CAPITAL STRUCTURE IN SMEs: PECKING VERSUS STATIC TRADE-OFF, BOUNDED RATIONALITY AND THE BEHAVIOURAL PRINCIPLE. SilviaSwinnen # WimVoordeckers * SigridVandemaele ° Abstract In this paper, we scrutinize financing decisions in small and mediumsized firms. In the finance literature,twocompetingmodels–thestatictradeofftheoryandthepeckingordertheory–tryto explainthefinancingdecisionsinfirms.GiventhespecialcognitivestyleofmanagementinSMEs, characterizedbyboundedrationalityandintuition,weinvestigatewhetherthebehaviouralprinciple hasahigherexplanatorypowerthanthetwotraditionalcompetingtheoriesintofinancing behaviourinSMEs.Ouranalysisisconductedonasampleof899firms,ofwhichfinancialdataare collectedovera10yearperiodfrom1993–2002.Allfirmsinoursamplefitthethreecriteria:1) privatelyowned, 2) SME criteria of the European Commission and 3) primary activity in manufacturing,wholesaleorretailindustry.Tostudytheempiricalsignificanceofthebehavioural principle, the static tradeoff and the pecking order theory, we use several partial adjustment models. The regression results support thepredictionsprovidedby thepecking order theory that firms decrease or increase their financial debt in correspondence to the availability or lack of internalfunds. EFM classification codes :140;800 # Corresponding author. Doctoral student. Limburg University Center, Faculty of Business Administration, Universitaire CampusGebouw D, B3590 Diepenbeek, Belgium. Tel. +32/11.26.86.31Fax.+32/11.26.87.00.email: [email protected] * Assistantprofessor of finance. Limburg University Center, Faculty of Business Administration, Universitaire CampusGebouw D, B3590 Diepenbeek, Belgium. Tel. +32/11.26.86.94 Fax. +32/11.26.87.00.email: [email protected] ° Assistant professor of finance. Limburg University Center, Faculty of Business Administration, Universitaire CampusGebouw D, B3590 Diepenbeek, Belgium. Tel. +32/11.26.86.22 Fax. +32/11.26.87.00.email: [email protected] 2

1 INTRODUCTION Incorporatefinancethereexistsalargebodyofliteraturethatexaminesthefinancingbehaviourof firms,reflectedbytheircapitalstructure.Researchinthecapitalstructurefieldisdominatedbytwo theories:thestatictradeofftheoryandpeckingordertheory.Thestatictradeofftheoryemergedin thestreamlineofthepathbreakingworkofModiglianiandMiller(1958).ModiglianiandMiller assumeperfectandfrictionlesscapitalmarketstoprovetheirirrelevancetheorem,whichwaslater generalized by Stiglitz (1974). According to the irrelevance theorem the firm’s financing policy shouldnotaffectthefirm’svalueoritscostofcapital.Thefirm’svalueissolelydeterminedbyits investment decisions. This obviously implies that there are no interactions between corporate finance and investment decisions. A logical conclusion is that firm’s financing and investment decisionscanbeanalysedseparately.TheM&Mirrelevancetheoremofcapitalstructure,though basedontheunrealisticassumptionofperfectcapitalmarkets,showsthatmarketimperfectionsare arequisiteforcapitalstructuretomatter.Byintroducingmarketimperfections,firmsseemtogetan optimal, valuemaximising debtequity ratio by trading off the advantages of debt against the disadvantages.Ontheotherside,thepeckingordertheory(Myers,1984;MyersandMajluf,1984) contradicts the existence of financial targets, and states that firms follow a financing : internalfundsarepreferredaboveexternalfinancingandifthelatterbecomesnecessary,safedebt ispreferredoverriskydebtandequityissuesareatthelowestendofthepeckingorder.Inspiteof ongoingdebate,therearestillnoclearcutanswersastohowfirmsmaketheirfinancingdecisions. Empirical studies have focused on studying determinants, identified by theoretical studies as potentially important, to make inferences about the predominance of one of the capital structure theories (e.g. Titman and Wessels, 1988; Rajan and Zingales, 1995; Graham, 1996). In most of thesestudies,firm’sadjustmenttothesefinancialtargetswasconsideredtobeinstantaneousand costless. In a perfect market, adjustment to these long run targets would be instantaneous and complete.However,marketimperfectionssuchastransactionandadjustmentcostsandconstraints preventfirmsfromchangingtheirdebtlevelorratiothewaytheydesire(Marsh,1982;Jalilvand andHarris,1984).Duetothesemarketimperfectionsfirm’sfinancialdecisionsshouldbeviewedas atwophaseprocess.Thefirstphaseconsistsofthetargetformationandthesecondphaseconsists oftheadjustmenttowardsthedebtleveloutinthefirstphase.Therefore,thefirm’sfinancial behaviour is best characterised by a partial adjustment model (Spies, 1974; Taggart Jr., 1977; JalilvandandHarris,1984;Ozkan,2001). Intheliterature,targetadjustmentmodelsusuallyhavebeenusedtoprovidemoredirectevidence that firms adjust towards a target capital structure (Taggart, 1977; Marsh, 1982; Jalilvand and Harris,1984).Targetadjustmentmodelscanalsobeused,however,totesttheempiricalvalidityof thetradeofftheoryandpeckingordertheory(Durinck,Laveren,VanHulleandVandenbroucke, 1998; Hovakimian, Opler and Titman, 2001; Fama and French, 2002). Most of the studies concerning capital structure dynamics have focused on large quoted firms. These firms that are assumedtohaveunlimitedaccesstowelldevelopedcapitalmarkets. Thispaperscrutinizesthefinancingbehaviourofprivatesmallandmediumsizedfirmsbyusinga targetadjustmentmodel.Smallfirmsareinterestingbecauseunlikelargefirms,theydonothave accessto welldeveloped capital markets. Due to informationasymmetriesand agencyproblems, externalfinancingislimitedandbanksbecometheprimarysourceoffundsforsmallfirmsbecause they are better equipped to assess small business quality and address agency and information problems(BergerandUdell,1995,1998).Anotherdifferencebetweensmallandlargefirmsisthat smallfirmsmightnothavetheknowledgeorfinancialcapabilitiestodeterminetheoptimaltarget for their firm. According to the behavioural principle (Emery, Finnerty and Stowe, 2004) these firmsmightusetheindustryaveragedebtratioasaguidingpointfortheirfinancingdecisions. Basedontheseobservations,theaimofthisstudyistoinvestigatetheunderlyingtheoreticaldrivers behindthefinancingdecisionsinsmallandmediumsizedfirms.Thispaperextendstheempirical literatureoncapitalstructuredecisionsinSMEsinseveralways.First,itisoneofthefirstpapersto useatargetadjustmentmodelonasampleofSME.Second,giventhespecialcognitivestyleof managementinSMEs(SadlerSmith,2004)characterizedbyintuitionandboundedrationality,we 3 investigateifthebehaviouralprincipleexplainsmoreofthefinancingbehaviourinSMEsthanthe traditional static tradeoff and pecking order theories. Hence, a target consistent with the behaviouralprincipleisanalysedwithinastatictradeoffandpeckingorderframework. The rest ofthepaperis organised as follows. In thenextsection thetheoreticalbackground and hypothesisarepresented.Section3and4describethedataandthevariablesusedinthestudy.In section5descriptivearediscussedbeforepresentingthemodelinsection6.Insection7 theresultsandinsection8theconclusionsarepresented.

2 THEORY AND HYPOTHESES Inthissectionwediscussthestatictradeofftheoryofcapitalstructure,thepeckingordertheory andthebehaviouralprincipleandformulatethehypothesesthatwillbetested. 2.1 Static trade-off theory Thestatictradeofftheory,whichfocusesonthebenefitsandcostsofissuingdebt,predictsthatan optimaltargetfinancialdebtratioexists,whichmaximizesthevalueofthefirm.Theoptimalpoint canbeattainedwhenthemarginalvalueofthebenefitsassociatedwithdebtissuesexactlyoffsets theincreaseinthepresentvalueofthecostsassociatedwithissuingmoredebt(Myers,2001).The benefits of debt are the tax deductibility of interestpayments. The tax deductibility of corporate interestpaymentsfavourstheuseofdebt.Thissimpleeffecthowever,canbecomplicatedbythe existenceofpersonaltaxes(Miller,1977)andnondebttaxshields(DeAngeloandMasulis,1980). Another benefit of debt is that it mitigates the managershareholder agency conflict. Corporate managers have the incentive to waste free cash flow on perquisites and bad investment. Debt financinglimitsthefreecashflowavailabletomanagersandtherebyhelpstocontrolthisagency problem(JensenandMeckling,1976).Thecostsassociatedwithissuingmoredebtarethecostsof financialdistress(ModiglianiandMiller,1963)andtheagencycoststriggeredbyconflictsbetween shareholdersanddebtors(JensenandMeckling,1976).Costsoffinancialdistressarelikelytoarise whenafirmusesexcessivedebtandisunabletomeettheinterestandprincipalpayments. Wetrytodetermineiffirmsexhibittradeoffbehaviourbyusingatargetadjustmentmodel.The tradeoff theory implies a targetadjustment model (Taggart, 1977; Jalilvand and Harris, 1984; Ozkan,2001).Inthismodelfirmshaveatargetdebtratiotowhichtheygraduallyadjust.Thedebt is adjusted by comparing the actual level or ratio of debt in the previous period with the predetermined target debt level or ratio. The adjustment, though, is only partial due to market imperfectionssuchastransactioncosts(Marsh,1982),adjustmentcostsandconstraints(Jalilvand and Harris, 1984). If firms are above the target debt ratio the value of the firm is not optimal becausefinancialdistressandagencycostsexceedthebenefitsofdebt.Therefore,weexpectfirms thatareabovetheirtargetdebtratio,todecreasetheirdebtinthecurrentperiod.Firmsthathavea debtratiobelowthetargetdebtratiocanstillincreasethevalueofthefirmbecausemarginalvalue ofthebenefitsofdebtarestillgreaterthanthecostsassociatedwiththeuseofdebt.Therefore,we expectfirmswhosedebtinthepreviousperiodwassituatedbelowthetargetlevel,toincreasetheir debt.Thecostandbenefitsofdebtmakethatfirmsthatarebelowthetargetdebtratioincreasetheir debtandfirmsthatareabovethetargetdebtratiodecreasetheirdebt,althoughthespeedofthese adjustmentscoulddiffer(Durinck,Laveren,VanHulleandVandenbroucke,1998). Accordingtothetradeofftheoryofcapitalstructure: H1A :Firmswithadebtratiobelowthetargetratioadjusttheirdebtupwardtowardsthetargetdebt ratio. H1B :Firmswithadebtratioabovethetargetratioadjusttheirdebtdownwardtowardsthetarget debtratio. 4

2.2 Pecking order theory The pecking order theory developed by Myers (1984) is an alternative capital structure theory. Accordingtothepeckingordertheory,afirm’scapitalstructureisdrivenbythefirm’spreference tofinancewithinternallygeneratedfundsinsteadofwithexternalfinancing.Ifexternalfinancingis required, debt is preferred over equity. The pecking order theory can be explained from the perspectiveofasymmetricinformationandtheexistenceoftransactioncosts. Asymmetricinformationcostsarisewhenafirmchoosesnottouseexternalfinancingandtherefore passupapositiveNPVinvestment.Managers(firm’sinsiders)haveaccesstobetterinformation thanoutsideinvestorshave.Thisinducesopportunisticbehaviourbymanagers.Managerswillissue securities whenthe market price ofthe firm’s securities is higher than the real firm value. The deviationbetweenthemarketpriceofthefirm’ssecuritiesandtherealfirmvaluearise,because investors, having inferior information about the value of the firm’s assets, can misprice equity (MyersandMajluf,1984).Sophisticatedinvestorsareawareofthefactthatfirmshavetheincentive to issue new shares when the market overvalues the existing shares. Therefore, investors will rationallyadjustthepricetheyarewillingtopay,causingnewsecuritiestobeunderpricedinthe market.Iffirmshavetofinancenewprojectsbyissuingequity,underpricingmaybesoseverethat new investors capture more of the NPV of the new project, resulting in a loss to existing shareholders.IfthisisthecasethantheprojectwillberejectedevenifitsNPVispositive,because managers act in favour of the existing shareholders. This underinvestment can be avoided by financingthenewprojectwithsecuritythatisnotsoseverelyundervalued(Myers,1984;Myersand Majluf,1984). Thepeckingordertheorycanalsobeexplainedbytheexistenceoftransactioncosts.Transaction costsassociatedwithexternalfinanceplayanimportantroleinselectingfinancingsources.Firms will first use internal equity financing, followed by external debt financing and finally external equityfinancing.Debtfinancingprecedesequityissuesbecausetransactioncostsfordebtarelower thanforequityissues(Baskin,1989).Baskin(1989)foundthatcostsforraisingdebtintheU.S. marketsmaybeaslowas1%oftheamountsoffundsraisedbutsimilarcostsforraisingequity rangebetween4%and15%.Onlyafterexhaustingotherfinancingpossibilities,newequity,which ischaracterisedbyhightransactioncosts,isissued. Therelianceoninternalfinancecanalsobeabyproductofthedesireofmanagerstoavoidexternal financing because it subjects them to the discipline of the market (Myers, 1984). Especially the ownermanagerofthecompanydoesnotliketolosecontroloverthefirm(HolmesandKent,1991; HamiltonandFox,1998).Thereforemanagersareveryreluctanttoacceptnewshareholdersand will try to finance their activities as much as possible with internal funds. If the firm’s retained earningsdonotsuffice,managementwillchoosethefinancingsourcewithoutcontrolrestrictions. Therefore management will opt for shortterm debt because no collateral is required and no covenantsareimposed,followedbylongtermdebtandfinallyequityissues. Myers(1984)suggeststhatasymmetricinformationandtransactioncostsoverwhelmtheforcesthat determineoptimalleverageinthetradeofmodels.Tominimizethesefinancingcosts,firmsprefer to finance their investment projects first with internal cash flows. Only if there is a residual financingneedtheywilluseexternalcapitalinfollowingorder;firstsafedebt,thenriskydebtand finallyequityissues.So,contrarytothetradeofftheory,thepeckingordertheorypredictsnolong run target capital structure. There is no optimal debtequity mix because there are two kinds of equity,retainedearningsatthetopofthepeckingorderandtheissueofnewsharesatthebottom (Myers,1984).Totestiffirmsfollowthepeckingorder,weusethetargetadjustmentmodelwith the target defined by the tradeoff theory. If firms exhibit pecking order behaviour, they should ignorethetargetandbasetheirfinancialdecisionsontheavailabilityofinternalfundsortheirfree cashflow. H2A :Iffirmshaveapositivefreecashflow,thedebtratiobelowthetargetdebtratiomovesfurther awayfromthetheoreticaltarget,whilethedebtratioabovethetargetmovestowardsthetargetdebt ratio. 5

