Economics and Interdisciplinarity: One Step Forward, N Steps Back?*

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Economics and Interdisciplinarity: One Step Forward, N Steps Back?* Revista Crítica de Ciências Sociais 119 | 2019 Número semitemático Economics and Interdisciplinarity: One Step Forward, N Steps Back? Economia e interdisciplinaridade: um passo em frente, n passos para trás? Économie et Interdisciplinarité: un pas en avant, n pas en arrière? Ben Fine Electronic version URL: http://journals.openedition.org/rccs/9230 DOI: 10.4000/rccs.9230 ISSN: 2182-7435 Publisher Centro de Estudos Sociais da Universidade de Coimbra Printed version Date of publication: 1 September 2019 Number of pages: 131-148 ISSN: 0254-1106 Electronic reference Ben Fine, « Economics and Interdisciplinarity: One Step Forward, N Steps Back? », Revista Crítica de Ciências Sociais [Online], 119 | 2019, Online since 06 August 2019, connection on 08 August 2019. URL : http://journals.openedition.org/rccs/9230 ; DOI : 10.4000/rccs.9230 Revista Crítica de Ciências Sociais, 119, setembro 2019: 131-148 BEN FINE Economics and Interdisciplinarity: One Step Forward, N Steps Back?* Mainstream economics has become more interdisciplinary. Why is this? Does it repre‑ sent a break with its intra ‑disciplinary character? How does it relate to major points of criticism – the lack of realism and disregard for methodology and alternative schools and history of economic thought? What light does this shed on the nature of economics today? Answers are found by tracing “economics imperialism” through three phases, emphasising the “historical logic” of economics imperialism, how its initial confinement to market supply and demand created a logical framing of universal application. As a result, microeconomics (and econometrics) triumphed over other fields and methods to such an extent and with such an acceptability that its corresponding principles are now applied, however inconsistently, with those of other disciplines and fields through a process termed “suspension”. Keywords: economic alternatives; epistemological decolonization, interdisciplinarity; mainstream economics; political economy. Economics Is as Economics Does The purpose of this piece is to assess the prospects for political economy, especially in the context of interdisciplinarity. A necessary starting point for making such an assessment is the current state of mainstream eco- nomics. I approach this obliquely in the first instance, and anecdotally. I was recently invited to give a lecture at the Institute of German Historical Research in London as part of a series to mark the 200th anniversary of Karl Marx’s birth, May 5th, 1818, and I sought to address the theme of Marx’s continuing influence on contemporary social science. Other talks in the series included politics, sociology, anthropology and history. I explained that the one on economics would necessarily be extremely * Based on a plenary address to the founding conference of the Portuguese Association of Political Economy, held at Lisbon, ISCTE -IUL, 25 -27 January 2018. Thanks to journal editors and referees for most helpful comments and suggestions. 132 | Ben Fine short as Marx had predominantly been excluded from mainstream eco- nomics today, since the mainstream totally dominates the discipline with little room for, let alone tolerance of, alternatives. This is so whether deriving from Marx, other classical authors, or political economy or otherwise more widely. As a result, I offered to give a lecture explaining why this was so, whether this was or was not a sign of health of the dis- mal science, and what sets economics apart as a social science in being so negligent of Marx (and others), themes to which I will return below. First, though, let me recall an earlier lecture I gave a few years ago for the Association of Social Economies, in which I suggested that the main- stream is unfit for purpose, focusing on just one of the many dimensions for which this is so, that is, its own heavy ethical content which it seeks to deny as being present in view of its putative scientific/positive content as opposed to normative content (Fine, 2013). In preparing the lecture, I undertook a simple test of the self-confidence of the discipline, compar- ing it with sociology. In the wake of the 2007/2008 Global Financial Crisis (GFC), I searched the scholarly literature employing the terms “crisis of sociology” and “crisis of economics”. Sociology had a steady stream (if not a torrent) of contributions, numbering in the thousands, persisting over time and suggesting a commendable degree of self-critical examina- tion. Economics, by contrast, barely totalled 100, most of these dating to a debate from the 1930s on Schumpeter. Especially in the wake of the GFC, one has to wonder whether this lack of critical self-examination is a mark of the mainstream’s success or of its failure.1 This is indicative of one of a number of other features of the mainstream: 1) its absolute self-confidence; 2) its lack or misuse (if not abuse) of the history of economic thought; 