Keeping Score: Improving the Positive Foundations for Antitrust Policy

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Keeping Score: Improving the Positive Foundations for Antitrust Policy KEEPING SCORE: IMPROVING THE POSITIVE FOUNDATIONS FOR ANTITRUST POLICY William E. Kovacic* INTRODUCTION ................................................................................... 50 I. THE AMBIGUOUS, DISPUTED SIGNIFICANCE OF DATA ON ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT ..................................................... 60 II. HOW THE QUALITY OF POSITIVE ANALYSIS AFFECTS OUR UNDERSTANDING OF THE OPERATION OF THE U.S. ANTITRUST REGIME .................................................................................... 67 A. Excessive and Misdirected Enforcement Activity: Two Narratives from the Late 1970s ........................................ 70 B. The Inadequate and Misdirected Enforcement Activity Narrative........................................................................... 86 C. How Narratives Predicated Upon Mistaken Positive Assumptions Distort Understanding About the Functioning of the U.S. Antitrust Regime............................................ 95 III. HOW THE QUALITY OF POSITIVE ANALYSIS AFFECTS ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AGENCY PERFORMANCE .............................. 101 A. Building Historical Awareness: The FTC in the 1970s.... 102 IV. HISTORICAL DATA-BASED ANALYSIS FOR ANTITRUST AGENCIES: FOCAL POINTS........................................................................ 108 A. Determining What Happened ........................................... 109 B. Using Positive Data to Make Normative Assessments..... 110 C. Improving Agency Historical Awareness......................... 112 D. Historical Analysis: Gains from Fuller Application......... 119 E. Case Reconstructions ........................................................ 121 F. Institutional Methods......................................................... 129 V. CONCLUSION ................................................................................ 130 * Global Competition Professor of Law and Policy, George Washington University Law School; Visiting Professor, Dickson Poon School of Law, King’s College London; Non- Executive Director, United Kingdom Competition & Markets Authority. The author received many useful comments and suggestions from Rory Van Loo and other participants in the summer 2020 antitrust research workshop convened by Professor Daniel Sokol of the University of Florida’s Levin School of Law. The author is most grateful for the excellent editorial guidance of the members of the University of Pennsylvania Journal of Business Law. The views expressed here are the author’s alone. Contact: [email protected]. 49 50 U. OF PENNSYLVANIA JOURNAL OF BUSINESS LAW [Vol. 23:1 INTRODUCTION At the start of class in a new academic term, students often ask their instructors, “What is the basis for the grade in this course?” In 2001, after fifteen years of fielding that question in university classrooms, I became a senior official at the Federal Trade Commission (“FTC”). On many occasions, a variant of my students’ perennial query came to mind: What is the basis for the grade in this course? How should my agency’s performance be evaluated?1 The question that occupied my thoughts at the FTC attracts vigorous debate today as a growing body of commentators and elected officials calls for dramatic changes in the U.S. competition policy regime. 2 Reform advocates have proposed a fundamental reorientation of federal antitrust enforcement, a major redesign of the competition statutes, and the creation of new tools to regulate dominant firms, especially large information services platforms.3 Not since the early-to mid-1970s has the mood reflected in public debate and legislative deliberations so welcomed a thorough overhaul of the U.S. competition law system.4 1. See William E. Kovacic, Rating the Competition Agencies: What Constitutes Good Performance?, 16 GEO. MASON L. REV. 903 (2009) [hereinafter Rating the Competition Agencies] (offering reflections on criteria for assessing performance of public antitrust authorities). 2. See Daniel A. Crane, The New Crisis in Antitrust (?), 83 ANTITRUST L.J. 253 (2020) (discussing modern debate about U.S. antitrust policy); A. Douglas Melamed, Antitrust Law and Its Critics, 83 ANTITRUST L.J. 269 (2020) (same). 