H2B :Iffirmshaveanegativefreecashflow,thedebtratioabovethetargetdebtratiomovesfurther awayfromthetheoreticaltarget,whilethedebtratiobelowthetargetmovestowardsthetarget. The pecking order theory states that firms prefer to finance with internal funds. Ideally, a firm would have a debtratioequalto zero. However,only firms that have enough internalfundscan reachthislongrunequilibrium.Firmsthataremostlikelytoachieveawellestablishedsourceof internalequityareolder,maturefirms.Small,youngorgrowingfirms,thatlackownresources,will havetorelyondebt(andequity)financing.Sointheshortrun,thedebtratiotendstodeviatefrom zero. Intheshortrun,Myers’(1984) simplepeckingordertheory suggeststhatfirmsincreaseordecrease their debt ratio if they have a negative free cash flow respectively a positive free cash flow. Implicitly,thisimpliesaperiodbyperioddebtratioequaltotheactuallevelorratiooffinancial debtinthepreviousperiodcorrectedwiththefreecashflowofthecurrentperiod.Acompany’sreal debtequity ratio, therefore, varies over time, depending on its need for external finance. A profitablefirmgeneratingslowgrowthwillendupwithalowdebtratio.Itmakesnosenseforsuch firms to borrow just to bring themselves into line with for example the theoretical target or an industryaverage.Unprofitablefirmsorfirmswithrelativehighgrowthcanexhibithighdebtratios. Firms,however,arenotabletoborrowindefinitely.Afirmwilleventuallyreachfulldebtcapacity. Oncethatthereserveborrowingpowerisexhausted,firmsareforcedtofinancetheirpositiveNPV projects with equity issues or forgo these positive NPV projects. The full debt capacity level, however, cannot be observed. The only thing that could be observed is a different financing behaviouroffirmswithrelativelymoredebtasopposedtofirmswithrelativelylowdebt. Accordingtothesimplepeckingorder: H3A :Firmswithapositivefreecashflowusethiscashflowtolowertheirdebtratio. H3B :Firmswithanegativefreecashflowincreasetheirdebtratiotorespondtothelackofinternal funds.Thepercentageadjustmentissmallerforfirmswithrelativelymoredebtthanforfirmswith relativelylowdebt. Inamore complexviewofthepeckingordermodel ,firmsareconcernednotonlywithcurrentbut also with future financing costs (Myers, 1984). Firms climbing up the pecking order, face two increasingcosts.Thefirmhasahigherprobabilityofincurringfinancialdistresscostsandahigher chanceofhavingtosurpassfuturepositiveNPVprojects,becausethefirmisunwillingtofinance with common stock. If firms are not only concerned with the current investments but also with futuregrowthopportunities,thentheywillfavouralowdebtratio.Myers(1984)arguesthatafirm may issue new common stock, even if it has not reached its debt capacity, because reserve borrowing capacity is valuable. If their debt ratio is below their debt capacity, the likelihood of having to surpass future profitable investments is lower (Myers, 1984). Opposite to the simple peckingorder,thecomplexpeckingorderpredictsthatfirms,withfuturegrowthopportunities,will trytomaintainreserveborrowingcapacityforfutureprojects. H4:Firmswithanegativefreecashflowandrelativelymorefuturegrowthopportunitiesincrease theirdebtmoreslowlythanfirmswithanegativefreecashflowandfewergrowthopportunities. 2.3 Static trade-off versus pecking order in small firms A basic assumption of the capital structure theories is that decisionmaking processes are based uponrationaleconomicbehaviour.Theyassumethatmanagersexhibitrationalhumanbehaviour, which leads to economic shareholder wealth maximization. In the literature, numerous empirical studies have focused on studying the determinants of capital structure as predicted by the static tradeoftheoryofcapitalstructure.Variousfirmspecificcharacteristicsareidentifiedasimportant in determining the optimal target capital structure, such as asset structure, firm size, growth opportunities, profitability, …(e.g. Rajan and Zingales, 1995; Chittenden, Hall and Hutchinson, 1996; Jordan, Lowe and Taylor, 1998; Titman and Wessels, 1988). However, instead of determiningtheirtargetwiththislaborioustimeconsumingprocess,firmsmightusetheindustry 6 averageastheiroptimaltarget.Theunderlyingrationaleisthattheoptimalpointforfirmsinthe sameindustryisapproximatelythesame. Lev (1969) found that various financial ratios, amongst which the equity to total debt ratio, convergetotheindustryaverages.Ratiosthatinvolveshorttermitems(e.g.currentratios)andare underthe control of management adjust more rapidly than ratiosinvolving longterm items (e.g. longterm debt, equity) and variables which are not under the complete control of management (Lev,1969).AccordingtoBowen,DaleyandHuber(1982),firmsexhibitastatisticallysignificant tendencytoadjustthedebtandequityratiostowardtheirindustrymeanoverbothfiveandtenyear timeperiods.MartinandScott(1974)findthatwhenfinancialleverageislowincomparisontothe industrynorm,thefirmwouldtendtoissuedebtratherthanequity.Withhigherdebtlevelsthefirm islesslikelytoissuemoredebtbecauseofthethreatofbankruptcy.Theuseofindustryaveragesas desired financial values is also in line with evidence that the industry class is an important determinantofcorporatefinancialstructures(MartinandScott,1975;FerriandJones,1979). However,whenmanagersaredealingwithlimitedinformation,timeconstraints,limitedcognitive abilities and subjectivity, the decisionmaking process is no longer completely rational (March, 1978).Furthermore,thebusinessenvironmentinwhichmanagersoperateiscomplex,unstableand unpredictable,whichmakesotherdecisionmakingmodelsmoresuitable(SadlerSmith,2004).The boundedrationalitymodelseemstobemoreappropriatetodescribeorganizationaldecisionmaking processes. Within the concept of bounded rationally March (1978) developed alternative rationalities,suchaslimitedrationality.Theideaoflimitedrationalityappearstoberelevanttothe small firm. According to the idea of limited rationality, individuals simplify decisionmaking problemsbecausetheyhavedifficultiesinconsideringallalternativesandallrelevantinformation (March, 1978). Hence, many small firms ownermanagers lack understanding of the various financingsourcesavailableandtheskillsinaccessingthem(Hutchinson,1999).Theydonothavea fullrangeofmanagerialexpertiseandoftenlackafullyequippedmanagementteam(Ang,1991), whichleadstoinadequateknowledgetomakewellsubstantiatedoptimaldecisions.Consequently, entrepreneursmightnothavethefinancialcapabilitiestochooseanoptimaltarget.Thereforethey havetolookforsomeguidanceandreferencepoints.Apossibilityistolookatothersimilarfirms for guidance. This is called the behavioural principle (Emery, Finnerty and Stowe, 2004). According to the behaviour principle, SMEs could use industry averages as financial targets becausetheyhavealimitedunderstandingonthesubjectofcapitalstructure(Emery,Finnertyand Stowe,2004).So,insteadofdeterminingtheiroptimaldebtlevelorratiobyatradeoffbetweenthe costsandbenefitsofborrowingaspredictedbythetradeofftheory,smallandmediumsizedfirms mightblindlyusetheindustryaverage. Thestatictradeofftheorypredictsthatfirmsadjusttheirdebtratiotowardsapredeterminedtarget. So,whenthedesiredfinancialvalueissetequaltotheindustryaveragedebtratio,firmswithadebt ratiobelowtheindustryaveragedebtratiowillincreasetheirdebtratio,whilefirmswithadebt ratioabovetheindustryaveragewilldecreasetheirdebt.Itisimmaterialwhetherthefirmdecidesto usetheindustryaverage,astheirtarget,basedonrationalthinkingorbyblindlyfollowingother firms. H5A :Firmswithadebtratiobelowtheaverageindustrydebtratioadjusttheirdebtupwardtowards theindustrydebtratio. H5B : Firms with a debt ratio above the average industry debt ratio adjust their debt downward towardstheindustrydebtratio. Iffirmslookupontheindustrydebtratioasastandardoptimaltargetdebtratio,theywilladjust theirdebtratiotowardstheindustrydebtratio.However,firmsmightalsobeawareoftheindustry debtratio,withoutthinkingofitastheoptimalratio.Firmsmightconsidertheindustrydebtratioto beimportantbecausebanksmightevaluateafirm’screditapplicationbycomparingthefinancial situationofthefirmwithotherfirmsinthesamesector.Inthiscasetheindustryaveragedebtratio playsarole,butnotaprimordialone.Thepeckingorderwillstillbeofsuperiorimportancewhen makingfinancingdecisions.Accordingtothesimplepeckingorder,firmswilldecreasetheirdebt ratioiftheyhaveapositivefreecashflow,therebymovingtowardstheindustryaverageinthey wereoperatingaboveitormovingfurtherawayfromtheindustrydebtratioiftheywereoperating belowit.Thelatterhavenoreasontogetinlinewiththeindustryaverage.Ifthefirmhasanegative 7 free cash flow, then it will increase its debt ratio whether their debt ratio is below or above the industrydebtratio.However,becausebankscomparesthefirm’sdebtratiototheindustryaverage debtratiowhendecidingongrantingloans.Firmsthatareoperatingwithadebtratioabovethatof theindustrymightbeconfrontedwithahighercostofdebtfinancing.Thiscostmightexceedthe costofincreasingtheircapital,duetoagencyproblems. Whenthecomplexpeckingorderapplies,firmswithmoregrowthopportunitiesincreasetheirdebt moreslowlythanfirmswithfewergrowthopportunities.Firmsthathaveanegativefreecashflow andadebtratioabovetheindustryaveragewillfindithardtoreceivemorefinancialdebtfrom banks,whilefirmswithdebtratiobelowtheindustryaveragewillincreasetheirdebtratiobutless thanfirmswithnofuturegrowthopportunities.

Previousempiricalstudieshavefoundevidenceofthepeckingordertheoryinthewayfirmsadjust totheaverageindustrydebtratio.Claggett,Jr.(1991)findssupportthatfirm’slongtermdebtto total assets ratio tend to move toward the most recent previous industry mean within one year. However, he finds notable exceptions to the basicpattern. In general, firms with longterm debt ratios above that of the industry average adjust more towards the mean than firms with below average ratios. When the pooled data are segmented by year and SIC , much of the significanceislost(ClaggartJr.,1991).Thiscouldbeinterpretedasevidenceofthepeckingorder theory.CatandGhosh(2003)findnosignificantdifferencebetweentheprobabilitythatafirm's debtlevelismovingtowardtheindustry’smeanandtheprobabilitythatitismovingfurtheraway fromtheindustrymean. H6A :Firmswithapositivefreecashflowandadebtratiobelowtheindustryaveragedebtratio, movetheirdebtratiofurtherawayfromtheindustryaverage.Iftheyhaveadebtratioabovethe industryaveragedebtratio,theirdebtratiomovestowardstheindustryaverage. H6B :Iffirmswithanegativefreecashflowhaveadebtratiobelowtheindustryaverage,theymove theirdebt ratiotowards the industry average. Firmswithfuture growth opportunities move more slowlytowardstheindustryaveragedebtratiothanfirmswithnofuturegrowthopportunities. H6C :Iffirmswithanegativefreecashflowhaveadebtratioabovethatoftheindustry,theyare expectedtoincreasetheircapitalwhilethedebtratiowilldecreaseorstayconstant.

3 DESCRIPTION OF THE DATABASE The data source for our analysis is the Belfirst CDrom, which provides detailed financial informationon320,000Belgiancompaniesand4,000Luxembourgfirms,collectedbytheNational BankofBelgium.Theenterprisesincludedinoursamplingframeare private Belgian small and medium-sized limited enterprises thatdisclose(unconsolidated) complete financial statements . Firmsareclassifiedassmallandmediumsizedaccordingtothecriteriaforsmallandmediumsized firms,adoptedbytheEuropeanCommission 1.Fromthissampleweselectedunquotedfirmswith theirprimaryactivitybeingmanufacturing(NaceBelactivitycode15to36),wholesale(NaceBel activity code 50 and 51) or retail (NaceBel code 52). The firms that disclose an abbreviated financialstatementareexcludedbecausethesestatementsdonotcontainallfinancialdatarequired forouranalysis.Thisleadstoaselectionof1322firms. FromtheBelfirstCDromwehavedataavailableovera10yearperiod,from1993to2002,which allowsustousecrosssectionaltimeseriesorpaneldata.Paneldatahastheadvantagethatitoffers a large of data points, increasing the degrees of freedom and reducing the collinearity amongexplanatoryvariables,providingcoefficientsthataremoreefficient(Hsiao,2003).Because

1 The European Commission formulated a first definition (recommendation 96/280/EC) for small and mediumsizedenterprisesin1996.Theenterpriseswerecategorizedonthebasisoftheirstaffheadcountand financialceilings:turnoverandbalancesheettotal.Inadditiontheenterprisehastobeindependent;which meansthatlessthan25%oftheenterprisemaybeownedbyoneormoreenterprisesthatdonotcomply with thesamecriteria.On6May2003therecommendation2003/361/EC providesforanincreaseofthefinancial ceilings,asaresultofinflationandproductivityincreasessince1996.Smallandmediumsizedenterprisesare nowdefinedasindependentprivatelyheldcompanieswithfewerthan250employees,whichhaveaturnover below50million€ortotalassetsunder43million€.Thisnewdefinitionappliesasof1January2005. 8 variablesarecalculatedoverthisperiod,weonlymaintainfirmsthatprovidedataoverthewhole 10yearperiod. This excludes newly founded firms and firms that have ceased to exist between 1993 and 2002. Firms with missing values, necessary to calculate ourvariables are alsorejected fromthesample.Thisleavesuswithasampleof943firms. Before checking for outliers we merge several related sectors into larger groups to be able to calculate meaningful averages. The wholesale sector, on the other hand, is very large and heterogeneousandthereforesplitupintosmaller,morehomogeneousgroups.Weendupwith22 sectors. (For details see appendix 1) After calculating the necessary variables, we checked for outlierswithineachindustrybywinsoring.Weused+3σastheupperand3σasthe lower limit. Firms with outliers on the total financial debt ratio and the longterm financial debt ratiowereremovedfromthesamplebecauseextremevaluescouldbiasourtestresults.Firmswitha very low or very high debt ratio might exhibit differentfinancingbehaviour (ShyamSunder and Myers,1999;ChirinkoandSingha,2000).Outliersfortheexplanatoryvariablesarereplacedbythe calculatedupperandlowerlimit.Weendupwithasampleof899firmsofwhich 397areactivein themanufacturingsectorand502belongtothewholesaleandretailtradesector.