3) its lack of engagement with alternatives; 4) its poverty of methodology; 5) its lack of realism; and 6) denial of, and so lack of attention to, normative content and issues.2 As a result, the absence of Marx from the mainstream is not a targeted exception, as much as the same is true of all major figures in the history of economic thought, and, other than opportunistically, most major figures in social science as well. Does this mean that there is no interdisciplinarity with respect to and within mainstream economics? I would suggest not at all, hardly surprising as I have been critically peddling the notion of economics imperialism, the colonisation of the subject matter of other social sciences by economics for twenty years or more now. Let me explore this in detail in order both to specify the nature 1 For an account of the “superiority” (if not the arrogance) of economists, see Fourcade et al. (2015). 2 Discussed at length in Fine (2013). Economics and Interdisciplinarity | 133 of contemporary mainstream economics, its approach to interdisciplinarity, and the potential for alternatives.3 Economics Imperialism The term economic(s) imperialism dates from the 1930s, but it only really gathers momentum after the Second World War (WWII). From there, it has gone through three phases, ones which I have called the “old”, the “new” and the “newer”. The first phase reflects the Post WWII period, the second corresponds in part to a reaction to the monetarist counter -revolution built upon the first phase (although this second phase had a dynamic and logic of its own), with the current phase just about preceding but intensified by the GFC. Analytically speaking, the logical origins of economics imperialism lie in what I have termed as its historical logic, which will require a bit of a nar- rative in the history of economic thought to specify. With the Marginalist Revolution of the 1870s, especially through Marshall rather than Jevons, Menger and Walras,4 we receive the key concepts of what I call the Technical Apparatus, TA1, which has remained persistent within mainstream econom- ics to the present day. It is the apparatus attached to utility and production functions and their application to supply and demand through the market. In what was to be termed microeconomics from the 1930s, and as the junior partner to macroeconomics that distinguished itself and became the senior branch given the pressing problems of unemployment, TA1 set itself two major problems. The first refers to the properties of supply and demand functions, given that they derive from optimising individuals, and the second addresses what I call the Technical Architecture, denoted by TA2, which gave rise to the problem of forming the aggregate economy out of those individuals coordinated through the market, otherwise known as general equilibrium, and whether it exists and is unique, stable and Pareto efficient. Forging these two problems, and TA1 and TA2 together and we get what might be designated as TA2. The first of these problems was solved in the late 1930s and the second in the 1950s, via what are known, respectively, as the Hicks-Slutsky -Samuelson 3 The main thrust of what follows is to be found in Milonakis and Fine (2009) and Fine and Milonakis (2009) but for some more recent material and reflections around other themes, see my other later contributions (Fine, 2010, 2011, 2016a, 2016b, 2016c, 2017a, 2017b and 2018; Fine and Dimakou, 2016; Fine and Milonakis, 2011), where extensive references to, and discus- sion of, the broader literature can be found. 4 Marshall’s Principles was the main microeconomic textbook until the end of the 1930s, laying out and applying the technical apparatus. General equilibrium, despite preoccupying Walras, only drew concerted attention from the mid -1930s (Marshall, 1959 [1890]). 134 | Ben Fine conditions and by Arrow and Debreu for General Equilibrium. I am less concerned with the solutions than with the process and context by and within which they occurred. I call the process an implosion – for it involved making whatever assumptions are necessary to be able to derive meaningful results, assumptions such as fixed individuals, preferences, endowments, technolo- gies, single motivation, fixed goods, etc., even technical assumptions within its own frame such as no externalities, increasing returns, concavities and imper- fect competition. These are the origins of the mainstream’s deviation from whatever we mean by realism since, whatever the extent of use of empirical information in econometrics or otherwise, it is theoretically embedded in assumptions that suit the theory rather than the evidence.5 Theoretically, we do whatever is necessary to get what we want. Indeed, this actually sets a standard method within the discipline: make whatever assumptions (and exclusions) we need for our purposes and reality will have to fit, giving rise to all sorts of problems, even on its own terms, as a result of what are known as aggregation problems, the theory of the second best, the Cambridge critique of capital theory, and so on.