3. These proposals are summarized in Alison Jones & William E. Kovacic, Antitrust’s Implementation Blind Side: Challenges to Major Expansion of U.S. Competition Policy, 65 ANTITRUST BULL. 227 (Issue 2, 2020) [hereinafter Implementation Blind Side]. 4. In the early-to mid-1970s, Congress pressed the federal antitrust agencies to initiate cases to deconcentrate large segments of the U.S. economy. See William E. Kovacic, Failed Expectations: The Troubled Past and Uncertain Future of the Sherman Act as a Tool for Deconcentration, 74 IOWA L. REV. 1105, 1126–27 (1989) [hereinafter Failed Expectations] (describing congressional encouragement in 1970s for federal antitrust agencies to undertake cases to restructure concentrated industries). The exhortations of legislators drew upon scholarly work and the findings of expert panels that recommended expansive efforts to break up dominant firms and tight oligopolies. Id. at 1136–37. The federal agencies responded to this guidance by bringing an ambitious collection of cases challenging single-firm misconduct and collective dominance. Id. at 1119–20. In this same period, Congress enacted major reforms to the U.S. antitrust laws. In 1974, it raised the status of the criminal antitrust offense from a misdemeanor to a felony and boosted fines and prison terms for infringements. Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act, P.L. 93-528, 88 Stat. 1706 (1974). In 1976, Congress renovated the merger control mechanism by requiring 2020] KEEPING SCORE 51 The contemporary reform proposals seem to be having a genuine effect. The calls for expanded enforcement already seem to have moved the federal antitrust authorities, the FTC and the Department of Justice (“DOJ”), to adopt a more aggressive posture.5 On October 20, 2020, the DOJ and eleven state attorneys general filed a complaint charging Google with illegal monopolization in various markets related to search. 6 There are also indications that Congress will give serious attention to bills to amend the antitrust laws and alter the competition policy institutional framework.7 A predicate for the reform demands is the view that the DOJ and the FTC have failed miserably in performing their law enforcement duties in the advance notification to the antitrust agencies of certain proposed mergers and imposing a suspensory period in which the agencies could gather information to review such deals. Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act of 1976, 15 U.S.C. § 18a. 5. Since 2019, the DOJ and the FTC have been investigating possible antitrust violations involving the country’s leading information technology firms. See Jones & Kovacic, Implementation Blind Side, supra note 3, at 237–38. 6. U.S. v. Google LLC, Case 1:20-cv-03010 (Oct. 20, 2020) [hereinafter DOJ Google Complaint], available at https://www.justice.gov/atr/case-document/file/1329131/download [https://perma.cc/7SM5-EDYG]. A number of other state attorneys general appear to be preparing to file a monopolization complaint against Google that alleges a broader range of anticompetitive conduct. Diane Bartz, Google’s antitrust legal woes far from over if Biden wins, Reuters (Oct. 22, 2020), https://www.reuters.com/article/usa-election-google-biden- idUSL1N2HA1ZP [https://perma.cc/GLX5-PPU7] (reporting comments by Colorado Attorney General Phil Weiser, who indicated that various state attorneys general will conclude their investigation of Google “in the coming weeks”). The FTC is reported to have met recently to discuss the status of its inquiry into Facebook and the possibility of bringing a case against the social media giant. Tony Room, FTC said to huddle privately to discuss Facebook antitrust probe, signaling advanced stage, WASH. POST (Oct. 22, 2020), https://www.washingtonpost.com/technology/2020/10/22/facebook-ftc-antitrust/ [https://per ma.cc/BXD6-FGR7]. 