American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2011, 101:3, 105–109 http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi 10.1257/aer.101.3.105 =

Fuel Economy, Class Mix, and Safety

By Mark R. Jacobsen*

Fuel economy standards, which are rapidly occupants, they impose a severe cost on other increasing in stringency in the , vehicles in a collision. Removing large vehicles typically alter the composition of the vehicle from the road via fuel economy standards could fleet toward smaller and lighter vehicles.1 The therefore create an improvement in overall link between these compositional changes and safety. safety has the potential to dramatically alter the My main empirical contribution is to recon- costs of saving gasoline via fuel economy regu- cile these findings by accounting for selection lation and is the issue I address here. I provide in driving safety behavior: Controlling for driver a new empirical model of accident fatality risks behavior by vehicle type allows me to isolate and combine it with a simulation model of vehi- the underlying “engineering safety” of vehicles cle fleets and fuel economy standards. and relate it to the earlier work on weight differ- This issue is particularly important given the ences. At the same time, my estimates of driver risks that driving imposes to life: More than behavior can explain the more recent findings 37,000 fatalities were recorded in US automo- that large trucks and SUVs are represented dis- bile accidents in 2008.2 Proportional increases proportionately often in fatal collisions. or decreases in this rate, even relatively small in Separating the riskiness of driving behavior magnitude, have substantial implications for the which comes from both observed and unob- cost of gasoline savings. served( factors, such as the propensity to drive on The prior literature can be divided into two dangerous roads is the central empirical chal- general strands, the first of which is summarized lenge.4 I solve it )by proxying for driving behav- in a report from the National Research Council ior using single-vehicle accidents and crash test NRC, 2002 . Based on engineering studies of results, recovering an intuitive set of estimates: vehicle( weight) and safety, they estimate that and small SUVs have the lowest risks 2,000 additional deaths annually are attributable attributable to the driver’s behavior and location, to vehicle size changes from existing fuel econ- while pickup trucks and large sedans are associ- omy standards.3 Using conservative assumptions ated with the highest risk. detailed in an Appendix available on the AER Returning to the motivating policy ques- website( , this corresponds to a cost of $1.55 per tion, I combine my new empirical results with gallon of) gasoline saved. a simple model of the automobile industry to A second, more recent set of studies empha- ask how changes in fleet composition alter fatal- size a very different feature in the data: Ted ity risks. After controlling for driver selection, Gayer 2004 , Michelle J. White 2004 , and I find that fuel economy regulation that main- Thomas( P. Wenzel) and Marc Ross (2005 ) show tains the historical separation of light trucks and that while the larger vehicles discouraged( ) by involves substantial deterioration in vehicle fuel economy standards are safer for their own safety. In contrast, I find much better safety out- comes under a unified standard that encourages manufacturers to substitute away from light * Department of Economics, University of California at trucks and into cars. San Diego, La Jolla, CA 92093 e-mail: m3jacobsen@ucsd. edu I wish to thank the University( of California Center for Energy). and Environmental Economics for generous finan- 4 Some of driving safety is well known to be correlated cial support. with observables like age, gender, and income. Important 1 An effect known in the industry as “mix-shifting,” see factors that are generally not observed include the tendency David Austin and Terry Dinan 2005 and Mark Jacobsen to drive drunk, the time of day driving occurs, types of roads 2010 for a description of the incentives.( ) used, disregard for traffic signals, or simply taste for safety. ( 2 National) Highway Traffic Safety Administration Steven D. Levitt and Jack Porter 2001 estimate drunk driv- NHTSA 2009 . ing rates using innocent vehicles( in accidents) as control, but ( 3 See Paul Portney) et al. 2003 and Robert W. Crandall in most cases the personal characteristics that go into driving and John D. Graham 1989 (for further) discussion. safety are quite difficult to measure. ( ) 105 106 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2011