Recommended publications
  • Reception Hosted by the Cliometric Society: Saturday, January 5Th, 5:30-7:30 Pm Coronodo Room and Terrace Westin Gaslamp Quarter
    The Newsletter of The Cliometric Society Winter 2013 Vol 27 No. 2 Economic History Association Annual Meeting 2012 By Shawn Michael Adrian, Steve Bannister, Fan Fei, Mary Eschelbach Hansen, Roy Mill, and Marlous van Waijenburg The 72nd annual meeting of the Economic History transport costs in international trade. Association convened from September 21-23, 2012, at the Sheraton Wall Centre Hotel in Vancouver. EHA Adrian Leonard (Cambridge) presented the final President Jeremy Atack, the program committee paper of the session—with perfect English diction. (Robert Margo, Ran Abramitzky, Leah Boustan, His early exploration of “The Pricing Revolution and Eugene White) and the local arrangements in Marine Insurance” uses new data to explain how committee (Angela Redish, David Jacks, Mauricio London companies became the leading insurers of Drelichman, Morten Jerven, and Catherine maritime trade in the 17th century. Discussant Eric Douglas) provided an outstanding weekend of lovely Hilt (Wellesley) encouraged Leonard to focus on accommodations and stimulating sessions. This article asymmetries of information (moral hazard and adverse summarizes the sessions at which original papers were selection) in the complex insurance market. presented. The theme of Session 2 was “Cities in Economic Session 1 covered the historical evolution of trade History.” Jim Sidola (UC-Irvine) presented “Razing and transport costs. Brandon Dupont (Western San Francisco: The 1906 Disaster and the Legacy Washington Univ.), Drew Keeling (Univ. of Zurich), of Urban Land Use” to an almost full room. The and Thomas Weiss (Univ. of Kansas) kicked off disastrous “experiment” allows Sidola to study the conference with a paper on tourism history. This whether land developers are hampered by prior early look at “Passenger Fares for Ocean Travel from development by comparing residential density in non- 1826 to 1916” focused on the relationship between affected areas to density in destroyed areas.
    [Show full text]
  • Uncertainty and Hyperinflation: European Inflation Dynamics After World War I
    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES Uncertainty and Hyperinflation: European Inflation Dynamics after World War I Jose A. Lopez Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Kris James Mitchener Santa Clara University CAGE, CEPR, CES-ifo & NBER June 2018 Working Paper 2018-06 https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/working-papers/2018/06/ Suggested citation: Lopez, Jose A., Kris James Mitchener. 2018. “Uncertainty and Hyperinflation: European Inflation Dynamics after World War I,” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2018-06. https://doi.org/10.24148/wp2018-06 The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Uncertainty and Hyperinflation: European Inflation Dynamics after World War I Jose A. Lopez Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Kris James Mitchener Santa Clara University CAGE, CEPR, CES-ifo & NBER* May 9, 2018 ABSTRACT. Fiscal deficits, elevated debt-to-GDP ratios, and high inflation rates suggest hyperinflation could have potentially emerged in many European countries after World War I. We demonstrate that economic policy uncertainty was instrumental in pushing a subset of European countries into hyperinflation shortly after the end of the war. Germany, Austria, Poland, and Hungary (GAPH) suffered from frequent uncertainty shocks – and correspondingly high levels of uncertainty – caused by protracted political negotiations over reparations payments, the apportionment of the Austro-Hungarian debt, and border disputes. In contrast, other European countries exhibited lower levels of measured uncertainty between 1919 and 1925, allowing them more capacity with which to implement credible commitments to their fiscal and monetary policies.