4 MEASURING THE VARIABLES Inthisparagraphwediscussourdependentvariables,independentvariablesandcontrolvariables. TheappliedmeasuresforthevariablesaresummarizedinTable1. < Insert Table 1>

4.1 Dependent variable Thelargestsourcesoffinanceforsmallbusinessesaretheprincipalowner,commercialbanksand trade creditors (Berger and Udell, 1998). The reason is that small firms face two fundamental problemsthatlimittheaccesstoexternalfinancing:informationasymmetriesandagencyproblems. Information asymmetries make it difficult for theproviders of external financing to evaluate the qualityandvalueofthefirm’sinvestmentopportunities.Agencyproblemsarisebecausemanagers might have the incentive to misallocate their funds and to act counter the interest of creditors (Dennis,2004).Insmallfirmstheseagencyproblemstendtobeveryseriousbecausethesefirms are confronted with high information asymmetries (Petit and Singer, 1985). First there is the familiar information problem where insiders are expected to have more information about the prospectsofthefirm.Thereasonisthatsmallfirmsarecharacterizedbytheir‘close’natureand that they have fewer disclosure requirements (Petit and Singer, 1985). A second information problemconcernsthequalityofthedatathatisgeneratedbysmallfirms.Smallfirmsdonothave audited financial statements to present to outside investors (Berger and Udell, 1998). Outsiders prefer such statements but small firms generally find it expensive to supply audited financial statementsandmayfinditdifficulttoovercomethisdeficiencywithotherinformation(Petitand Singer,1985).Smallfirmsmaynothavethemanagerialtalentandstafftocomeupwithusefuldata (Ang, 1991). Beside the significant costs associated with public equity and debt issues, informational opacity is a major reason why small firms cannot issue publicly traded securities (Berger and Udell, 1998).Therefore, small firms are much more dependent onprivate financing sources.Banksareaprimarysourceoffundsforsmallfirmsbecausetheyhavespecialmechanisms at hand to assess small business quality and address agency and information problems such as screening,contractingandmonitoring(BergerandUdell,1995,1998).Thereforeourstudyfocuses onthetotalfinancialdebtratioandthelongtermfinancialdebtratio.Longtermfinancialdebtis equaltothefinancialdebtpayableafteroneyearpluscurrentportionsofdebtpayableafterone year.Totalfinancialdebtistheaggregateofshortandlongtermfinancialdebt.Totalfinancialdebt is, therefore, the composite of financial debt payable after one year, plus financial debt payable withinoneyearpluscurrentportionsofdebtafteroneyear.Inourregressionweusethechangesin total and longterm financial debt ratio as dependent variable. The difference between the total, respectivelylongtermfinancialdebtlevelsoftwosuccessiveperiodsisrelatedtothetotalassetsof the beginning period. This specification alleviates the problem of heteroskedasticy that might be 9 presentinoursampledata.Thechangeintotalfinancialdebtratio, TFDT andlongtermfinancial debtratio, LFDT forfirm iinyear t are:

TFDT ,ti −TFDT ,ti −1 LFDT ,ti − LFDT ,ti −1 TFDT ,ti = ; LFDT ,ti = TA ,ti −1 TA ,ti −1 4.2 Target financial debt ratio Totestallourhypothesesweneedtodefinetargetfinancialdebtratios.Wedefinethetargetratioas the debt ratio predicted by the statictrade off theory, the debt ratio as predicted by the pecking ordertheoryandtheindustryaverages.

4.2.1 Target financial debt ratio as predicted by the static-trade off theory TotestourhypothesesH 1tillH 4,weneedtocalculatethetargettotalandlongtermfinancialdebt ratio as predicted by the static tradeoff theory. Following Fama and French (2002) and Hovakimian,OplerandTitman(2001),weregressthefinancialdebtratiosonthevariablesthatare assumedtodeterminethetargetleverageandthenusethefittedvaluesfromequation(1)and(2)as proxiesforthetargettotalfinancialdebtratiosandtargetlongtermfinancialdebtratiorespectively. In the pecking order model firms do not have a target financial debt ratio. So it ispossible that equation (1) and (2) simply describes how the financial debt ratios vary as a of the explanatory variables. The total and longterm financial debt ratios for firm i at time t are respectively:

TFDT ,ti =α i + β ki,t Χ ki,t +ut (1); LFDT ,ti =α i + β ki,t Χ ki,t +ut (2) where Xki,t aretheexplanatoryvariables. Theexplanatoryvariablesusedintheregressionaretakenfromthesetofvariablesusedinearlier empiricalstudiesofcapitalstructure.Numerousempiricalstudies(e.g.TitmanandWessels,1988; Rajan and Zingales, 1995; Graham, 1996) have focused on studying determinants of capital structureaspredictedbythestatictradeofftheoryofcapitalstructure.Empiricaldeterminantsthat havebeenidentifiedareage,assetstructure,firmsize,growthopportunities,liquidity,profitability andearningsvolatility(e.g.TitmanandWessels,1988;RajanandZingales,1995).Mostofthese studies have focused on large, public firms, which try to maximize the economic shareholders’ wealth. The empirical implications of capital structure for small firms are seldom discussed and tested.Oneofthereasonsisthatsmallfirmsareassumedtofollowthesamemanagementprinciples aslargefirms,anotherreasonwasthelackofavailablefinancialdataofsmallfirms(VanderWijst and Thurik, 1989). More recently, studies try to explain small firm financing decisions using modern financial theory. Determinants that appear to be most importantinsmallfirmsareasset structure, firm size, growth opportunities and profitability (Van der Wijst and Thurik, 1993; Chittenden,HallandHutchinson,1996;Jordan,LoweandTaylor;1998;Michaelas,Chittendenand Poutziouris, 1999; Voordeckers, 1999). In this paper it is not our intent to measure the relative importanceofthedistincttradeoffdeterminants,justtodetectwhetherfirmsexhibitstatictradeoff behaviour.Thereforewecalculateourtargetratiosbasedonthedeterminantsdeemedimportantin smallfirms:assetstructure,firmsize,growthopportunitiesandprofitability. Theproxiestomeasureassetstructurearetangiblefixedassetsscaledbytotalassets(AssStr1). As proxies for firm size we use the natural logarithm of total assets (S1). As a proxy for growth opportunities(growthopp)theratioofintangibleassetstototalassetsischosenandasaproxyfor profitability(prof)theratioofpretaxprofitstototalassetsforaperiodoftwoyearsischosen. Giventhenatureofthedata,weexpectindividualfirmspecificheterogeneitytoexistwithinthe model. Firms can vary systematically in terms of management, structure, operations, etc. 10

Consequentlytheuseofordinaryleastsquareswouldproduceestimatesthatarebiased.Therefore, theuseofpaneldataanalysisismoreappropriate. Thecrosssectionalparameterheterogeneitycanbecapturedusingfixedorrandomeffectsmodels. Totestwhichmodelismostappropriate,ahausmantestshasbeenperformed.Thehausmantests checkswhetherthefirmspecificrandomerrorisuncorrelatedwiththeexplanatoryvariables,which is a requirement for using the random effects model. Using the random effects model when the orthogonalityassumptionisviolatedresultsinlessconsistentestimates.Thehausmantestchecksa more efficient model against a less efficient but consistent model to make sure that the more efficient model also gives consistent results. The hausman test tests the null hypothesis that the coefficientsestimatedbytheefficientrandomeffectsmodelarethesameastheonesestimatedby the consistent fixed effects estimator (i.e orthogonality). The test statistic is asymptotically distributedasχ²(4).Thecalculatedteststatisticfortheregressionofthetotalfinancialdebtratioas well as for the regression of the longterm financial debt ratio results in significant pvalues, rejectingthenullhypothesisoforthogonality. Based on the result from the hausman test, the fixed effects model was used to estimate our regressions 2. The results are given intable2. Consideredjointly, thecalculated Fstatistic shows that the coefficients are significant. When using the logarithm of sales as a proxy for firm size and/ortangibleassetsfixedassetsexpandedwithaccountsreceivableandinventoriesscaledbytotal assets,themodeldoesnotameliorate.Wenowusethefittedvaluesofequation1and2astheproxy for the total and longterm financial debt ratio repectively. In the tradeoff model, firms have a targettotalandlongtermfinancialdebtratiotowardswhichtheyadjusteveryperiod.

4.2.2 Financial debt ratio as predicted by the pecking order theory Inthesimplestform,thepeckingorderstatesthatiftheinternalcashflowofthefirmisinsufficient foritsrealinvestments,thefirmissuesdebt.Todetermineifthefirmhasasurplusoradeficitwe calculatethefreecashflow.Wedefinethefreecashflow,FCF,offirm iinperiod tasfollows:

FCF ,ti = Operating cash flow after taxes at the end of period t – gross investment in operating fixedassetsinperiod t–increaseinworkingcapitalinperiod t. Theoperatingcashflowaftertaxesisdefinedastheoperatingprofit/lossofthecurrentperiodplus any noncash adjustmentsminus income taxes.Thegross investmentin operating fixedassets in period tisthechangeinoperatingfixedassetsfromtheendofperiod t1totheendofperiod t + recordeddepreciationandamountswrittendownonoperatingfixedassets–thedepreciationand amountswrittendowntakenback–revaluationsurplusesonoperatingfixedassets.Operatingfixed assetsareallfixedassetsexceptthefinancialfixedassets. Thenetincreaseinworkingcapitalinperiod tisdefinedastheworkingcapitalattheendofthe current period t – the working capital at the end of the previous period t1. Working capital is definedasallcurrentassetsthatdonotpayinterestminusallcurrentliabilitiesthatdonotcharge interest. We define the ‘target’ total andlongterm financialdebt ratio asthetotal respectively long term financialdebtofthepreviousperiodminusthefreecashflowforeveryfirm iinanyperiod tover totalassetsofthepreviousperiod.

2Usingtherandomeffectsmodel,however,leadstothesameconclusions,forbothourdescriptivestatistics asourestimatedresultsfortheequations3to12. 11

4.2.3 Industry averages Wewillalsousethemostrecentindustryaverageasthetargetvalueforourfinancialcomponents. The industry mean in year t is measured by averaging the values of the total (and longterm) financialratioofperiod t forallthefirms i inthatspecificindustryclasspresentinoursample. 4.3 Control variables In our adjustment model control variables are included as proxies for things that could cause deviationsfromthetargetfinancialdebtratios.Thesevariablesarefirmsize,returnoninvestment, historicalgrowthandadummyvariableforexpectedgrowthopportunities.Asaproxyforfirmsize weusethenaturallogarithmoftotalassets.Returnoninvestment,whichreflectsthepossibilityof retainedearnings,ismeasuredascurrentprofit/lossesbeforetaxesovertotalassets.Asaproxyfor historical growth we use the growth rate of total assets over a period of two years:

(TAt −TAt−2 )/TAt−2 . As a proxy for expected growth opportunities we use the ratio intangible assets to total assets and create a dummy variable equal to one if the firm has expected growth opportunitiesandzerootherwise.