Table 1—Vehicle Classes, Accident Rates, normalize the measure of driver riskiness such and Estimated Driver Effects that it multiplies the fatality risk. Values of ​ i​ ​ come from individual-level factors that may beα Vehicle Single-car Crash test Average class fatality ​rate​a​ fatality risk ​ ​ b​ ​ unobservable. The subscript s indicates bins αi of the data by time-of-day, geography, demo- Compact 14.3 1.00 1.14 graphics, and urban density—factors that 0.06 ( ) appear to significantly influence both the com- Midsize 11.3 0.93 0.98 position of the fleet and the probability of fatal 0.06 ( ) accidents. Fullsize 10.2 0.67 1.25 0.08 Combining the three terms, I model the count ( ) Small luxury 13.5 0.80 1.19 of accident fatalities as: 0.08 ( ) 1 E Z​ ​ n​ ​ ​n​ ​ ​ ​​ ​ ​​ ​ ​.​ Large luxury 11.9 0.89 1.05 ( ) (​ ijs) = ​is js αi αj βij 0.07 ( ) Small SUV 9.4 1.18 0.65 This form contains an important implicit 0.04 restriction: Behaviors that increase risk are ( ) Large SUV 12.8 1.00 1.06 assumed to have the same influence in the pres- 0.06 ence of different classes and driver types. I argue ( ) Small pickup 15.9 1.26 1.09 that this is a reasonable approximation given 0.07 ( ) that most fatal accidents result from inattention, Large pickup 18.2 1.11 1.45 drunk driving, and signal violations;5 such acci- 0.08 ( ) dents give drivers little time to alter behavior 4.9 1.09 0.39 based on attributes of the other vehicle or driver. 0.02 Given that the ​​ ​ terms include unobserv- ( ) αi a Per billion miles traveled able driving behaviors it is impossible to esti- b Standard errors in parentheses mate equation 1 alone; it can’t be separately determined if a( vehicle) class is dangerous in an engineering sense captured in or if the driv- I. Empirical Model ers who select it just( happen to driveβ) particularly badly captured in . I model the count of fatal accidents between To separate( the twoα) parameters, I include sin- each combination of vehicle classes as a gle-car accidents in the model defining ​Yis​ ​ as the Poisson random variable. Vehicle classes in count of single-car fatalities: the data represent ten sizes and types of cars, trucks, SUVs and minivans; covering all pas- 2 E Yis​ ​ nis​ ​ ​ i​​ ​ s​​ ​xi​ ,​ senger vehicles in the United States. They are ( ) (​ ) = ​ α λ listed in Table 1. where ​n​ ​ and ​ ​ ​ are as above and ​ ​ ​ flexibly is αi λs DefineZ ​​ij​ as the count of fatal accidents captures factors specific to bin s that influence where vehicles of class i and j have collided and the frequency of single-car accidents relative to a fatality occurs in the vehicle of class i. Counts multicar accidents. ​xi​ ​refers to the fatality risk to of accidents reflect all factors influencing risk occupants of class i in a standardized collision and exposure. I categorize these into three mul- with a fixed object. This will be reflected up ( tiplicative components: i ​ ij​ ​ reflects the engi- to a constant using crash test results. The key neering safety risk of a fatality) β in vehicle i when restriction across) equations 1 and 2 is that ( ) ( ) vehicles from classes i and j collide, abstracting the dangerous behaviors contained in i multi- from all aspects of driver behavior or location. ply both the risk of single-car accidentsα and the ii ​ i​ ​represents the portion of risk attributable risk of accidents with other vehicles. to) theα behavior or location of drivers in class i. Much of the previous work focusing on the iii ​nis​ ​is the number of vehicles of class i that are influence of weight of vehicles see Charles J. present) in bin s. Kahane 2003 has parameterized( the risks in The greater any of these components—engi- ) neering risk, drivers’ risk, and number of vehi- cles—the more fatal accidents are expected. I 5 NHTSA 2008b . ( ) VOL. 101 NO. 3 fuel economy, car class mix, and safety 107 collisions according to weight differences. By aggregate data on miles traveled.6 I estimate the assigning a complete set of fixed effects for all parameters of the following two equations: possible interactions, ​ ​,​ I can still recover this βij information while adding considerable flexibil- 3 ​Yis​ ​ Poisson is​ ​ ity in form. Wenzel and Ross 2005 estimate ( ) ~ (ω​ ) ( ) risks using a similar approach for vehicle inter- E Yis​ ​ is​ ​ is​ ​ ​ s​​ ​xi​ ​ actions but importantly do not include driving (​ ) = ​ω = δ λ safety behavior. For purpose of comparison I 4 ​Z ​ ijs​ Poisson ijs​ ​ provide estimates of a restricted version of my ( ) ~ (μ​ ) model where I set each of the ​ i​ ​parameters to E Z ​ ijs​ ijs​ ​ is​ ​ ​ js​ ​ ​ ij​ ,​ unity. The parameter estimatesα turn out to be (​ ) = ​μ = δ δ β quite different, so much so that the primary pol- where ​x​i​ and the realizations of ​Yis​ ​and ​Z​ijs ​are icy implication is reversed in sign. data. All remaining parameters are estimated simultaneously using maximum likelihood. II. Data Estimates are robust to fitting a negative bino- mial distribution in place of the Poisson. For Accident