7. On July 29, 2020, the House Judiciary Subcommittee on Antitrust, Commercial, and Administrative Law held hearings to take testimony from the chief executive officers of Amazon, Apple, Facebook, and Google. During the proceedings, the panel’s Chair (Rep. David Cicilline) and several of his colleagues called for new legislation to strengthen the existing antitrust laws to control dominant technology platforms. Online Platforms and Market Power, Part 6: Examining the Dominance of Amazon, Apple, Facebook, and Google Before the Subcomm. on Antitrust, Com., and Admin. L. of Just. Of the H. comm. On the Judiciary, 116th Cong (2020)(statement of Rep. David Cicilline). On October 6, 2020, the House Judiciary Subcommittee on Antitrust, Commercial and Administrative Law released a majority staff report calling for sweeping changes to the U.S. antitrust system, including the creation of new regulatory mechanisms to oversee leading digital platforms. Investigation of Competition in Digital Markets: Majority Staff Report and Recommendations, Subcommittee on Antitrust, Commercial and Administrative Law, House Committee on the Judiciary 376-405 (2020) [hereinafter Majority Staff Report], available at https://judiciary.house.gov/uploadedfiles/competition_in_digital_markets.pdf [https://perma.cc/Z7JL-KKZV] (presenting antitrust and regulatory reform recommendations). 52 U. OF PENNSYLVANIA JOURNAL OF BUSINESS LAW [Vol. 23:1 modern era, a period that, in critical commentary, begins in 2000 and sometimes extends back to roughly 1980.8 The
Recommended publications
  • Twelve Fallacies of the “Neo-Antitrust” Movement
    TWELVE FALLACIES OF THE “NEO-ANTITRUST” MOVEMENT Seth B. Sacher John M. Yun Antonin Scalia Law School, George Mason University George Mason University Law & Economics Research Paper Series 19-12 This paper is available on the Social Science Research Network at ssrn.com/abstract=3369013 TWELVE FALLACIES OF THE “NEO-ANTITRUST” MOVEMENT Seth B. Sachera and John M. Yunb Antonin Scalia Law School George Mason University May 1, 2019 Abstract Antitrust enforcement is back in the spotlight with advocates from both the political left and the populist political right demanding fundamental competition policy changes. While there are differences among those calling for such changes, several common beliefs generally unite them. This includes a contention that the writings and interpretations of Robert Bork and the Chicago School of economics have led antitrust astray in a manner fundamentally inconsistent with the original intent of the Sherman Act. Further, they are united by a belief that recent empirical, economic studies indicate the economy is becoming overly concentrated, that market power has been increasing dramatically, that performance in many, if not most, markets has been deficient, and that too much profit is going to too few firms. In this article, we identify and detail twelve fallacies of what we call the “neo-antitrust movement” and their associated claims. At the heart of these fallacies is a fundamental misunderstanding of economics and the consumer welfare standard that has been at the heart of competition policy since at least the 1960s. Additionally, there is a heavy reliance on studies that, upon closer scrutiny, do not support the positions of those who cite them.
    [Show full text]
  • V16 FTC Reform
    Consumer Protection & Competition Regulation in a High-Tech World: Discussing the Future of the Federal Trade Commission December 2013 Report 1.0 of the FTC: Technology & Reform Project Consumer Protection & Competition Regulation in a High-Tech World: Discussing the Future of the Federal Trade Commission December 2013 Report 1.0 of the FTC: Technology & Reform Project This document represents the combined input of several authors and commentators, and has been compiled to ask questions and prompt discussion about the Federal Trade Commission. It is, by design, over-inclusive, so that it may foster broad discussion. At the same time, it is also certainly not complete. This document does not necessarily represent the views of its principal authors or other contributors to the drafting process, nor the members of the FTC: Technology & Reform Project. The FTC: Technology & Reform Project was convened by the International Center for Law & Economics and TechFreedom. It is not affiliated in any way with the FTC. I. Introduction ........................................................................................................................................... 2 A. What this Report is About ................................................................................................................. 4 B. The (Not-So-Unique) Role of Technology .......................................................................................... 4 C. Some Historical Context: Constraining & Reasserting FTC Power ...................................................