5 DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS Table3presentssummarystatisticsofthesample.Theaveragedebtratioinoursampleis62.85%, of which 19.26% is financial debt. A large portion of the debt component therefore contains accountspayable,taxesandothernonfinancialdebt. < Insert Table 3 > Tables4to8indicatesomedifferencesinthefinancingbehaviouroffirmsindistinctclassesinour sample.Ouraimistoexplaindifferencesintermsoftheoneofthetwocapitalstructuretheories underinvestigation:thestatictradeofftheoryandthepeckingordertheory.Table4showssome characteristicswhenthefirmsareallocatedtotwoclassesbasedondummyvariable Ti,t .Dummy variable Ti,t isequalto1ifthetotal(longterm)financialdebtratioattheendofthepreviousperiod (beginningofthecurrentperiod)isbelowthetargetratiooftotal(longterm)financialdebt,and0 otherwise.Presentedmathematically,thisgivesthefollowing: * * 1if TFDT ,ti −TFDT ,ti −1 (LFDT ,ti − LFDT ,ti −1 )>0 T L T ,ti (T ,ti )= * * 0if TFDT ,ti −TFDT ,ti −1 (LFDT ,ti − LFDT ,ti −1 )≤0 < Insert Table 4 > Acloserlookattable4,revealsthatfirmsthatoperatebelowthetargetduringthepreviousperiod are,countertowhatthestatictradeofftheoryofcapitalstructurepredicts,asapercentage,more likelytodecreasetheirtotalandlongtermfinancialdebtratio.Thesefindingsareinlinewiththe resultsofDurinck,Laveren,VanHulleandVandenbroucke(1998).Thedecreaseoftotalandlong termfinancialdebtisevenmorepronouncedforfirmsoperatingabovethetarget.Thisisinline withthepredictionsofthetradeofftheory.Strikingthoughisthataverylargepercentageoffirms operatingabovethetarget,doesnotmovedowntowardsthetarget,butincreasetheirtotalfinancial debtratiosevenfurther.Itseemsthatfirmsthatareabovethetargetratioaremoredecisiveabout the changes of their totaland longterm financial debt. Finally, changesin equity capital are not significantlydifferentforfirmsoperatingaboveandbelowthetargetandunchangedcapitalisthe most frequent. This could be a logical consequence of the fact that small firms do not have 12 unlimitedaccesstowelldevelopedcapitalmarketsandusuallydependonbankfinancing(Berger andUdell,1998).However,itcouldalsobeafirstindicationforthepeckingordertheory. Therefore,intable5weassignfirmstotwodistinctclassesbasedondummyvariable Pi,t .Dummy variable Pi,t isequalto1ifthefreecashflowofthefirmispositive(cashsurplus)andequalto0 whenthefirmhasanegativeorzerofreecashflow(cashdeficit). < Insert Table 5 > Table5seemstoprovideevidenceforthepeckingordertheory.Firmswithanegativefreecash flowaremorelikelytoincreasetheirtotalfinancialdebtratiothanfirmswithapositivefreecash flow. The latter are more likely to decrease their total financial debt ratio. For the longterm financial debt ratio the results are similarfor firms with apositive free cash flow. However, for firms with a negative free cash flow, the pattern of the total financial debt ratios cannot be recognized in the longterm financial debt ratios. For firms with a negative free cash flow, the percentagethatincreasesthelongtermfinancialdebtratio(34.94%)issmallerthanforthetotal financialdebtratioandnotsignificantdifferentfromthepercentagethatdecreasesthelongterm financial debt ratio (36.75%). Table 5 shows that the proportion of increases in equity capital is higherforfirmthathaveadeficitofinternalfunds.Butmostlyequitycapitalremainsunchanged. Theseconclusionsareinlinewiththepeckingordertheorythatpredictsthatfirmswithinsufficient internalfinance(negativefreecashflow)increasetheirdependenceonexternalfinance,firsttheir shorttermdebt,thenlongtermdebtandfinallyequityfinancing. For firms with a negative free cash flow, the changes in longterm financial debt ratios do not exhibit the same pattern that is found for the changes of total financial debt ratios. This could suggestthatfirmsarenotabletoincreasetheirlongtermdebtthewaytheypleaseandthatshort termfinancialdebtisusedtopickuptheslack,whichwouldbeinlinewithfindingsofTaggartJr. (1977) who estimates a simultaneous equation model with equity, longterm and shortterm debt and liquid assets as dependent variables and finds that the adjustment to the longterm capital targetsisfairlyslow,andliquidassetsandshorttermdebtpickupthisslack. To get abetter understanding of the differencebetween changesin total and longterm financial debtratio,weexaminehowthechangesinthetotalfinancialdebtratiosarecomposed;isitlong termdebtorshorttermdebtthatchanges?Table6showsthatfor45.39%(14.59% +30.80% )ofthe observationwithanegativefreecashflowandanincreaseinthetotalfinancialdebtratio,itisnot thelongtermfinancialdebtratiothatincreasesbuttheshorttermfinancialdebtratiothatincreases enoughtoleadtoanincreaseinthetotalfinancialdebtratio.Whenfirmshaveapositivefreecash flow, total financial debt decreases in 57.75% of the cases (table 5). Firms seem to prefer to decrease longterm financial debt before shortterm financial debt. This is the case for 43.58% (15.30% + 28.28% ) of the observations while only for 20.89% ( 8.13% + 12.76% ) of the observationsshorttermfinancialdebtdecreasedwhilelongtermfinancialdebtisnot. < Insert Table 6 > Table7(forthetotalfinancialdebtratio)and8(forthelongtermfinancialdebtratio)showthe financingbehaviourbetweenfirms,whentheyaredistributedacrossfourdistinctclasses,basedon the four possible combinations of the dummy variables Ti,t and Pi,t . The four classes of observationsareasfollows: Ti,t =1and Pi,t =0meansbelowthetargetandanegativefreecashflow Ti,t =1and Pi,t =1meansbelowthetargetandapositivefreecashflow Ti,t =0and Pi,t =0meansabovethetargetandanegativefreecashflow Ti,t =0and Pi,t =1meansabovethetargetandapositivefreecashflow < Insert Table 7 > 13

Theincreasesinthetotalfinancialdebtratioaswellasinequitycapitalaremostfrequentwhenthe firm has insufficient internal funds, despite of whether the firm is below or above the target financialdebtratio.Thenumberofincreasesinthetotalfinancialdebtratiowhenthefirmisabove thetargetissignificantlygreaterthanwhenthefirmisbelowthetarget.Thesamecanbesaidfor increasesinequitycapital.Thedecreasesinthetotalfinancialdebtratioarealsodeterminedbythe amountoffreecashflowofthefirmandnotbythedeviationfromthetotalfinancialtargetdebt ratio, although thepercentage decreaseis significantly higher for firms above the target than for firmsbelowthetarget.Asintable4thepercentageofunchangedtotalfinancialdebtratiosisvery lowforfirmsoperatingabovethetarget.Forthechangesinequitycapital,unchangedequitycapital isdominantineachoftheclassesandnosignificantdifferencesarepresentbetweentheclassesata 1%significancelevel,asisthecasefordecreasesinequitycapital. < Insert Table 8 > Whenclassifyingthefirmsbasedontherelationbetweenthelongtermfinancialdebtratioofthe previousperiodandthelongtermfinancialtargetdebtratio,thesamefinancialbehaviourisfound. Yet,forfirmsbelowthetargetratiowithanegativefreecashflow,unchangedlongtermfinancial debt is more frequent than increases or decreases of debt, which indicates again that longterm financialdebtadjustsslowlytothefirm’sfinancingneed.Forobservationsbelowthetargetwitha positivefreecashflowthelongtermfinancialdebtratiosmostlyremaineitherunchangedorthey decrease.So,insomecasesthefreecashflowisusedtodecreaselongtermfinancialdebt,inother caseslongtermfinancialdebtseemstobemaintainedtomeetpossiblefuturefinancingneeds.Only in 15.71% we see the increase that is predicted by the tradeoff theory. Mostly firms operating abovethelongtermfinancialdebtratio,decreasestheirlongtermfinancialdebtratio.Therewhere table7showedanincreaseintotalfinancialdebtforfirmsoperatingabovethetotalfinancialtarget debtratiowithanegativefreecashflow,table8showsthatlongtermfinancialdebtismorelikely todecrease. Whenusingtheindustryaveragetotalandlongtermfinancialdebtratioastargets,theresultsare the same as when the target was determined by firmcharacteristics such as firm size, asset structure,profitabilityandhistoricalgrowth.Thesetablessuggestthatthefinancingbehaviourin firmsisnotcharacterisedbyapartialadjustmenttowardstheindustryaverage. < Insert Table 9, Table 10, Table 11> Becausewefindevidenceforthepeckingorder,wealsodistributeourobservationintotwoclasses * * basedonthedesireddebtratiobasedaccordingtothepeckingorder PTFDT ,ti ( PLFDT ,ti ),whichwe definedasthetotal(longterm)financialdebtofthepreviousperiodminusthefreecashflowofthe currentperiodovertotalassetsofthepreviousperiodforeveryfirm iinanyperiod t.Inanygiven yearthefirmcanbeoperatingaboveorbelowthetarget.Thereforewecreateadummyvariable Ii,t forthetotalfinancialdebtratioandforthelongtermfinancialdebtratio.Dummy variable Ii,t is equalto1ifthetotal(longterm)financialdebtratioattheendofthepreviousperiod(beginningof the current period) is below the target ratio of total (longterm) financial debt, and 0 otherwise. Presentedmathematically,thisgivesthefollowing: * * 1if PTFDT ,ti −TFDT ,ti −1 (PLFDT ,ti − LFDT ,ti −1 )>0(thusnegativefreecashflow) T L I ,ti (I ,ti )= * * 0if PTFDT ,ti −TFDT ,ti −1 (PLFDT ,ti − LFDT ,ti −1 )≤0(thuspositivefreecashflow) Thefindingsfromtable5areconfirmedintable12.Whenwecomparewithtable4wefindthat firmsthatarebelowthepeckingorder‘target’aremorelikelytoincreasetheirfinancialdebtratio, whilefirmsabovethepeckingorder‘target’aremorelikelytodecreasetheirfinancialdebtratio. 14

The proportions that decrease and increase are significantly different except for the longterm L financialdebtratioif I ,ti =1(34.96%versus36.71%). < Insert Table 12 > Fromthedescriptivedatathepeckingordertheoryseemstobesuperiortothetradeofftheory.This conclusionisconfirmedintable13wherewecheckhowfirm’sfinancingbehaviourrelatestothe firm’sprofitability. Thepercentage of observations where the total financial debt ratio decreases rises when profitability increases, while the percentage of observations where the total financial debtratioincreasesdrops.Lessprofitablefirmsseemtoappealtoequitycapital. < Insert Table 13 > Sofarwehavelookedatthepercentageofobservationsthatsatisfytheconditionsofthevarious classes.Theevidencefoundisinfavourofthepeckingordertheory.Firmswithanegativefreecash flowseemtoincreasetheirfinancialdebtratio.Intable14theaveragechangeinthetotalfinancial debtratiointhecurrentyearisrelatedtothetotalfinancialdebtratiointhepreviousperiod.For firms with a positive free cash flow the average change of the total financial debt ratio is significantly differentbetween the variousclasses and theaverage decreaseofthetotalfinancial debt ratio is higher for firms, the higher their total financial debt ratio in theprevious period as couldbeexpected.Firmswithanegativefreecashflowincreasetheirtotalfinancialdebtratiobut thereisnonegativerelationshipbetweenthetotalfinancialdebtratiointhepreviousperiodandthe averagechangeinthecurrentperiodoverthewholeline.Thenegativerelationshipemergeswhen thetotalfinancialdebtratioofthepreviousperiodisaround45%(seetable14bandfigure1).This indicatesthatfirmswithanegativefreecashflowtakeintoconsiderationtheirdebtcapacitywhen decidingonfurtherloans. < Insert Table 14 > Theresultsfromtable15suggestthatfirmsdonotfollowthecomplexpeckingorder.Theydonot take into consideration future growth opportunities when making their financing decisions. The average change ofthe total financial debtratio is not significantly differentat a 1% significance level, between observations with future growth opportunities and without future growth opportunities. The average change in the total financial debt ratio is only significantly different betweenobservationswithanegativefreecashflowandapositivefreecashflow,confirmingthe simplepeckingorder.

< Insert Table 15 >

6 MODEL SPECIFICATION Wetestourhypothesesusingatargetadjustmentmodelforfirm i attime t (equations3to12).This partialadjustmentmodelindicatesthatthechangeofthefinancialdebtratiofromperiod t1to t dependsbothonthetargetfinancialdebtratioforperiodtandthepreviousactualfinancialdebt ratioforperiod t1.Thechangeofthefinancialdebtratioisafunctionofthedifferencebetweenthe targetfinancialdebtratioandthecurrentfinancialdebtratio.Astargetfortotalfinancialdebtratio weusethefittedvaluesfromequation1inequation3andtheaverageindustrytotalfinancialdebt ratioinequation5.Astargetforthelongtermfinancialdebtratioweusethefittedvaluesfrom equation2inequation4andtheaverageindustrylongtermfinancialdebtratioinequation6. 15

T L By introducing the dummy variables T ,ti and T ,ti in the equations 3 and 4 respectively and the dummy variables IAT ,ti and IAL ,ti in equations 5 and 6 respectively, we allow the speed of adjustmentstodifferbetweenobservationsthatarebelowthetargetandthosethatareabovethe target. T * T * TFDT ,ti =α +δ1T ,ti (TFDT ,ti −TFDT ,ti −1 ) +δ 2 (1−T ,ti )(TFDT ,ti −TFDT ,ti −1 ) (3) L * L * LFDT ,ti =α + δ1T ,ti (LFDT ,ti − LFDT ,ti −1 ) + δ 2 (1− T ,ti )(LFDT ,ti − LFDT ,ti −1 ) (4)

TFDT,ti =α +δ1IAT,ti (INDAVT,ti −TFDT,ti −1 ) +δ 2 (1− IAT ,ti )(INDAVT,ti −TFDT,ti −1 ) (5)

LFDT,ti =α +δ1IAL ,ti (INDAVL,ti − LFDT,ti −1 ) +δ 2 (1− IAL ,ti )(INDAVL,ti − LFDT,ti −1 ) (6) * * 1if TFDT ,ti −TFDT ,ti −1 (LFDT ,ti − LFDT ,ti −1 )>0 T L with T ,ti (T ,ti )= * * 0if TFDT ,ti −TFDT ,ti −1 (LFDT ,ti − LFDT ,ti −1 )≤0