counts come from the Fatal comparison with other work, and to demonstrate Accident Reporting System FARS , which the importance of allowing driver selection comprehensively records each( fatal )automo- across vehicle classes, I compare my estimates bile accident in the United States. This dataset with a restricted version of the model. It is esti- is complete, of high quality, and includes not mated identically to the above with the restric- only the vehicle class and information about tion that ​ i​ is equal to unity for all classes. where and when the accident took place which α​ I use to define bin s in the model , but (a host I V. Empirical Results and Policy Simulation of other factors like weather, and) distance to a hospital. I make use of these in a series of I first estimate the restricted version of the robustness checks available in the Appendix. model, such that all drivers are assumed to have For my main specification I pool data for average risk. This version of the model reflects the three years 2006–2008. My measure of ​ aggregate trends in the data well but conflicts nis​ ​ comes from the 2008 National Household with typical assumptions in the engineering Transportation Survey, detailing the driving literature. For example, minivans, while much patterns and vehicles owned by more than larger and heavier than the average car, appear to 20,000 US households. impose very few fatalities on any other vehicle The second key data component is crash type. test results xi​ ​ in the model above , which I My full model resolves this puzzle by describ- take from the(​ National Highway Traffic) Safety ing a set of selection effects in vehicle safety Administration NHTSA . The head-injury cri- across classes. The third column of Table 1 ( ) terion HIC is a summary index available from displays estimates of ​ ​ i ​normalized to 1.0 for a the crash( tests) and reflects the probability of a driver of average risk. αMinivans and small SUVs fatality very close to linearly Irving P. Herman receive the lowest coefficients, with minivan 2007 , important for integration( with my model. drivers having fatal accident rates less than half Fatality) rates in single-car accidents and the that of the average driver. The drivers of large average HIC by vehicle class are shown in the cars and pickup trucks bring the highest risks. first and second columns of Table 1. The corresponding set of estimated coeffi- cients appears in the Appendix, both beforeβ and III. Estimation after accounting for driver behavior. The cor- rection for driver selection reconciles accident Since the parameters for driving behavior and risks across classes with engineering predic- quantity are relevant only up to a constant they tions: Minivans appear similar to the light trucks express relative riskiness and vehicle density,( they are based on in terms of engineering risk, respectively I combine them into a single term for estimation:) n . The average risks by δis ≡ is α i class can be recovered after estimation using 6 See Appendix for the derivation. α i 108 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2011 and light vehicles more generally appear riskier Table 2—Changes in Accident Risk under than heavy ones. My corrected coefficients also Alternative Policies reflect the weight externality: The parameters reflecting standardized risk in accidentsβ between Increment to CAFE Unified standard compacts and large pickup trucks, for example, Restricted Full Restricted Full a show a risk nearly eight times larger for occu- model model model model pants of the . Compact 368.6 413.6 273.5 251.0 I apply my estimates to a simple model of Midsize 135.5 101.9 47.0 58.6 Fullsize −112.0 −106.1 5.2 4.0 fuel economy standards in the US, consider- Small luxury − 46.8 − 44.2 6.5 5.6 ing two possible regulatory regimes. The first is Large luxury −60.2 −57.0 8.1 6.9 an extension of the current Corporate Average Small SUV −94.8 −187.7 −24.3 −7.0 Large SUV 113.0 109.0 −81.7 −81.2 Fuel Economy CAFE rules: Light trucks and − − − − cars are separated( into) two fleets, which must Small pickup 59.7 69.3 53.0 52.0 Large pickup 223.2 222.3 −161.6 −161.8 individually meet average fuel economy targets. Minivan − 32.6 −119.3 − 15.6 − 1.8 This produces a distinctive pattern of shifts to Total 135.0 149.5 −12.1 −8.5 Standard error − 6.1 9.4 − 3.8 4.3 smaller vehicles within each fleet, but without ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) substitution between cars and trucks overall. I a Values are the predicted change in number of annual traffic hold the total number of vehicles and riskiness fatalities occuring in each vehicle class. of drivers fixed, keeping track of individual driv- ers as substitution across vehicle classes occurs. The first column of Table 2 displays results from my restricted model, before