    [Show full text]
  • The Rule of Law & FTC: Thesis & Antithesis? Some Proposals
    Volume 86 Issue 3 Dickinson Law Review - Volume 86, 1981-1982 3-1-1982 The Rule of Law & FTC: Thesis & Antithesis? Some Proposals John A. Maher Follow this and additional works at: https://ideas.dickinsonlaw.psu.edu/dlra Recommended Citation John A. Maher, The Rule of Law & FTC: Thesis & Antithesis? Some Proposals, 86 DICK. L. REV. 403 (1982). Available at: https://ideas.dickinsonlaw.psu.edu/dlra/vol86/iss3/2 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Reviews at Dickinson Law IDEAS. It has been accepted for inclusion in Dickinson Law Review by an authorized editor of Dickinson Law IDEAS. For more information, please contact [email protected]. The Rule of Law & FTC: Thesis & Antithesis? Some Proposals John A. Maher* I. Introduction A. Recent Events December 17, 1980 is a remarkable date for those interested in either quality of government or, more particularly, evolution of the Federal Trade Commission's sense of the unfair.' On that day, the five Commissioners then in office2 purported to renounce Commis- sion reliance on what they apparently regarded as a non-exclusive substantive rule of decision concerning the content of their enabling 3 act's use of "unfair . .acts or practices." That renounced can be said to possess the cachet of Supreme Court approval by reason of a unanimous opinion in FTC.v. Sperry & Hutchinson Co.4 (S&H). * A.B. 1951, University of Notre Dame; LL.B. 1956, LL.M. (Trade Regulation) 1957, New York University; Professor, Dickinson School of Law. Professor Maher currently serves the Banking & Business Law Section of the Pennsylvania Bar Association as chairperson of its antitrust committee and as a member of its committee for reform and recodification of Penn- sylvania's corporation and partnership laws.
    [Show full text]
  • George Mason Law Review 19Th Annual Antitrust Symposium: Antitrust in an Interconnected World
    HENRY G. MANNE PROGRAM IN LAW & ECONOMICS STUDIES GEORGE MASON LAW REVIEW 19TH ANNUAL ANTITRUST SYMPOSIUM: ANTITRUST IN AN INTERCONNECTED WORLD FEBRUARY 18, 2016 WELCOME HENRY G. MANNE PROGRAM IN LAW & ECONOMICS STUDIES GEORGE MASON LAW REVIEW 19TH ANNUAL ANTITRUST SYMPOSIUM FEBRUARY 18, 2016, ARLINGTON, VA ABOUT US OUR PROGRAMS CONTENTS Since its inception in 1974, the THE MASON JUDICIAL EDUCATION PROGRAM is the nation’s Law & Economics Center has preeminent provider of high-quality, balanced judicial educational Agenda 2 played a critical role as a leader in seminars and conferences that focus on economics, finance, accounting, law and economics research and statistics, and scientific method. The LEC has been offering programs for Speaker Bios 6 education. The LEC recognizes judges since 1976. both the importance of timely, relevant, and unassailable research THE HENRY G. MANNE PROGRAM IN LAW & ECONOMICS STUDIES LEC Contact Info 19 on public policy issues as well as promotes law and economics scholarship by funding faculty research and the necessity of communicating hosting policy-relevant research roundtables and academic conferences. Upcoming Schedule 21 research findings to those who are directly shaping our country’s THE SEARLE CIVIL JUSTICE INSTITUTE is a public policy institute public policy discussions. With devoted to producing timely, analytically rigorous, and balanced research research divisions devoted to on important civil justice issues confronting our free enterprise system. large-scale empirical projects and top-quality legal policy analysis, THE MASON ATTORNEYS GENERAL EDUCATION PROGRAM offers and educational arms reaching courses that provide a broad-based understanding of economic and public out to judges, attorneys general, policy issues to state attorneys general and their staff attorneys.
    [Show full text]
  • Amazon's Antitrust Paradox
    LINA M. KHAN Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox abstract. Amazon is the titan of twenty-first century commerce. In addition to being a re- tailer, it is now a marketing platform, a delivery and logistics network, a payment service, a credit lender, an auction house, a major book publisher, a producer of television and films, a fashion designer, a hardware manufacturer, and a leading host of cloud server space. Although Amazon has clocked staggering growth, it generates meager profits, choosing to price below-cost and ex- pand widely instead. Through this strategy, the company has positioned itself at the center of e- commerce and now serves as essential infrastructure for a host of other businesses that depend upon it. Elements of the firm’s structure and conduct pose anticompetitive concerns—yet it has escaped antitrust scrutiny. This Note argues that the current framework in antitrust—specifically its pegging competi- tion to “consumer welfare,” defined as short-term price effects—is unequipped to capture the ar- chitecture of market power in the modern economy. We cannot cognize the potential harms to competition posed by Amazon’s dominance if we measure competition primarily through price and output. Specifically, current doctrine underappreciates the risk of predatory pricing and how integration across distinct business lines may prove anticompetitive. These concerns are height- ened in the context of online platforms for two reasons. First, the economics of platform markets create incentives for a company to pursue growth over profits, a strategy that investors have re- warded. Under these conditions, predatory pricing becomes highly rational—even as existing doctrine treats it as irrational and therefore implausible.