    [Show full text]
  • Review of Economics Imperialism Versus Multidisciplinarity John B
    Marquette University e-Publications@Marquette Economics Faculty Research and Publications Economics, Department of 1-1-2016 Review of Economics Imperialism versus Multidisciplinarity John B. Davis Marquette University, [email protected] Accepted version. History of Economic Ideas, Vol. 24, No. 3 (2016): 77-94. DOI. © 2016 Fabrizio Serra Editore. Used with permission. Forthcoming in History of Economic Ideas Economics imperialism versus multidisciplinarity John B. Davis, Marquette University and University of Amsterdam 2015 STOREP Conference Plenary Lecture Shifting Boundaries: Economics in the Crisis and the Challenge of Interdisciplinarity June 11-13, 2015 Abstract: This paper examines the implications of Chicago School economist Edward Lazear’s 2000 defense of economics imperialism using standard trade theory. It associates that defense with interdisciplinarity or the idea that the sciences are relatively autonomous, but treats this defense as a mask for a more conventional imperialist strategy of promoting Chicago School neoclassicism. Lazear’s argument actually created a dilemma for Chicago regarding how it could espouse interdisciplinarity while operating in a contrary way. I argue that the solution to this dilemma was for neoclassicism to rebuild economics imperialism around neoclassicism as a theory that sees the world in its own image in a performative manner. This strategy, however, suffers from a number of problems, which upon examination ultimately lead us to multidisciplinarity or the idea that the sciences can have transformative effects on one another. This latter conception can be associated with a complexity economics approach as an alternative view of the relation between the sciences. The paper argues that this view provides a basis for pluralism in economics.
    [Show full text]
  • DISTRIBUTION, WEALTH and DEMAND REGIMES in HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE USA, UK, France and Germany, 1855-2010
    FMM WORKING PAPER No. 14 · January, 2018 · Hans-Böckler-Stiftung DISTRIBUTION, WEALTH AND DEMAND REGIMES IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE USA, UK, France and Germany, 1855-2010 Engelbert Stockhammer*, Joel Rabinovich**, Niall Reddy*** ABSTRACT Most empirical macroeconomic research limited to the period since World War II. This paper analyses the effects of changes in income distribution and in private wealth on consumption and investment covering a period from as early as 1855 until 2010 for the UK, France, Ger- many and USA, based on the dataset of Piketty and Zucman (2014). We contribute to the post-Keynesian debate on the nature of demand regimes, mainstream analyses of wealth effects and the financialisation debate. We find that overall domestic demand has been wage-led in the USA, UK and Germany. Total investment responds positively to higher wage shares, which is driven by residential investment. For corporate investment alone, we find a negative relation. Wealth effects are found to be positive and significant for consumption in the USA and UK, but weaker in France and Germany. Investment is negatively affected by private wealth in the USA and the UK, but positively in France and Germany. * Kingston University London & FMM Fellow. ** Université Paris 13. *** New York University. Distribution, wealth and demand regimes in historical perspective. USA, UK, France and Germany, 1855-2010 Engelbert Stockhammer*, Joel Rabinovich** and Niall Reddy*** * Kingston University London, ** Université Paris 13, *** New York University Version 1.04 Oct 2017 Abstract Most empirical macroeconomic research limited to the period since World War II. This paper analyses the effects of changes in income distribution and in private wealth on consumption and investment covering a period from as early as 1855 until 2010 for the UK, France, Germany and USA, based on the dataset of Piketty and Zucman (2014).