1if INDAVT −TFDT ,ti −1 (INDAVL− LFDT ,ti −1 )>0 and IAT ,ti (IAL ,ti )=

0if INDAVT −TFDT ,ti −1 (INDAVL− LFDT ,ti −1 )≤0 Thepredictionsforthetradeofftheoryconcerningchangesindebtratioscannowbetranslatedinto expectedvaluesforthecoefficients δkwherek=1,2.Accordingtothetradeofftheory,firmshave thetendencytomovetheirdebtratiotowardsthetargetdebtratio,whethertheyareaboveorbelow thetarget.Theadjustmenttothetargetisonlygradualduetocostsandconstraints.Therefore,the coefficients δkhavetobestrictlypositiveandsmallerthan1. Fromtheequations3to6wecannotdetermineiffirmsoperatingunder/abovethetargetbehave differentlydependingonwhethertheyhaveapositivefreecashfloworanegativefreecashflow. Totakethecashsituationoffirm i attime t intoconsiderationweintroducethedummyvariable Pi,t intoourequation.Therebydividingourobservationsintofourdistinctclasses. TFDT =α +δ T T P (TFDT * −TFDT ) +δ (1−T T )P (TFDT * −TFDT )+ ,ti 1 ,ti ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 2 ,ti ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 T * T * δ 3T ,ti ()1− P ,ti ()()TFDT ,ti −TFDT ,ti −1 +δ 4 1−T ,ti ()1− P ,ti ()TFDT ,ti −TFDT ,ti −1 (7) LFDT =α +δ T L P (LFDT * − LFDT ) +δ (1−T L )P (LFDT * − LFDT )+ ,ti 1 ,ti ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 2 ,ti ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 L * L * δ 3T ,ti ()1− P ,ti ()()LFDT ,ti − LFDT ,ti −1 +δ 4 1−T ,ti ()1− P ,ti ()LFDT ,ti − LFDT ,ti −1 (8) TFDT =α +δ IAT P (INDAVT −TFDT ) +δ (1− IAT )P (INDAVT −TFDT )+ ,ti 1 ,ti ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 2 ,ti ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 δ 3 IAT ,ti (1− P ,ti )(INDAVT ,ti −TFDT ,ti −1 )+δ 4 (1− IAT ,ti )(1− P ,ti )(INDAVT ,ti −TFDT ,ti −1 ) (9) LFDT =α +δ IAL P (INDAVL − LFDT ) +δ (1− IAL )P (INDAVL − LFDT )+ ,ti 1 ,ti ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 2 ,ti ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 δ 3 IAL ,ti (1− P ,ti )(INDAVL ,ti − LFDT ,ti −1 )+δ 4 (1− IAL ,ti )(1− P ,ti )(INDAVL ,ti − LFDT ,ti −1 ) (10) 1ifthefreecashflowispositive(surplus) with P i,t = 0ifthefreecashflowisnegativeorzero(deficit) 16

Whenthetradeoffmodelappliestoourdata,thecoefficients δk,where k=1,2,3,4havetobe strictlypositiveandsmallerthan1.Whenthepeckingorderappliestoourdata,weexpectthatfirms with a positive free cash flow to decrease their debt ratio, whether they are below the target or abovethetarget.Thisimpliesthatweexpectthecoefficients δ1tobenegativeand δ2topositive.If, on the other hand, firms have a negative free cash flow, δ3 is expected to be positive and δ4 is expected to be negative, because firms with a deficit are expected to increase their debt ratio, whethertheyareaboveorbelowthetargetratio. Becauseourdescriptivestatisticsseemtofavourthepeckingorder,wealsoestimateequations11 and12.Intheseequationswedonotincludeatradeofftarget,butthedebtratiowewouldexpect firmstochangetofollowingthepeckingorder. T * T * TFDT ,ti =α +δ1I ,ti (PTFDT ,ti −TFDT ,ti −1 ) +δ 2 (1− I ,ti )(PTFDT ,ti −TFDT ,ti −1 ) (11) T * T * LFDT ,ti =α +δ1I ,ti (PLFDT ,ti − LFDT ,ti −1 ) +δ 2 (1− I ,ti )(PLFDT ,ti − LFDT ,ti −1 ) (12) * * 1if PTFDT ,ti −TFDT ,ti −1 (PLFDT ,ti − LFDT ,ti −1 )>0 T L with I ,ti (I ,ti )= * * 0if PTFDT ,ti −TFDT ,ti −1 (PLFDT ,ti − LFDT ,ti −1 )≤0 * * and PTFDT ,ti (PLFDT ,ti )isthetotal(longterm)financialdebtofthepreviousperiodminusthefree cashflowovertotalassetsofthepreviousperiod.

7 ESTIMATION RESULTS Beforewestartwiththediscussionofourestimationresults,recallthatthetargetsusedinequations 3,4,7and8arecalculatedfromthefittedvaluesofequation1and2usingthefixedeffectsmodel. That decision to use the fixed effects model was based on the hausman chisquared statistic. However,itisimportanttonotethatusingtherandomeffectsmodelwouldnothavechangedthe findingsfromeitherthedescriptiveanalysisortheregressionanalysis. Themodelsareestimatedusingboththefixedeffectsmodelandtherandomeffectsmodel.The estimation results differ substantially when using the fixed effects model or the random effects model. There where the fixed effects model seems to support the tradeoff theory, the random effectsmodelseemstosupportthepeckingordertheory.Here,thechoicebetweenthetwomodels is not as straightforward. The hausman specification test suggests that the fixed effects model shouldbeused,becausethecalculatedteststatisticrejectsthenullhypothesisoforthogonalityatthe onepercentsignificancelevel.However,whenexplanatoryvariablesdonotvarymuchovertime, fixed effects can lead to imprecise estimates (Wooldridge, 2002), because they will be highly collinearwiththefixedeffects.Basedonthefindingsfromourdescriptiveanalysisandbecauseour explanatoryvariablesvaryonlyalittle,therandomeffectsmodelseemsmoreappropriate. < Insert Table 17 > Inregressions3and4weonlytakeintoconsiderationwhetherfirmsareoperatingbeloworabove the target, which is determined by their firmspecific characteristics. Table 17 shows that the estimatedcoefficientsfor δ1and δ2 arepositivebutsmallforboththetotalfinancialdebtratio(eq. 3)andthelongtermfinancialdebtratio(eq.4).Thiscouldindicatethatfirmsadjusttowardsthe tradeofftarget.However,theadjustmentisverysmallwhichmightsuggestthattheadjustmentand transactioncostsorconstraints(JalilvandandHarris,1984)aremuchlargerincomparisontothe costs of deviating from the target or thatthe firm has no desire toreach apredetermined target. When using industry averages as proxy for the total (eq. 5) and longterm (eq. 6) financial debt targetratios,thecoefficientsremainpositivebutsmall.Theadjustmentcoefficienttowardsthetotal financial debt ratio is not significant for firms operating below the industry average, but the 17 coefficientofthelongtermfinancialdebtratioforfirmsbelowtheindustryaverageissignificant. Overallitcanbesaidthattheequationswiththeindustrytargetsproducesimilarresultsaswhenthe targetisdeterminedbasedontheoreticalmodels.Thefactthattheadjustmentcoefficientsaresmall isanecessarybutinsufficientperquisitetorejecthypothesesH 1A andH 1B orH 5A andH 5B, butthese resultscouldbeafirstindicationofthepresenceofpeckingorderbehaviourinSMEs. According to the pecking order, firms increase their debt if the free cash flow is negative and decreasetheirdebtifthefreecashflowispositive.Whendividingourobservationsintofourclasses T basedondummyvariables T ,ti and Pforthetotalfinancialdebtratio,thecoefficients δ2 and δ3 (eq. 7)areinlinewithboththestatictradeofftheoryandthepeckingordertheory.Theformertheory explains the decrease ( δ2) of the total financial debt ratio based on the fact that the firm was operatingabovethetargetinthepreviousperiod.Theincrease( δ3)ofthetotalfinancialdebtratio canalsobeexplainedonthebasisofthedeviationfromthetargetbecausewhenfirmsarebelowthe target the tradeoff theory predicts an increase in the debt ratio. According to the pecking order theory,thechangesinthefinancialdebtratioareaconsequenceofthecashpositionofthefirm. Firmswithapositivefreecashflowdecrease( δ2)theirtotalfinancialdebtratioandfirmswitha negativefreecashflowincrease( δ3)theirfinancialdebtratio.Thestatisticsintable7confirmthis conclusion.Whenoperatingabovethetargetfinancialdebtratio,adeficitofinternalfundsforces thefirmtoincreasetheirtotalfinancialdebtratio( δ3<0),whichindicatesthatthepeckingorder theoryissuperiortothetradeofftheory.Observationsshowingasurplusofinternalfundsanda financial debt ratio below the target have an adjustment coefficient that is negative, which is consistentwiththepeckingordertheory,howeverthecoefficientisnotstatisticallydifferentfrom zero. A possible explanation could be that firms do use their free cash flow to decrease their financialdebtratio,butaremorelikelytodosoiftheirfinancialdebtratioishigher.Fromequation 8,thecameconclusionscanbedrawn,exceptfortheobservationsthathaveanegativefreecash flowandarealreadyoperatingabovethetarget.Theretheadjustmentisnotsignificantlydifferent fromzero. Equations 9 and 10 also distribute the observation into four classes based on whether they are operatingaboveorbelowthetargetandwhethertheyhaveapositivefreecashfloworanegative free cash flow. The difference with equations 7 and 8 is that the target is not determined as predictedbythetradeofftheorybuttheindustryaverageisused.Table17showsthattheresultsdo not change whether the industry averages are used as targets or whether more complicated calculationsareusedtodeterminethetarget.Firmswithanegativefreecashflowandadebtratio abovethatoftheindustryhavenosignificantadjustmentcoefficient,whichcouldbeconsideredas partial evidence of hypothesis H6c. Tables 10 and 11 already showed that the proportion of observationsthatincreasedtheircapitalishighestforfirmsinthisclass. Theanalysisofequations5to10providesevidenceinfavourofthepeckingordertheory.Therefore weruntwoadditionalregressionsinwhichwereplacethetargetdebtratiocalculatedaspredicted bythetradeofftheorybythedebtratioofthepreviousperiodcorrectedwiththefreecashflowof the current period scaled by total assets. The pecking order theory, after all, states that firm’s financingbehaviourisdeterminedbythefreecashflow.Firstofall,itshouldbenotedthattheR² increasesascomparedtothepreviousregressions.Theestimationresultsindicatethatfirmsthatare operating below this value, meaning that they have a negative free cash flow, adjust their total financialdebtratiowith89.41%andtheirlongtermdebtratiowith92.03%totheFCFcorrected debtratio.Firmswithapositivefreecashflowdecreasetheirdebtratiobutonlywith13%to20%. Longtermdebtdecreaseslessbutthatmightbeexplainedbythefactthatbankloansmostlyare repaidaccordingtoarepaymentscheduleorthatfirmsprefertoholdtheirfreecashforlaterusage. < Insert Table 18 > When reestimating equation 11 for observations with ahigh totalfinancial debtratio and alow totalfinancialdebtratio,wenoticethatfirmswithanegativefreecashflowrespondtothelackof internal funds without taking into consideration the current amount of debt. When reestimating equation 11 separately for firms with and without growth opportunities, we see that firms with growth opportunities either increase their debt more when they have growth opportunities and 18 decreasetheirdebtlessiftheyhavepositivefreecashflow.Combinedwiththestatisticsfromtable 15thiscontradictsthecomplexpeckingorder.

8 CONCLUSIONS The aim of our study was to scrutinize the underlying theoretical drivers behind the financing decisions in small and mediumsized firms. Given the special cognitive style of management in SMEs,characterizedbyboundedrationalityandintuition,weinvestigatewhetherthebehavioural principlehasahigherexplanatorypowerthanthetwotraditionalcompetingtheoriesinrelationto financingbehaviourinSMEs. We presented an elaborate descriptive analysis that gives a first indication that in small and mediumsized firms, the static tradeoff theory, which suggests using complex targets does not outperform the behavioural principle that proposes using the industry average as debt target. However,thedescriptiveanalysisseemstoprovidestrongevidenceinfavourofthepeckingorder theory. To test the contradicting theoretical predictions from the tradeoff theory and the pecking order theory and the behavioural principle we use several partial adjustment models. Due to the classificationofobservations,bytheuseofdummyvariables,wewereabletofocusmoredirectly on the classes for which the static tradeoff theory and the behavioural theory make other predictionsthatthepeckingordertheory.Themodelsusingtheindustryaveragesastargetsperform aswellasthemodelsinwhichamorecomplextarget,aspredictedbythestatictradeofftheoryis used,but do not seem tobe more explanatory. In small firms the static tradeoff theory and the behaviouralprinciplearelessimportantthanthepeckingordertheory,whichismoreprevailingin ourdata.Theregressionresultssupportthepredictionsprovidedbythepeckingordertheorythat firms decrease or increase their financial debt in correspondence to the availability or lack of internalfunds. 19

References AngJ.,1991.SmallBusinessUniquenessandTheTheoryofFinancialManagement. Journalof SmallBusinessFinance1(1) ,113. Baskin J., 1989. An Empirical Investigation of the Pecking Order Hypothesis. Financial Management19 ,2635. BergerA.N.andUdellG.F.,1995.Relationshiplendingandlinesofcreditinsmallfirmfinance. JournalofBusiness68(3) ,351382. BergerA.N.andUdellG.F.,1998.TheEconomicsofSmallBusinessFinance:TheRolesofPrivate EquityandDebtMarketsintheFinancialGrowthCycle. JournalofBanking&Finance22(6 8) ,613673. BowenR.M.,DaleyL.A.andHuberC.C.,Jr.,1982.EvidenceontheExistenceandDeterminantsof CatF.andGhoshA.,2003.TestsofCapitalStructureTheory:ABinomialApproach. Journalof Business&EconomicStudies9(2) ,2033. ChittendenF,HallG.andHutchinsonP.,1996.SmallFirmGrowth,AccesstoCapitalMarketsand Financial Structure: Review of Issues and an Empirical Investigation. Small Business Economics8 ,5967. DeAngelo A. and Masulis R., 1980. Optimal Capital Structure under Corporate and Personal Taxation. JournalofFinancialEconomics8 ,329. Dennis D.J., 2004. Entrepreneurial finance: an overview of the issues and evidence. Journal of CorporateFinance10 ,301326. DurinckE.,LaverenE.,VanHulleC.andVandenbrouckeJ.,1998.ConfrontingCapitalStructure Theories Empirically: Pecking Order versus Target Adjustment. Cahiers Economique de Bruxelles158 ,121144. Claggett E.T. Jr., 1991. Capital Structure: Convergent and Pecking Order Evidence. Review of FinancialEconomics1(1) ,3549. EmeryD.R.,Finnerty,J.D.andStowe,J.D.,2004. CorporateFinancialManagement .2 nd ed.Upper SaddleRiver:PrenticeHall. FamaE.F.andFrenchK.R.,2002.TestingTradeoffandPeckingOrderPredictionsaboutDividends andDebt. ThereviewofFinancialStudies15(1) ,p133. Ferri, M.G. and W.H. Jones, 1979. Determinants of Financial Structure: A New Methodological Approach. JournalofFinance34 ,631644. GrahamJ.R.,1996.Debtandthemarginaltaxrate. JournalofFinancialEconomics41 ,4173. HallG.,HutchinsonP.andMichaelasN.,2000.IndustryeffectsonthedeterminantsofUnquoted SMEs’capitalstructure. InternationalJournaloftheEconomicsofBusiness7(3) ,297312. HamiltonR.T.andFoxM.A.,1998.Thefinancingpreferencesofsmallfirmowners. International JournalofEntrepreneurialBehaviour&Research4(3) ,239248. HolmesS.andKentP.,1991.AnEmpiricalAnalysisoftheFinancialStructureofSmallandLarge AustralianManufacturingEnterprises. JournalofSmallBusinessFinance1(2) ,141154. Hovakimian A., OplerT.andTitman S., 2001.Thedebtequity choice. Journal offinancialand quantitativeanalysis36(1), 124. HsiaoC.,2003. Analysisofpaneldata .2 nd ed.CambridgeUniversityPress. HutchinsonP.,1999.SmallEnterprise:Finance,OwnershipandControl. InternationalJournalof ManagementReviews1(3) ,343365. Jalilvand A. and Harris R.S., 1984. Corporate Behavior in Adjusting to Capital Structure and DividendTargets:AnEconometricStudy. TheJournalofFinance39(1), 127145. JensenM.andMecklingW.,1976.TheoryoftheFirm:ManagerialBehavior,Agencycostsand OwnershipStructure. JournalofFinancialEconomics 3,305360. JordanJ.,LoweJ.andTaylorP.,1998.StrategyandFinancialPolicyinUKSmallfirms. Journalof BusinessFinanceandAccounting25(1) ,127. LevB.,1969.IndustryAveragesasTargetsforFinancialRatios. JournalofAccountingResearch , 290299. MarchJ.G.,1978.Boundedrationality,ambiguity,andtheengineeringofchoice. TheBellJournal ofEconomics9(2) ,587608. MarshP.,1982.TheChoiceBetweenDebtandEquity:AnEmpiricalStudy. JournalofFinance37 , 121144. Martin J.D. and Scott D.F., 1974. A discriminant analysis of the corporate debtequity decision. FinancialManagement3(4) ,7179. 20