    [Show full text]
  • Caspar Weinberger and the Reagan Defense Buildup
    The University of Southern Mississippi The Aquila Digital Community Dissertations Fall 12-2013 Direct Responsibility: Caspar Weinberger and the Reagan Defense Buildup Robert Howard Wieland University of Southern Mississippi Follow this and additional works at: https://aquila.usm.edu/dissertations Part of the American Studies Commons, Military History Commons, Political History Commons, and the United States History Commons Recommended Citation Wieland, Robert Howard, "Direct Responsibility: Caspar Weinberger and the Reagan Defense Buildup" (2013). Dissertations. 218. https://aquila.usm.edu/dissertations/218 This Dissertation is brought to you for free and open access by The Aquila Digital Community. It has been accepted for inclusion in Dissertations by an authorized administrator of The Aquila Digital Community. For more information, please contact [email protected]. The University of Southern Mississippi DIRECT RESPONSIBILITY: CASPAR WEINBERGER AND THE REAGAN DEFENSE BUILDUP by Robert Howard Wieland Abstract of a Dissertation Submitted to the Graduate School Of The University of Southern Mississippi In Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements For the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy December 2013 ABSTRACT DIRECT RESPONSIBILITY: CASPAR WEINBERGER AND THE REAGAN DEFENSE BUILDUP by Robert Howard Wieland December 2013 This dissertation explores the life of Caspar Weinberger and explains why President Reagan chose him for Secretary of Defense. Weinberger, not a defense technocrat, managed a massive defense buildup of 1.5 trillion dollars over a four year period. A biographical approach to Weinberger illuminates Reagan’s selection, for in many ways Weinberger harkens back to an earlier type of defense manager more akin to Elihu Root than Robert McNamara; more a man of letters than technocrat.
    [Show full text]
  • Competition Agencies, Independence, and the Political Process
    Unclassified DAF/COMP/WD(2014)86 Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Économiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 27-Nov-2014 ___________________________________________________________________________________________ _____________ English - Or. English DIRECTORATE FOR FINANCIAL AND ENTERPRISE AFFAIRS COMPETITION COMMITTEE Unclassified DAF/COMP/WD(2014)86 COMPETITION AGENCIES, INDEPENDENCE, AND THE POLITICAL PROCESS -- Chapter by William Kovacic (George Washington University, United States) -- 17-18 December 2014 This chapter by William Kovacic (George Washington University, United States) was submitted as background material for the Roundtable on Changes in Institutional Design of Competition Authorities which will take place at the 122nd meeting of the OECD Competition Committee on 17-18 December 2014. It is an extract from Competition Policy and the Economic Approach, edited by Josef Drexl, Wolfgang Kerber and Rupprecht Podszun. Published by Edward Elgar, 2011. The opinions expressed and arguments employed herein do not necessarily reflect the official views of the Organisation or of the governments of its member countries. More documents related to this discussion can be found at http://www.oecd.org/daf/competition/changes-in- competition-institutional-design.htm. This document is available as a PDF only English JT03367265 Complete document available on OLIS in its original format - This document and any map included herein are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of Or international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area. English DAF/COMP/WD(2014)86 2 Graham HD:Users:Graham:Public:GRAHAM'S IMAC JOBS:12764 - EE - DREXL:M2555 - DREXL PRINT 16. Competition agencies, independence, and the political process William E.
