic theory of price determination. This article is divided into sections, section 1 describes the development of the Mengerian approach to price theory up until World War I, by which time it had reached the zenith of its international influence.
    [Show full text]
  • Carl Menger on Labour
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Konan University Repository KONAN UNIVERSITY Carl Menger on Labour 著者(英) Motohiro Okada journal or Konan Economic Papers publication title volume 52 number 3・4 page range 95-152 year 2012-03-20 URL http://doi.org/10.14990/00001446 甲南経済学論集第52巻第₃・₄号 2012年₃月 Carl Menger on Labour Motohiro Okada* Abstract: This article examines Carl Menger’s thought on labour from broad points of view. Founded on his subjectivist perspective, Menger insisted on the predominance of goods of lower order over goods of higher order in value determination. He argued that wages, too, are determined according to this rule, like rent and capital interest. He denied the peculiarities of labour services and, therefore, of labour exchange. As a consequence, despite his reference to the direct impact of labour on the worker’s welfare, Menger neglected it and restricted the object of his economic study on the worker’s behaviour to labour supply in the market place. Thus, actual labour and the worker’s motivation behind it were excluded from the object. Menger refused to be labelled an adherent of laissez-faireism and approved modest state interventions in the protection of workers. He simultanesouly preached class harmony by placing emphasis on the indispensability of capital accumulation and entrepreneurship to the benefit of workers. For all his advocacy of subjectivism and respect for actuality, Menger lacked his consideration of the worker’s identity as to her/his labour performance. This identity makes the nature of labour exchange differ from that of the exchange of non-human services.
    [Show full text]
  • Socialism and Marginalism in Economics, 1870-1930
    SOCIALISM AND MARGINALISM IN ECONOMICS 1870–1930 Edited by Ian Steedman London and New York SOCIALISM AND MARGINALISM IN ECONOMICS The rise to dominance of marginalist economics coincided with a major increase in the spread of socialist ideas. As many socialist and Marxist thinkers were preoccupied with economic questions this was scarcely a development they could ignore. Socialists either had to defend Marxist economics against marginalist criticism or show that socialism and marginalism were compatible. This volume explores the varied socialist responses in a number of major European countries including Italy, France, Russia and the German- speaking countries. No one response prevailed: some socialists defended Marxist economics and rejected marginalism; others criticized Marxist economics ‘from within’ without adopting marginalism to any significant degree. Yet others sought to effect a theoretical compromise or amalgam, or, again, to advocate an outright acceptance of marginalist economics and its use in arguing for socialism. The first chapter presents the general findings on a ‘cross-country’ basis, while the remaining eight chapters provide detailed case studies. The relations between marginalism and socialism are shown to be highly complex and variable, and this book pays equal attention to the differences and the common themes. It also highlights some of the many, innovative contributions to ‘classical’ political economy, some of which were only to be rediscovered after many decades. Ian Steedman is Research Professor in Economics at Manchester Metropolitan University. He has been much influenced by Italian economists. He has worked in trade theory, capital theory and the history of economic thought (especially Ricardo, Marx, Jevons and Wicksteed).
    [Show full text]