Martin J.D. and Scott D.F., Jr., 1975. Industry Influences on Financial Structure. Financial Management4(1), 6773. MichaelasN.,ChittendenF.andPoutziourisP.,1999.FinancialPolicyandCapitalStructureChoice inU.K.SMEs:EmpiricalEvidencefromCompanyPanelData. SmallBusinessEconomics12 , 113130. MillerM.,1977.DebtandTaxes. Journaloffinance32 ,261275. ModiglianiF.andMillerM.,1958.TheCostofCapital,CorporationFinance,andTheTheoryof Investment. AmericanEconomicReview 48,261297. Modigliani F. and Miller M., 1963. Corporate Income Taxes and Cost of Capital: A Correction. AmericanEconomicReview53 ,433443. MyersS.C.,1984.Thecapitalstructurepuzzle. JournalofFinance34(3) ,575592. MyersS.C.,2001.CapitalStructure. JournalofEconomicPerspectives15(2), 81102. MyersS.C.andMajlufN.,1984.CorporateFinancingandInvestmentDecisionswhenFirmshave InformationInvestorsdonothave. JournalofFinancialEconomics13 ,187221. OzkanA.,2001.DeterminantsofCapitalStructureandAdjustmenttoLongRunTarget:Evidence fromUKCompanyPanelData. JournalofBusinessFinance&Accounting28(1)&(2) ,175 198. Pettit R.R. and Singer R.F., 1985, Small Business Finance: A research Agenda. Financial Management14(3), 4760. RajanR.G.andZingalesL.,1995.WhatdoweknowaboutCapitalStructure?Someevidencefrom internationaldata. JournalofFinance50(5) ,14211460. SadlerSmith, E. (2004). Cognitive style and the performance of small and medium sized enterprises. OrganizationStudies,25 ,155182 ShyamSunder L. and Myers S.C., 1999. Testing static tradeoff againstpecking order models of capitalstructure. JournalofFinancialEconomics51 ,219244. SpiesR.R.,1974.TheDynamicsofCorporateCapitalBudgetting. JournalofFinance29(3), 829 845. StiglitzJ.,1974.OntheIrrelevanceofCorporateFinancialPolicy. AmericanEconomicReview , 851866. Taggart R.A. Jr., 1977. A Model of Corporate Financing Decisions. Journal of Finance 32 (5) , 14671484. Titman S. and Wessels R., 1988. The determinants of Capital Structure Choice. The Journal of Finance43(1) ,119. Van der Wijst D., 1989. Financial structure in small business. Theory, tests and applications. Lecturenotesineconomicsandmathematicalsystems,n°320.SpringerVerlag. Van der Wijst N. and Thurik R., 1993. Determinants of Small Firm Debt Ratios: An anlysis of RetailPanelData, SmallBusinessEconomics5 ,5565. VoordeckersW.,1999.Eenonderzoeknaardedeterminantenvandekapitaalstructuurvankleine industriële ondernemingen: theorievorming met behulp van een casestudyonderzoek en empirischetoetsing,UnpublishedDoctoralDissertation,LimburgUniversityCenter. Wooldridge J.M. ,2002. Econometric analysis of crosssection and panel data . The MIT Press, Cambridge,Massachusetts. 21

Appendix 1 N° firms NaceBel Sector Activity per activitycode N° sector 15 Manufactureoffoodproducts 1 66 16 Manufactureoftabaccoproducts 17 Manufactureoftextiles 18 Manufactureofwearingapparel 2 42 19 Tanning&dressingofleather 20 Manufactureofwood 3 15 21 Manufactureofpulp&paper 4 11 22 Publishingandprinting 5 27 23 Manufactureofcoke 6 24 24 Manufactureofchemicals 25 Manufactureofrubberproducts 7 28 26 Manufactureofmineralproducts 8 34 27 Manufactureofbasicmetals 9 13 28 Manufactureoffabricatedmetalproducts 10 43 29 Manufactureofmachinery&equipment 11 38 30 Manufactureofcomputers 31 Manufactureofelectricalmachinery 12 23 32 Manufactureofradio&telecommunication 33 Manufactureofmedicalinstruments 34 Manufactureofmotorvehicles 13 12 35 Manufactureofothertransportequipment 36 Manufactureoffurniture 14 21 50 Saleofmotorvehicles 15 73 Whole sale of agricultural raw materials and live 16 9 animals Wholesaleoffood,beveragesandliveanimals 17 72 Wholesaleofhouseholdgoods 18 113 51 Wholesale of nonagricultural intermediate products, 19 99 wasteandscrap Wholesaleofmachinery,equipmentandsupplies 20 81 Otherwholesale 21 10 52 Retailtrade 22 45 22

Appendix 2: Tables

Table 1 Overview of variables and measures

Variable Label Measure/proxy Equitycapital C  Issuedanduncalledcapital

Debtratio DT  Debtovertotalassets

Total financial debt TFDT  Financial debt payable after one year, plus financial ratio debtpayablewithinoneyearpluscurrentportionsof debtsafteroneyearovertotalassets Longtermfinancial LFDT  Financial debt payable after one year plus current debtratio portionsofdebtsafteroneyearovertotalassets Shorttermfinancial SFDT  Financialdebtpayablewithinoneyear debtratio Totalassets TA  Balancesheettotal

Changeintotal TFDT TFDT −TFDT ,ti ,ti −1 financialdebtratio  TFDT ,ti = TA ,ti −1

Change in longterm LFDT LFDT − LFDT ,ti ,ti −1 financialdebtratio  LFDT ,ti = TA ,ti −1 Change in shortterm SFDT SFDT − SFDT ,ti ,ti −1 financialdebtratio  SFDT ,ti = TA ,ti −1 Targetlongterm LFDT *  Fittedvaluesoftheregressionresultsobtainedbythe financialdebtratio fixedeffectsmodel(table2) L * T ,ti  1if LFDT ,ti − LFDT ,ti −1 >0,otherwise0 Targettotalfinancial TFDT *  Fittedvaluesoftheregressionresultsobtainedbythe debtratio fixedeffectsmodel(table2) T * T ,ti  1if TFDT ,ti −TFDT ,ti −1 >0,otherwise0 Freecashflow FCF  Operatingcashflowaftertaxesattheendofperiod– grossinvestmentinoperatingfixedassetsinperiod– netincreaseinworkingcapitalinperiod

Pi,t  1ifFCF>0;otherwise0

Pecking order total PTFDT *  Totalfinancialdebtofthepreviousperiodminusthe financialdebtratio freecashflowovertotalassetsofthepreviousperiod, restrictedtothe[0,1] T * I ,ti  1if PTFDT ,ti −TFDT ,ti −1 >0,otherwise0 Pecking order long – PLFDT *  Longtermfinancialdebtofthepreviousperiodminus termfinancialdebt the free cash flow over total assets of the previous ratio period,restrictedtotheinterval[0,1] L * I ,ti  1if PLFDT ,ti −TLFDT ,ti −1 >0,otherwise0 Industryaverages INDAVT  measured by averaging the values of the total (and (INDAVL) longterm)financialratioofperiod t forallthefirms i inthatspecificindustryclasspresentinoursample 23

IAT i,t  1if INDAVT i,t –TFDT i,t1>0,otherwise0

IAL i,t  1if INDAVL i,t –LFDT i,t1>0,otherwise0

Firmsize S1  Naturallogarithmoftotalassets

S2  Naturallogarithmofsales

Assetstructure AssStr1  Tangibleassetsovertotalassets

AssStr2  Tangible assets expanded with accounts receivable andinventoriesscaledbytotalassets Profitability Prof  Ratioofpretaxprofitstototalassetsforaperiodof twoyears Growthopportunities Growhtopp  Intangibleassetsovertotalassets

Grdum  1ifGrowthopp>0,otherwise0

Historicalgrowth Histgrowth  Growthrateoftotalassetsoveraperiodoftwoyears: (TA t–TA t2)/ TA t2 Returnoninvestment ROI  Currentprofit/lossesbeforetaxesovertotalassets

Table 2 Fixed effects model for total financial debt ratio and long-term financial debt ratio Equationnumber 1 2 Dependentvariable TFDT LFDT 0.2901461 0.1997128 Constant (0.0354881) ** (0.0245359) ** 0.0469448 0.0253079 Firmsize(S1) (0.00404) ** (0.0027932) ** 0.4209704 0.4130974 Assetstructure(AssStr2) (0.0187025) ** (0.0129306) ** 0.0567684 0.0031949 Profitability (0.0096311) ** (0.0066588) 0.0691943 0.00687 Growthopportunities (0.0761092) * (0.0526208) Numberofobs 7192 7192 Numberofgroups 899 899 Rsqwithin 0.0962 0.1460 F(4,6289) 167.30 ** 268.72 ** Standarderrorsinparenthesis:**significantat1%significancelevel,*significantat5%significancelevel. Theproxytomeasureassetstructure(AssStr1)istangiblefixedassetsscaledbytotalassets.Theproxyfor firmsizeS1isthenaturallogarithmoftotalassets.Asaproxyforgrowthopportunities(growthopp)theratio ofintangibleassetstototalassetsischosenandasaproxyforprofitability(prof)theratioofpretaxprofitsto total assets for a period of two years is chosen. When using AssStr2 (tangible fixed assets expanded with accounts receivable and inventories scaled by total assets) or S2 (the natural logarithm of sales) the explanatorypowerofthemodeldrops .

24

Table 3 Sample statistics Standard Mean (*) Median (*) Min (*) Max (*) deviation (*) DT 62.85% 66.27% 21.95% 2.20% 99.91%

TFDT 19.26% 14.99% 18.58% 0.00% 92.17%

LFDT 9.40% 4.51% 11.92% 0.00% 76.46%

TFDT 15.15% 0.00% 20.13% 75.81% 939.52%

LFDT 0.47% 0.00% 13.43% 54.86% 712.18%

C 33.70 0.00% 796.58 25193 40000

TFDT * 19.25% 18.64% 7.00% 1.17% 52.62%

LFDT * 9.439 8.28% 6.19% 3.86% 39.71%

INDAVT 19.29% 20.40% 4.17% 8.88% 36.42%

INDAVL 9.42% 9.51% 3.46% 2.70% 21.51%

PTFDT * 17.27% 10.56% 19.83% 0.00% 100%

PLFDT * 9.97% 2.26% 14.54% 0.00% 100%

FCF 1104.74 224.00 2715.86 11362.14 14316.36

Totalassets 7928.36 5482.00 7215.90 296.00 97871

Sales 15296.73 10745.50 15270.29 442.00 279975

AssStr1 17.92% 14.75% 14.31% 0.00% 83.41%

AssStr2 82.50% 87.74% 16.41% 5.97% 99.98%

Prof 0.94% 0.36% 10.84% 128.89% 1031.34%

Growthopp 0.52% 0.00% 2.15% 0.00% 55.43%

Histgrowth 13.08% 7.55% 32.90% 82.41% 277,14%

ROI 6.92% 5.49% 9.76% 84.84% 59.48%

(*) Statisticsarecalculatedoverallyearsandfirmscombined. 25

Table 4

T 3 A. Some characteristics of the distinct classes based on T ,ti

T T T ,ti =1 T ,ti =0 56.08% 43.92%

TFDT i,t >0 32.06% 42.89% • TFDT i,t =0 29.90% 1.46% • TFDT i,t <0 38.04% 55.65% •

Ci,t >0 8.50% 9.09% Ci,t =0 90.18% 89.68% C i,t <0 1.32% 1.23% (*) (**) Percentageofthesampleinthecolumn. Percentageperclassthatsatisfiestherowchange.Symbols: Tit : below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod. •Indicatesthattheproportionsofthatspecificrowaresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel. Theproportionsinthecellsaresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel.