    [Show full text]
  • Ftc Stakeholder Perspectives: Reform Proposals to Improve Fairness, Innovation, and Consumer Welfare
    S. HRG. 115–541 FTC STAKEHOLDER PERSPECTIVES: REFORM PROPOSALS TO IMPROVE FAIRNESS, INNOVATION, AND CONSUMER WELFARE HEARING BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON CONSUMER PROTECTION, PRODUCT SAFETY, INSURANCE, AND DATA SECURITY OF THE COMMITTEE ON COMMERCE, SCIENCE, AND TRANSPORTATION UNITED STATES SENATE ONE HUNDRED FIFTEENTH CONGRESS FIRST SESSION SEPTEMBER 26, 2017 Printed for the use of the Committee on Commerce, Science, and Transportation ( Available online: http://www.govinfo.gov U.S. GOVERNMENT PUBLISHING OFFICE 35–459 PDF WASHINGTON : 2019 VerDate Nov 24 2008 07:37 Mar 18, 2019 Jkt 000000 PO 00000 Frm 00001 Fmt 5011 Sfmt 5011 S:\GPO\DOCS\35459.TXT JACKIE SENATE COMMITTEE ON COMMERCE, SCIENCE, AND TRANSPORTATION ONE HUNDRED FIFTEENTH CONGRESS FIRST SESSION JOHN THUNE, South Dakota, Chairman ROGER F. WICKER, Mississippi BILL NELSON, Florida, Ranking ROY BLUNT, Missouri MARIA CANTWELL, Washington TED CRUZ, Texas AMY KLOBUCHAR, Minnesota DEB FISCHER, Nebraska RICHARD BLUMENTHAL, Connecticut JERRY MORAN, Kansas BRIAN SCHATZ, Hawaii DAN SULLIVAN, Alaska EDWARD MARKEY, Massachusetts DEAN HELLER, Nevada CORY BOOKER, New Jersey JAMES INHOFE, Oklahoma TOM UDALL, New Mexico MIKE LEE, Utah GARY PETERS, Michigan RON JOHNSON, Wisconsin TAMMY BALDWIN, Wisconsin SHELLEY MOORE CAPITO, West Virginia TAMMY DUCKWORTH, Illinois CORY GARDNER, Colorado MAGGIE HASSAN, New Hampshire TODD YOUNG, Indiana CATHERINE CORTEZ MASTO, Nevada NICK ROSSI, Staff Director ADRIAN ARNAKIS, Deputy Staff Director JASON VAN BEEK, General Counsel KIM LIPSKY, Democratic Staff Director
    [Show full text]
  • FTC Nominee Expected to Oppose Broad Privacy Rules
    Portfolio Media. Inc. | 860 Broadway, 6th Floor | New York, NY 10003 | www.law360.com Phone: +1 646 783 7100 | Fax: +1 646 783 7161 | [email protected] FTC Nominee Expected To Oppose Broad Privacy Rules By Bibeka Shrestha Law360, New York (September 2, 2011) -- If confirmed, Federal Trade Commission nominee Maureen Ohlhausen would likely call for greater transparency about privacy practices but fight comprehensive restrictions on the collection and use of consumer information, according to privacy experts. Should the Senate greenlight President Barack Obama's pick, Ohlhausen would leave her partner position at Wilkinson Barker Knauer LLP's privacy, data protection and cybersecurity practice to join the FTC's five-member board as its second Republican commissioner for a seven-year term starting Sept. 26. Ohlhausen would replace Republican Commissioner William Kovacic, who has served on the commission since January 2006. Experts say it would be surprising for the technology policy heavyweight to meekly sign on to FTC Chairman Jon Leibowitz's privacy agenda, which seeks to set a minimum standard of conduct for companies across the board that collect personal information, rather than focusing on specific sectors like the financial industry. "As a general matter, I do not think that she would not support 'substantive' regulation — restrictions on what companies can collect and disclose or how they can use the information that they collect," said Andrew Smith, a Morrison & Foerster LLP partner who worked closely with Ohlhausen while at the FTC's Bureau of Consumer Protection. Leibowitz has sought to move past the notice-and-choice mechanism espoused under the George W.