    [Show full text]
  • Attack of the Cyborgs: Economic Imperialism and the Human Deficit in Ducationale Policy-Making & Research
    Journal of Educational Controversy Volume 8 Number 1 Who Defines the Public in Public Article 7 Education? 2014 Attack of the Cyborgs: Economic Imperialism and The Human Deficit in ducationalE Policy-Making & Research Scott Ellison University of Tennessee Follow this and additional works at: https://cedar.wwu.edu/jec Part of the Education Commons Recommended Citation Ellison, Scott (2014) "Attack of the Cyborgs: Economic Imperialism and The Human Deficit in ducationalE Policy-Making & Research," Journal of Educational Controversy: Vol. 8 : No. 1 , Article 7. Available at: https://cedar.wwu.edu/jec/vol8/iss1/7 This Article in Response to Controversy is brought to you for free and open access by the Peer-reviewed Journals at Western CEDAR. It has been accepted for inclusion in Journal of Educational Controversy by an authorized editor of Western CEDAR. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Ellison: Attack of the Cyborgs: Economic Imperialism and The Human Deficit Attack of the Cyborgs: Economic Imperialism and The Human Deficit in Educational Policy-Making & Research Scott Ellison University of Tennessee [T]he ideas of economists and political philosophers, both when they are right and when they are wrong, are more powerful than is commonly understood. Indeed the world is ruled by little else. Practical men, who believe themselves to be quite exempt from any intellectual influences, are usually the slaves of some defunct economist. Madmen in authority, who hear voices in the air, are distilling their frenzy from some academic scribbler of a few years back. I am sure that the power of vested interests is vastly exaggerated compared with the gradual encroachment of ideas..
    [Show full text]
  • A Cliometric Counterfactual: What If There Had Been Neither Fogel Nor
    A Cliometric Counterfactual: What if There Had Been Neither Fogel nor North? By Claude Diebolt (CNRS, University of Strasbourg) and Michael Haupert (University of Wisconsin-La Crosse Author contact information: [email protected] [email protected] Preliminary draft, please do not quote Abstract 1993 Nobel laureates Robert Fogel and Douglass North were pioneers in the “new” economic history, or cliometrics. Their impact on the economic history discipline is great, though not without its critics. In this essay, we use both the “old” narrative form of economic history, and the “new” cliometric form, to analyze the impact each had on the evolution of economic history. Introduction In December of 1960 the “Purdue Conference on the Application of Economic Theory and Quantitative Techniques to Problems of History” was held on the campus of Purdue University.1 It is recognized as the first meeting of what is now known as the Cliometric Society.2 While it was the first formal meeting of a group of like-minded applicants of economic theory and quantitative methods to the study of economic history, it was not the first time such a concept had been practiced or mentioned in the literature.3 Cliometrics was a long time in coming, but when it arrived, it eventually overran the approach to the discipline of economic history, leading to a bifurcation of the economists and historians who practice the art, and the blurring of the distinction between cliometricians and theorists who use historical data. Clio’s roots are historical in nature, and its focus on theory has actually come full circle over the last century and a half.
    [Show full text]
  • Examining the Ideas of Globalisation and Development Critically: What Role for Political Economy?