L 4 B. Some characteristics of the distinct classes based on T ,ti

L L T ,ti =1 T ,ti =0 58.68% 41.32%

LFDT i,t >0 20.33% 26.58% • LFDT i,t =0 45.09% 5.28% • LFDT i,t <0 34.57% 68.57% •

Ci,t >0 8.67% 8.88% Ci,t =0 89.91% 90.04% C i,t <0 1.42% 1.08% (*) (**) Percentageofthesampleinthecolumn. Percentageperclassthatsatisfiestherowchange.Symbols: Tit : below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod. •Indicatesthattheproportionsofthatspecificrowaresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel. Theproportionsinthecellsaresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel.

3(2) Whendividingtheobservationintomorethentwocategorieswefindnoadditionalinformation. Whenusingtheindustryaverageasthetarget,theresultsaresimilar(seetable9). 26

Table 5

Some characteristics of the distinct classes based on Pi,t Pi,t =0 Pi,t =1 33.59% (*) 66.41%

(**) TFDT i,t >0 61.55% 24.31% • TFDT i,t =0 16.35% 17.94% TFDT i,t <0 22.10% 57.75% •

5 LFDT i,t >0 34.94% 16.83% • LFDT i,t =0 28.31% 28.81% LFDT i,t <0 36.75% 54.36% •

Ci,t >0 10.35% 7.96% • Ci,t =0 88.57% 90.66% • C i,t <0 1.08% 1.38% (*) Percentageofthesampleinthecolumn. (**) Percentageperclassthatsatisfiestherowchange.Symbols: Pi,t :positivefreecashflow(=1)ornegativefreecashflow(=0) •Indicatesthattheproportionsofthatspecificrowaresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel. Theproportionsinthecellsaresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel. Table 6 In depth investigation of changes in the components of the total financial debt ratio

Pi,t = 0 Pi,t =1

TFDT i,t TFDT i,t

>0 =0 <0 >0 =0 <0

(*) LFDT i,t >0 SFDT i,t >0 31.81% 0% 0% 19.73% 0% 0%

LFDT i,t =0 SFDT i,t >0 14.59% 0% 0% 14.99% 0% 0%

LFDT i,t <0 SFDT i,t >0 30.80% 0.25% 14.04% 35.40% 0.35% 15.30%

LFDT i,t >0 SFDT i,t =0 13.38% 0% 0% 16.45% 0% 0%

LFDT i,t =0 SFDT i,t =0 0% 99.75% 0% 0% 99.18% 0%

LFDT i, t<0 SFDT i,t =0 0% 0% 45.51% 0% 0% 28.28%

LFDT i,t >0 SFDT i,t <0 9.42% 0% 5.99% 13.43% 0.47% 8.13%

LFDT i,t =0 SFDT i,t <0 0% 0% 13.67% 0% 0% 12.76%

LFDT i,t <0 SFDT i,t <0 0% 0% 20.79% 0% 0% 35.53%

(*) Percentageperclassthatsatisfiestherowchange.Symbol: Pi,t :positivefreecashflow(=1)ornegative freecashflow(=0)

5Whenexpandinglongtermdebtwithcurrentportionsofdebtsafteroneyear,thefinancingbehaviourdoes notchange. 27

Table 7 T 6 Some characteristics of the distinct classes based on T ,ti and Pi,t T T T T T ,ti =1& Pi,t =0 T ,ti =1& Pi,t =1 T ,ti =0& Pi,t =0 T ,ti =0& Pi,t =1 20.16% 36.51% 13.43% 29.90%

TFDT i,t >0 50.83% 21.82% 77.64% 27.35% TFDT i,t =0 26.21% 31.53% 1.55% 1.35% TFDT i,t <0 22.97% 46.65% 20.81% 71.30%

Ci,t >0 9.52% 8.19% 11.59% 7.67% Ci,t =0 89.17% 90.52% 87.68% 90.84% C i,t <0 1.31% 1.29% 0.72% 1.49% (*) (**) Percentageofthesampleinthecolumn. Percentageperclassthatsatisfiestherowchange.Symbols: Ti,t : below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod; Pi,t :positivefreecashflow(=1)ornegativefree cashflow(=0) The proportions for TFDT i,t > 0, are pairwise all significantly different at a 1% significance level. The proportions for TFDT i,t =0arepairwisesignificantlydifferentata1%significance level, except for the proportionsinthetwolastcolumns.Theproportionsfor TFDT i,t <0arepairwisesignificantlydifferentata 1% significance level except for the proportions in class 1 and 3. The proportions for C i,t >0are not significantlydifferentpairwiseata1%significancelevelexceptfortheproportionsinclass2and3andclass 3 and 4. The proportions for C i,t = 0 and C i,t < 0 are not significantly different pairwise at a 1% significancelevel.Theproportionswithineachcellaresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel. Table 8 L 7 Some characteristics of the distinct classes based on T ,ti and Pi,t L L L L T ,ti =1&P i,t =0 T ,ti =1& Pi,t =1 T ,ti =0& Pi,t =0 T ,ti =0& Pi,t =1 20.27% 38.40% 13.32% 28.01%

LFDT i,t >0 29.08% 15.71% 43.84% 18.37% LFDT i,t =0 43.14% 46.13% 5.74% 5.06% LFDT i,t <0 27.78% 38.16% 50.42% 76.56%

Ci,t >0 9.60% 8.18% 11.48% 7.65% Ci,t =0 89.23% 90.26% 87.58% 91.21% C i,t <0 1.17% 1.56% 0.94% 1.14% (*) (**) Percentageofthesampleinthecolumn. Percentageperclassthatsatisfiestherowchange.Symbols: Ti,t : below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod; Pi,t :positivefreecashflow(=1)ornegativefree cashflow(=0) Theproportionsfor LFDT i,t >0,aresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel,exceptthoseinclass2 and4.Theproportionsfor LFDT i,t =0arepairwisesignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel,except fortheproportionsinclass1and2,andclass3and4whicharestatisticallythesame.Theproportionsfor LFDT i,t <0arepairwisesignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel.Theproportionsfor C i,t >0are not significantly different at a 1% significance level except for the proportions in class 3 and 4. The proportionsfor C i,t =0arepairwisenotsignificantlydifferent,exceptfortheproportionsinclass3and4at a1%significancelevel.Theproportionsfor C i,t <0arepairwisestatisticallythesameineachclass.The proportionsinthecellsaresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel.

6(5) Whenusingtheindustryaverageasthetarget,theresultsaresimilar(seetable10andtable11). 28

Table 9

A. Some characteristics of the distinct classes based on IAT i,t IAT i,t =1 IAT i,t =0 56.19% 43.81%

TFDT i,t >0 31.77% 43.29% • TFDT i,t =0 30.17% 1.05% • TFDT i,t <0 38.06% 55.66% •

Ci,t >0 8.29% 9.36% Ci,t =0 90.50% 89.27% Ci,t <0 1.21% 1.36% (*) Percentageofthesampleinthecolumn. (**) Percentageperclassthatsatisfiestherowchange.Symbols: IAT it :below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod. •Indicatesthattheproportionsofthatspecificrowaresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel. Theproportionsinthecellsaresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel.

B. Some characteristics of the distinct classes based on IAL i,t IAL i,t =1 IAL i,t =0 61.75% 38.25%

LFDT i,t >0 19.68% 28.14% • LFDT i,t =0 44.76% 2.62% • LFDT i,t <0 35.56% 69.25% •

Ci,t >0 8.53% 9.12% Ci,t =0 90.14% 89.68% Ci,t <0 1.33% 1.20% (*) Percentageofthesampleinthecolumn. (**) Percentageperclassthatsatisfiestherowchange.Symbols: IAL it :below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod. •Indicatesthattheproportionsofthatspecificrowaresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel. Theproportionsinthecellsaresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel. 29

Table 10

Some characteristics of the distinct classes based on IAT i,t and Pi,t IAT i,t =1& Pi,t =0 IAT i,t =1& Pi,t =1 IAT i,t =0& Pi,t =0 IAT i,t =0& Pi,t =1 19.66% 36.53% 13.93% 29.88%

TFDT i,t >0 49.50% 22.23% 78.54% 26.85% TFDT i,t =0 27.09% 31.82% 1.20% 0.98% TFDT i,t <0 23.41% 45.95% 20.26% 72.17%

Ci,t >0 9.05% 7.88% 12.18% 8.05% Ci,t =0 89.75% 90.90% 86.93% 90.37% Ci,t <0 1.20% 1.22% 0.90% 1.58% (*) Percentageofthesampleinthecolumn. (**) Percentageperclassthatsatisfiestherowchange.Symbols: IAT i,t :below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetintheprevious period; Pi,t : positive free cash flow (= 1) or negativefreecashflow(=0) The proportions for TFDT i,t > 0, are pairwise significantly different at a 1% significance level. The proportions for TFDT i,t =0arepairwisesignificantlydifferentata1%significance level, except for the proportionsinthetwolastcolumns.Theproportionsfor TFDT i,t<0arepairwisesignificantlydifferentata 1%significancelevelexceptfortheproportionsinclass1and3.Theproportionsfor C i,t >0arepairwise notsignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevelexceptfortheproportionsinclass2and3andclass3and 4.Theproportionsfor C i,t =0arepairwisenotsignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel,exceptfor theproportioninclass3whichissignificantlydifferentfromtheproportionsinclass2and4.Theproportions of C i,t < 0 are pairwise not significantly different. The proportions within each cell are significantly differentata1%significancelevel. Table 11

Some characteristics of the distinct classes based on IAL i,t and Pi,t IAL i,t =1& Pi,t =0 IAL i,t =1& Pi,t =1 IAL i,t =0& Pi,t =0 IAL i,t =0& Pi,t =1 21.47% 40.28% 12.12% 26.13%

LFDT i,t >0 27.14% 15.71% 48.74% 18.57% LFDT i,t =0 42.75% 45.84% 2.75% 2.55% LFDT i,t <0 30.12% 38.45% 48.51% 78.87%

Ci,t >0 9.20% 8.18% 12.39% 7.61% Ci,t =0 89.77% 90.33% 86.47% 91.17% Ci,t <0 1.04 1.48% 1.15% 1.22% (*) Percentageofthesampleinthecolumn. (**) Percentageperclassthatsatisfiestherowchange.Symbols: IAL i,t :below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetintheprevious period; Pi,t : positive free cash flow (= 1) or negativefreecashflow(=0) TheproportionsforLFDTi,t>0,arepairwisesignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel,exceptthose inclass2and4.TheproportionsforLFDTi,t=0arepairwisesignificantlydifferentata1%significance level, except for the proportions in class 1 and 2, and class 3 and 4 which are statistically the same. The proportionsforLFDTi,t<0arepairwisesignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel.Theproportions forCi,t>0arepairwisenotsignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevelexceptfortheproportionsin class2and3andclass3and4.TheproportionsforCi,t=0arepairwisestatisticallythesameforeach class,exceptfortheproportioninclass3whichissignificantlydifferentfromtheproportionsinclass2and4 ata1%significancelevel.TheproportionsforCi,t<0arepairwisenotsignificantlydifferentata1% significancelevel.Theproportionsinthecellsaresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel. 30

Table 12

T A. Some characteristics of the distinct classes based on I ,ti

T T I ,ti =1 I ,ti =0 33.54% (*) 66.46%

(**) TFDT i,t >0 61.57% 25.23% • TFDT i,t =0 16.33% 17.95% TFDT i,t <0 22.10% 57.72% •

Ci,t >0 10.36% 7.95% • Ci,t =0 88.56% 90.67% • C i,t <0 1.08% 1.38% (*) (**) Percentageofthesampleinthecolumn. Percentageperclassthatsatisfiestherowchange.Symbols: Ii,t : below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod. •indicatesthattheproportionsofthatspecificrowaresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel. Theproportionsinthecellsaresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel.

L B. Some characteristics of the distinct classes based on I ,ti

L L I ,ti =1 I ,ti =0 33.52% (*) 66.48%

(**) LFDT i,t >0 34.96% 16.84% • LFDT i,t =0 28.33% 28.80% LFDT i,t <0 36.71% 54.36% •

Ci,t >0 10.37% 7.95% • Ci,t =0 88.56% 90.67% • C i,t <0 1.08% 1.38% (*) (**) Percentageofthesampleinthecolumn. Percentageperclassthatsatisfiestherowchange.Symbols: Ii,t : below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod. •indicatesthattheproportionsofthatspecificrowaresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel. Theproportionsinthecellsaresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel. 31

Table 13 A. Financing behaviour in relation to profitability

Percentilesofprofitability <2,87% [2.87%0.36%] [0.36%4.39%] >4.39%

8 (*) TFDT i,t >0 38.22% 42.60% 37.21% 29.25% TFDT i,t =0 20.63% 12.96% 14.58% 21.47% TFDT i,t <0 41.15% 44.44% 48.21% 49.28%

Ci,t >0 10.01% 8.29% 7.73% 9.01% Ci,t =0 88.43% 90.71% 91.32% 89.38% C i,t <0 1.56% 1.00% 0.95% 1.61% (*) Percentage per class that satisfies the row change. The class boundaries are determined based on the percentiles25,50and75. For TFDT i,t >0,theproportionofclass4ispairwisesignificantlydifferentfromtheproportionsintheother classes at a 1 % significance level. The proportions in class 2 and 3 are also statistically different. The proportions for TFDT i,t =0arepairwisesignificantlydifferentata1%significance level, except for the proportions in class 1 and 4 and also class 2 and 3. The proportions for TFDT i,t < 0 are pairwise not significantlydifferentexceptfortheproportioninclass1whichissignificantlydifferentfromtheproportions inclass3and4,ata1%significancelevel.Theproportionsof C i,t arepairwisestatisticallythesameexcept fortheproportionsinclass1and4when C i,t >0,ata1%significancelevel. Theproportionsinthecellsaresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel. B. Average change of the total financial debt ratio and equity capital in relation to profitability Profitability <2,87% [2.87%0.36%] [0.36%4.39%] >4.39%

TFDT i,t >0 0.13129 0.08799 0.10018 0.11716 TFDT i,t =0 0 0 0 0 TFDT i,t <0 0.05417 0.05113 0.05279 0.06517

Ci,t >0 714.8667 247.7987 667.6115 775.3889 Ci,t =0 0 0 0 0 Ci,t <0 1960.571 1869.611 1485.059 958.931 (*) Averagechangeofthetotalfinancialdebtratiooffirmsthatsatisfythecolumnandrowcondition.The classboundariesaredeterminedbasedonthepercentiles25,50and75. Theaveragedecreasesofthetotalfinancialdebtratioaresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel betweenthefourclasses.Theotherchangesarestatisticallythesame.