    [Show full text]
  • Amazon's Surveillance Infrastructure and Revitalizing a Fair Marketplace
    JULY 2021 Eyes Everywhere: Amazon's Surveillance Infrastructure and Revitalizing a Fair Marketplace Daniel A. Hanley 1 1 Contents Executive Summary ................................................................................ 2 I. Introduction ........................................................................................ 3 II. Competitor Surveillance ......................................................................... 4 A. Amazon Marketplace ...................................................................... 4 B. Amazon Web Services ...................................................................... 5 C. Fulfillment by Amazon ..................................................................... 6 III. Consumer Surveillance ...................................................................... 7 A. Amazon Marketplace ...................................................................... 7 B. Amazon Alexa .................................................................................. 8 C. Amazon Ring .................................................................................... 9 D. Amazon's Other Consumer Surveillance Ambitions ..................... 10 IV. Harms .............................................................................................. 11 A. Copying Competitor Products ...................................................... 11 B. Self-Preferencing ............................................................................ 13 C. Arbitrary and Exclusionary Rules ..................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Section 5: Principles of Navigation, Maureen K. Ohlhausen
    United States of America Federal Trade Commission Section 5: Principles of Navigation Remarks of Maureen K. Ohlhausen1 Commissioner, Federal Trade Commission U.S. Chamber of Commerce Washington, D.C. July 25, 2013 I. Introduction Good morning. I am delighted to be here at the U.S. Chamber of Commerce. Let me thank Sean Heather of the Chamber for inviting me to speak today. In my remarks, I would like to discuss unfair methods of competition (UMC) under Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) Act.2 By that, of course, I mean standalone Section 5 enforcement – separate from our enforcement of the antitrust laws. My primary goal in making these remarks is to continue the dialogue on Section 5, both inside and outside the Commission.3 As a Commissioner, I have called for our agency to issue some type of policy statement or other guidance on how and when it will pursue standalone Section 5 cases. Today I offer some thoughts on what might inform such a statement, as well as some guiding and limiting principles for consideration by my colleagues at the Commission and by interested parties outside the agency. Finally, calling on these principles, I will suggest how the agency should prioritize its competition efforts. II. A Sea of Uncertainty For many decades, the Commission’s exercise of its UMC authority has launched the agency into a sea of uncertainty, much like the agency weathered when using its unfairness authority in the consumer protection area in the 1970s. In issuing our 1980 statement on the 1 The views expressed in this speech are my own and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Trade Commission or any other Commissioner.
    [Show full text]
  • What Does Lina Khan's Appointment As FTC Chair Mean for Your Business?
    Litigation & Arbitration Group Client Alert What Does Lina Khan’s Appointment as FTC Chair Mean for Your Business? June 25, 2021 Contact Fiona Schaeffer Andrew Wellin Eric Hyla Lena K. Bruce Partner Special Counsel Associate Associate +1 212.530.5243 +1 212.530.5432 +1 212.530.5243 +1 212.530.5028 [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] On June 15, 2021, within hours of her Senate confirmation as a Federal Trade Commission (FTC) Commissioner, 32-year-old Lina Khan was appointed by President Biden to serve as the youngest FTC Chair in history. Khan has established herself as a progressive antitrust activist and a leader of the “New Brandeis Movement”1 that advocates for a revival of more aggressive U.S. antitrust policies and enforcement from the earlier part of the 20th century. Khan’s most widely-recognized and influential work, “Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox,” published in the Yale Law Journal in 2017 (while she was a Yale law student), argues that the current US antitrust paradigm (heavily influenced by the Chicago School) is too narrowly focused on consumer welfare and “is unequipped to capture the architecture of market power in the modern economy.”2 Because the consumer welfare standard focuses on short-term price and output effects, it is ill-equipped to address the purported harms to competition that big tech platforms raise. In her article, Khan maintains that platform markets, such as Amazon, have evaded antitrust liability because they focus on long-term growth over short-term profits – in short, they can make predatory, below-cost pricing a rational and profitable strategy, and can control the infrastructure on which their rivals depend without raising prices or reducing output in the short-term.
    [Show full text]