    New Political Economy, Vol. 9, No. 2, June 2004 Examining the Ideas of Globalisation and Development Critically: What Role for Political Economy? BEN FINE The purpose of this article is primarily to situate the rise of the idea of ‘globalisation’ in terms of its broader intellectual context, with some emphasis on the relevance for ‘development’, an equally contested concept.1 In part, the aim is to provide an answer to the question that has recently been succinctly posed by David Harvey. He recognises that globalisation ‘is now one of the most hegemonic concepts for understanding the political economy of international capitalism. And its uses extend far beyond the business world to embrace questions of politics, culture, national identity, and the like. So where did this concept come from?’2 I offer a broad and partial answer to this question in the next section, arguing that ‘globalisation’ neatly captures two intellectual trends, the dual retreat from the excesses both of neoliberalism and of postmodernism. From preoccupation with deconstruction and semiotics across the social sci- ences, attention has increasingly been directed towards understanding the nature of contemporary capitalism as a system of power and conflict, of poverty and inequality, of environmental degradation, and so on. ‘Globalisation’ predomi- nantly represents a return in emphasis to the study of material realities other than as a system of signs. Interest has focused on how the world is organised and functions internationally and nationally, reflecting intellectual departure from a ‘virtual’ world of increasingly free and unconstrained markets. Such concerns have also reduced the appeal of neoliberalism, the idea that the world could and should be run as if a perfectly functioning set of markets with at most a light, facilitating touch by the state.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics Imperialism Under the Impact of Psychology: the Ac Se of Behavioral Development Economics John B
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by epublications@Marquette Marquette University e-Publications@Marquette Economics Faculty Research and Publications Economics, Department of 3-1-2013 Economics Imperialism under the Impact of Psychology: The aC se of Behavioral Development Economics John B. Davis Marquette University, [email protected] Published version. OEconomia, Vol. 2013, No. 1 (March 2013): 119-138. Publisher Link. © 2013 NecPlus. Used with permission. Economics imperialism under the impact of psychology: The case of behavioral development economics John B. Davisi Department of Economics Marquette University Abstract. Economics imperialism is broadly explained as economics having an impact on other disciplines. But how should economics imperialism be understood when it is in some sense the product of other disciplines having an impact on economics? The paper examines psychology’s impact on economics in connection with the emergence of behavioral development economics, and then discusses the nature of behavioral development economics imperialism associated with development economists’ explanations of non-market dimensions of life in developing economies in behavioral economics terms. The paper argues that this new form of economics imperialism reflects economics’ selective appropriation from psychology of the Kahneman- Tversky heuristics and biases view of choice behavior and rejection of the Gigerenzer-ABC group fast and frugal heuristics view. This selective appropriation,
    [Show full text]
  • Mäki on Economics Imperialism
    Department of Economics Working Paper Mäki on Economics Imperialism By John B. Davis Working Paper 2010-04 College of Business Administration Mäki on Economics Imperialism John B. Davis♦ Department of Economics University of Amsterdam and Marquette University Abstract: This paper reviews Uskali Mäki’s epistemic analysis of economics imperialism formulated in terms of the science unification ideal and the three constraints on imperialism he develops. It then examines the phenomenon of ‘reverse imperialism’ associated with the influence of other fields on economics especially since 1980, and advances a core-periphery model of the identity of economics as a field made up of a collection of different research programs. The discussion returns to Mäki’s constraints framework to re-evaluate the ‘economics’ imperialism of individual research programs, and evaluates what we learn from Mäki’s three constraints. The paper concludes with a brief comment on the deductive top-down nature of Mäki’s epistemic model, and outlines a more historical approach to the subject of disciplinary imperialism that provides an alternative concept of constraints on research program extensions in terms of the idea of ‘resistances and accommodations.’ JEL codes: B20, B41 Keywords: economics imperialism, epistemic account, ‘reverse imperialism,’ core-periphery model of economics September 2010 ♦ Email: [email protected] Electronic copy available: http://epublications.marquette.edu/econ_workingpapers/4 1. Introduction Of Uskali Mäki’s many excellent contributions to the philosophy of economics, arguably one of the most important is his research on the phenomenon of economics imperialism. Other scholars have also discussed economics imperialism, but whereas this has often focused on particular historical episodes, schools, and individuals, Mäki’s attention has been both broader and deeper in his effort to think systematically about interdisciplinarity in the social sciences generally, as well as between the social sciences and the cognitive and biological sciences.