8Theresultsforthelongtermfinancialdebtratioexhibitthesamepatterns. 32

Table 14 A. Average change of the total financial debt ratio in the current year related to the total financial debt ratio in the previous period and the cash position of the firm

Totalfinancialdebtratioofthepreviousperiod <1.26% [1.26%15.31%] [15.31%32.57%] >32.57%

(*) Pi,t = 1 0.01811 0.00553 0.02793 0.05130

Pi,t =0 0.03463 0.08108 0.07650 0,11322 (*) Averagechangeofthetotalfinancialdebtratiooffirmsthatsatisfythecolumnandrowcondition.Symbol: Pi,t :positivefreecashflow(=1)ornegativefreecashflow(=0).Theclassboundariesaredeterminedbased onthepercentiles25,50and75. Theaveragechangesofthetotalfinancialdebtratioaresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevelover therows.Theaveragechangesofthetotalfinancialdebtratiowithintheclassesaresignificantlydifferentata 1% significance level, except for the average changes in the first class (total financial debt ratio in the previousperiod<1.26%). B. Average change of the total financial debt ratio in the current year related to the total financial debt ratio in the previous period and the cash position of the firm Totalfinancialdebtratioofthepreviousperiod [32.57%46.52%] [46.52%54.44%] >54.44%

Pi,t = 1 0.03822 0.06235 0.07794

Pi,t =0 0,12797 0.09612 0.08259 (*)Averagechangeofthetotalfinancialdebtratiooffirmsthatsatisfythecolumnandrowcondition. Symbol: Pi,t :positivefreecashflow(=1)ornegativefreecashflow(=0).Theclassboundariesare determinedbasedonthepercentiles75,90and95. 33

Figure 1 Averagechangeofthetotalfinancialdebtratiorelatedto thetotalfinancialdebtratioofthepreviousperiod 20 )

0

-20

40

0to15% 15to30 % 30to45%45to60% 60to75%75to90% 90to100% Averagechangeofthetotalfinancialdebtratio(% Totalfinancialdebtratioofthepreviousperiod

34

Table 15 Average change of the total financial debt ratio in the current year related future growth opportunities, calculated as intangible over total assets in the current year, and the cash position 9

Futuregrowthopportunities No(0) Yes(>0)

Pi,t =1 0.15479 0.02090

Pi,t =0 0.07391 0.08005 (*) Averagechangeofthetotalfinancialdebtratiooffirmsthatsatisfythecolumnandrowcondition.Symbol: Pi,t :positivefreecashflow(=1)ornegativefreecashflow(=0).Theproxyforgrowthopportunitiesis intangibleassetsovertotalassets. The average changes are not significantly different at a 1% significance level over the rows. The average changeswithineachclassoffuturegrowthopportunities,aresignificantlydifferentata1%significancelevel.

9Whenrelatingtheaveragechangeofthetotalfinancialdebtratioofthecurrentyear ttofuturegrowth opportunities,calculatedasintangibleovertotalassetsinthenextperiod t+1, theresultsare: for Pi,t =1:–0.02102;0.02493andfor P i,t =0: 0.06969;0.08205 35

Table 16 Regresson results obtained by the fixed effects model 10

Equationnumber 3 4 5 6 Dependentvariable TFDT LFDT TFDT LFDT .0150971 .0113729 .0287802 .0139128 Constant (.0061849) * (.0034364) ** (.0067789) ** (.0042055) **

T * .7220006 T (TFDT −TFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0581791) **

T * .71461 (1−T )(TFDT −TFDT ) ** ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0392578)

L * .6092675 T (LFDT − LFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0617673) **

L * .7187955 (1−T )(LFDT − LFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0354226) **

* .5517993 IAT INDAVT −TFDT ,ti ( ,ti ,ti −1 ) (.0618545) **

* .7312442 (1− IAT )(INDAVT −TFDT ) ** ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0404866)

* .5242733 IAL (INDAVL − LFDT ) ** ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0717121)

* .6847756 (1− IAL ) INDAVL − LFDT ** ,ti ( ,ti ,ti −1 ) (.034882) Numberofobs 7192 7192 7192 7192 Numberofgroups 899 899 899 899 Rsqwithin 0.0971 0.0984 0.0844 0.0889 Rsqoverall 0.0071 0.0150 0.0055 0.0105 F(4,6289) 338.25 ** 343.41 ** 289.98 ** 306.82 ** Symbols: Ti,t :below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod; IAT i,t :below(=1)orabove(=0) thetargetinthepreviousperiod; IAL i,t :below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod IAL i,t : below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod.

10 Theestimates,forallthemodels,aresimilarwhenextendingthemodelswithcontrolvariablessuchasfirm size(S1),returnoninvestmentandadummyforgrowthopportunitiesandarethereforenotincludedinthe paper. 36

Equationnumber 7 8 9 10 Dependentvariable TFDT LFDT TFDT LFDT .0115174 .0130983 .0236755 .0144114 Constant (.0061473) (.0034513) ** (.006716) ** (.0041934) **

T * .6148885 T P (TFDT −TFDT ) ** ,ti ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0625068)

T * .7996984 (1−T )P (TFDT −TFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0390805) **

T * .8403525 T (1− P )(TFDT −TFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.060791) **

T * .2833713 (1−T )(1− P )(TFDT −TFDT ) ** ,ti ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0502991)

L * .4749645 T P (LFDT − LFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0683278) **

L * .7801962 (1−T )P (LFDT − LFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0370348) **

L * .7174852 T (1− P )(LFDT − LFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0661875) **

L * .5775846 (1−T )(1− P )(LFDT − LFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0458342)**

* .4509541 IAT P INDAVT −TFDT ,ti ,ti ( ,ti ,ti −1 ) (.0647973) **

* .8083142 (1− IAT )P INDAVT −TFDT ** ,ti ,ti ( ,ti ,ti −1 ) (.0402249)

* .7089203 IAT (1− P )(INDAVT −TFDT ) ** ,ti ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.065449)

* .310085 (1− IAT )(1− P ) INDAVT −TFDT ** ,ti ,ti ( ,ti ,ti −1 ) (.0512279)

* .4179458 IAL P INDAVL − LFDT ,ti ,ti ( ,ti ,ti −1 ) (.0753965) **

* .7481168 (1− IAL )P (INDAVL − LFDT ) ** ,ti ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0360248)

* .6634835 IAL (1− P ) INDAVL − LFDT ** ,ti ,ti ( ,ti ,ti −1 ) (.0776729)

* .5202605 (1− IAL )(1− P ) INDAVL − LFDT ** ,ti ,ti ( ,ti ,ti −1 ) (.0436607) Numberofobs 7192 7192 7192 7192 Numberofgroups 899 899 899 899 Rsqwithin 0.1262 0.1049 0.1136 0.0975 Rsqoverall 0.0193 0.0183 0.0174 0.0140 F(4,6289) 227.09 ** 184.26 ** 201.41 ** 169.80 ** Symbols: Ti,t :below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod; IAT i,t :below(=1)orabove(=0) thetargetinthepreviousperiod; IAL i,t :below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod IAL i,t : below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod; Pi,t :positivefreecashflow(=1)ornegativefree cashflow(=0). 37

Equationnumber 11 12 Dependentvariable TFDT LFDT .0029539 .0119955 Constant (.002941) * (.0029145) **

T * .891209 I (PTFDT −TFDT ) ** ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0262214)

T * .2764099 (1− I )(PTFDT −TFDT ) ** ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0250992)

L * .9315435 I (PLFDT − LFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0259777) **

L * .2496179 (1− I )(PLFDT − LFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0413712) ** Numberofobs 7192 7192 Numberofgroups 899 899 Rsqwithin 0.2088 0.1974 Rsqoverall 0.2009 0.1928 F(4,6289) 830.18 ** 773.70 ** Symbols: Ii,t :below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod. 38

Table 17 Regression results obtained by the random effects model 11

Equationnumber 3 4 5 6 Dependentvariable TFDT LFDT TFDT LFDT .0150533 .0072165 .0178684 .0050793 Constant (.0043003) ** (.0024237) ** (.004648) ** (.0028444)

T * .0889078 T (TFDT −TFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0329408) **

T * .0986104 (1−T )(TFDT −TFDT ) ** ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0233684)

L * .119039 T (LFDT − LFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.1695267) **

L * .1695267 (1−T )(LFDT − LFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0220249) **

* .0527779 IAT INDAVT −TFDT ,ti ( ,ti ,ti −1 ) (.035418)

* .1002406 (1− IAT )(INDAVT −TFDT ) ** ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.02398)

* .119242 IAL (INDAVL − LFDT ) ** ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0408089)

* .1181297 (1− IAL ) INDAVL − LFDT ** ,ti ( ,ti ,ti −1 ) (.0207637) Numberofobs 7192 7192 7192 7192 Numberofgroups 899 899 899 899 Rsqwithin 0.0969 0.0981 0.0836 0.0884 Rsqoverall 0.0071 0.0151 0.0056 0.0106 Waldchi2(2) 51.38 ** 109.93 ** 40.35 ** 76.97 ** Symbols: Ti,t :below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod; IAT i,t :below(=1)orabove(=0) thetargetinthepreviousperiod; IAL i,t :below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod IAL i,t : below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod.

11 Theestimates,forallthemodels,aresimilarwhenextendingthemodelswithcontrolvariablessuchasfirm size(S1),returnoninvestmentandadummyforgrowthopportunitiesandarethereforenotincludedinthe paper. 39

Equationnumber 7 8 9 10 Dependentvariable TFDT LFDT TFDT LFDT .015059 .0077806 .016301 .0049815 Constant (.0042111) ** (.0024165) ** (.0045536) ** (.002831)

T * .0260644 T P(TFDT −TFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0365595)

T * .2761863 (1−T )P(TFDT −TFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0251721) **

T * .2764455 T (1− P)(TFDT −TFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0412708) **

T * .3196975 (1−T )(1− P)(TFDT −TFDT ) ** ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0343246)

L * .0031923 T P(LFDT − LFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0402142)

L * .2373694 (1−T )P(LFDT − LFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0247181) **

L * .2955299 T (1− P)(LFDT − LFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0454871) **

L * .0184087 (1−T )(1− P)(LFDT − LFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0352389)

* .0418802 IAT P INDAVT −TFDT ,ti ( ,ti ,ti −1 ) (.0381502)

* .265007 (1− IAT )P INDAVT −TFDT ** ,ti ( ,ti ,ti −1 ) (.0255608)

* .2486237 IAT (1− P)(INDAVT −TFDT ) ** ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0444108)

* .311699 (1− IAT )(1− P) INDAVT −TFDT ** ,ti ( ,ti ,ti −1 ) (.0346148)

* .0292254 IAL P INDAVL − LFDT ,ti ( ,ti ,ti −1 ) (.0452508)

* .1934777 (1− IAL )P(INDAVL − LFDT ) ** ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0229614)

IAL (1− P) INDAVL* − LFDT .2790589 ,ti ( ,ti ,ti −1 ) (.0521899) **

(1−IAL )(1−P) INDAVL* −LFDT .0618441 ,ti ( ,ti ,ti −1) (.0321291) Numberofobs 7192 7192 7192 7192 Numberofgroups 899 899 899 899 Rsqwithin 0.0683 0.0685 0.0621 0.0524 Rsqoverall 0.0497 0.0240 0.0465 0.0211 Waldchi2(4) 375.63 ** 176.36 ** 350.18 ** 154.58 ** Symbols: Ti,t :below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod; IAT i,t :below(=1)orabove(=0) thetargetinthepreviousperiod; IAL i,t :below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod IAL i,t : below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod; Pi,t :positivefreecashflow(=1)ornegativefree cashflow(=0) 40

Equationnumber 11 12 Dependentvariable TFDT LFDT .0075252 .0156279 Constant (.0027394) ** (.0026911) **

T * .8941607 I (PTFDT −TFDT ) ** ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0233616)

T * .200955 (1− I )(PTFDT −TFDT ) ** ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0219995)

L * .9203343 I (PLFDT − LFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0232992) **

L * .134787 (1− L )(PLFDT − LFDT ) ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0342797) ** Numberofobs 7192 7192 Numberofgroups 899 899 Rsqwithin 0.2079 0.1965 Rsqoverall 0.2020 0.1939 Waldchi2(2) 1819.33 ** 1729.25 ** Symbols: Ii,t :below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod. Table 18 Comparison between observations with high or low previous total financial debt ratio and comparison between observations with an without growth opportunities

Equationnumber 13 (1) 14 15 (2) 16 Dependentvariable TFDT TFDT TFDT TFDT .0377466 .012599 .015685 .0036699 Constant (.0076294) ** (.0079327) (.0060794) ** (.0028848)

T * 1.603516 .4542258 .9947 .8380691 I (PTFDT −TFDT ) ** ** ** ** ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0639114) (.0427889) (.0479102) (.0255903)

T * 0.1330517 .49605 .1649689 0.2204071 (1− I )(PTFDT −TFDT ) ** ** ** ,ti ,ti ,ti −1 (.0380429) (1.998728) (.044906) (.0241621) Numberofobs 1798 1797 2236 4956 Numberofgroups 405 375 436 786 Rsqwithin 0.3105 0.0626 0.1984 0.2366 Rsqoverall 0.2974 0.0539 0.1867 0.2173 Waldchi2(4) 759.62 ** 114.30 ** 512.77 ** 1374.82 ** Symbols: Ii,t :below(=1)orabove(=0)thetargetinthepreviousperiod. (1) Equation13onlyincludestheobservationswithatotalfinancialdebtratiointhepreviousperiodthatare abovepercentile75,whileequation14includesthosewhicharebelowpercentile25. (2) Equation15includestheobservationswithgrowthopportunitieswhileequation16includesthosewithout growthopportunities.