accounting to the downsizing of vehicles, for a near-zero for selection. A reduction of 135 fatalities per change in total fatalities. year is predicted from a 0.1 mile-per-gallon MPG increase in fuel economy via composi- V. Future Work tional( )changes.7 The second column reflects the full model and presents a very different conclu- My empirical estimates can inform a vari- sion: An increase of 150 fatalities is predicted. ety of other policy considerations, importantly Intuitively, I am finding that much of the danger including the “footprint” based standard that of large vehicles comes from their drivers, who is in effect for the 2012–2016 model years. It will remain on the road and are now more vul- assigns target fuel economies to each size of nerable in accidents. The effect is particularly vehicle as determined by width and wheel- strong for single-car accidents, which represent base , limiting( the incentives for any change in nearly two-thirds of fatalities in the data. fleet) composition. This increases the technology My second policy simulation is a unified stan- costs of meeting a given target but may miti- dard that regulates all vehicles together based gate the safety consequences.8 My simulations only on fuel economy. This has the effect of can address these issues directly. I also plan a shifting consumers away from trucks and SUVs further separation of risk factors that will allow and into cars. The results appear in the fourth me to relax assumptions in the simulation model column of Table 2, showing an increase of only regarding the constancy of driver behavior. eight fatalities per year with a zero change included in the confidence bounds. This signifi- References cant improvement over an increment to current CAFE comes as the result of shifts out of trucks Austin, David, and Terry Dinan. 2005. “Clear- and into cars, which I predict confers a safety ing the Air: The Costs and Consequences of benefit even after accounting for driver behavior. Higher Cafe Standards and Increased Gasoline The benefit almost exactly offsets the deteriora- tion of safety within the car and truck fleets due

8 NHTSA 2008a discusses the rationale for the footprint rule. Technology( costs) are higher because all improvement 7 If, for example, an additional 0.9 MPG appeared through must be achieved through technology; without the footprint changes in technology within vehicle class, the simulation basis some of the improvement may come from technology would represent a total increment of 1 MPG. and some via fleet composition. VOL. 101 NO. 3 fuel economy, car class mix, and safety 109

Taxes.” Journal of Environmental Economics National Highway Traffic Safety Administration. and Management, 50 3 : 562–82. 2008b. “National Motor Vehicle Crash Cau- Crandall, Robert W., and( John) D. Graham. 1989. sation Survey: Report to Congress.” National “The Effect of Fuel Economy Standards on Highway Traffic Safety Administration Tech- Automobile Safety.” Journal of Law and Eco- nical Report DOT HS 811 059. nomics, 32 1 : 97–118. National Highway Traffic Safety Administration. Gayer, Ted. 2004.( ) “The Fatality Risks of Sport- 2009. “Traffic Safety Facts: A Brief Statistical Utility Vehicles, , and Pickups Relative to Summary.” National Highway Traffic Safety Cars.” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 28 2 : Administration Technical Report DOT HS 103–33. ( ) 811172. Herman, Irving P. 2007. The Physics of the National Research Council. 2002. Effectiveness Human Body. New York: Springer. and Impact of Corporate Average Fuel Econ- Jacobsen, Mark. 2010. “Evaluating US Fuel omy CAFE Standards. Washington, DC: Economy Standards in a Model with Producer National( Academy) Press. and Household Heterogeneity.” Unpublished. Portney, Paul R., Ian Parry, Howard Gruenspecht, Kahane, Charles J. 2003. “Vehicle Weight, Fatal- and Winston Harrington. 2003. “Policy Watch: ity Risk and Crash Compatibility of Model Year The Economics of Fuel Economy Standards.” 1991–99 Passenger Cars and Light Trucks.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17 4 : National Highway Traffic Safety Administra- 203–17. ( ) tion Technical Report DOT HS 809 662. Wenzel, Thomas P., and Marc Ross. 2005. “The Levitt, Steven D., and Jack Porter. 2001. “How Effects of Vehicle Model and Driver Behavior Dangerous Are Drinking Drivers?” Journal of on Risk,” Accident Analysis and Prevention, Political Economy, 109 6 : 1198–1237. 37: 479–94. National Highway Traffic( Safety) Administration. White, Michelle J. 2004. “The ‘Arms Race’ on 2008a. “Average Fuel Economy Standards, American Roads: The Effect of Sport Util- Passenger Cars and Light Trucks Model Years ity Vehicles and Pickup Trucks on Traf- 2011–2015; Proposed Rule.” Federal Register, fic Safety.” Journal of Law and Economics, 73 86 : 24352–487. 47 2 : 333–55. ( ) ( )