    [Show full text]
  • Handbook of Cliometrics
    Handbook of Cliometrics Claude Diebolt • Michael Haupert Editors Handbook of Cliometrics With 59 Figures and 20 Tables Editors Claude Diebolt Michael Haupert BETA/CNRS, University of Strasbourg University of Wisconsin – La Crosse Institute for Advanced Study La Crosse, WI, USA Strasbourg, France ISBN 978-3-642-40405-4 ISBN 978-3-642-40406-1 (eBook) ISBN 978-3-642-40407-8 (print and electronic bundle) DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-40406-1 Library of Congress Control Number: 2015943062 Springer Heidelberg New York Dordrecht London # Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2016 This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved by the Publisher, whether the whole or part of the material is concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, reuse of illustrations, recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilms or in any other physical way, and transmission or information storage and retrieval, electronic adaptation, computer software, or by similar or dissimilar methodology now known or hereafter developed. The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, service marks, etc. in this publication does not imply, even in the absence of a specific statement, that such names are exempt from the relevant protective laws and regulations and therefore free for general use. The publisher, the authors and the editors are safe to assume that the advice and information in this book are believed to be true and accurate at the date of publication. Neither the publisher nor the authors or the editors give a warranty, express or implied, with respect to the material contained herein or for any errors or omissions that may have been made.
    [Show full text]
  • The Integration of Economic History Into Economics
    Cliometrica https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-018-0170-8 ORIGINAL PAPER The integration of economic history into economics Robert A. Margo1 Received: 28 June 2017 / Accepted: 16 January 2018 Ó Springer-Verlag GmbH Germany, part of Springer Nature 2018 Abstract In the USA today the academic field of economic history is much closer to economics than it is to history in terms of professional behavior, a stylized fact that I call the ‘‘integration of economic history into economics.’’ I document this using two types of evidence—use of econometric language in articles appearing in academic journals of economic history and economics; and publication histories of successive cohorts of Ph.D.s in the first decade since receiving the doctorate. Over time, economic history became more like economics in its use of econometrics and in the likelihood of scholars publishing in economics, as opposed to, say, economic history journals. But the pace of change was slower in economic history than in labor economics, another subfield of economics that underwent profound intellec- tual change in the 1950s and 1960s, and there was also a structural break evident for post-2000 Ph.D. cohorts. To account for these features of the data, I sketch a simple, overlapping generations model of the academic labor market in which junior scholars have to convince senior scholars of the merits of their work in order to gain tenure. I argue that the early cliometricians—most notably, Robert Fogel and Douglass North—conceived of a scholarly identity for economic history that kept the field distinct from economics proper in various ways, until after 2000 when their influence had waned.
    [Show full text]
  • Cliometrics: a Market Account of a Scientific Community (1957-2006)
    Lect. Econ., 66 (enero-junio), pp. 47-82. © Universidad de Antioquia-Lecturas de Economía, 2007. Cliometrics: A Market Account of a Scientific Community (1957-2006) Angela Milena Rojas –Introduction. –I. A Pseudo-market for Scientific Communities. –II. The Golden Age: 1957-1975. –III. Internal Contraction and International Diffusion: 1976-1990. –IV. Toward Disciplinary and Global Integration: 1991-2006. –Conclusions. –References. Primera versión recibida en enero de 2007; versión final aceptada en abril de 2007 Lecturas de Economía. 66 (enero-junio 2007), pp 47-82 Angela Milena Rojas Cliometría: Una comunidad científica en el pseudo-mercado del conocimiento (1957-2006) Resumen: Este artículo tiene como objetivo evaluar las principales contribuciones de la cliometría en la integración global y disciplinaria de las ciencias sociales. A través de una analogía de un pseudo-mercado del conocimiento son analizadas las presiones y respuestas que los cliometristas han enfrentado en tanto una empresa cuyo objetivo es proveer respuestas a ciertas preguntas que la sociedad formula. Basado en una valoración general de los productos cliométricos se encuentra que esta comunidad científica norteamericana revolucionó la práctica de la historia económica y ganó terreno frente a la competencia representada por la historia tradicional. Posteriormente, los cliometristas difundieron sus innovaciones internacionalmente, pero atravesaron divisiones internas que en última instancia han enriquecido sus prácticas y llamado a cooperar con otras comunidades científicas. Palabras clave: cliometría, nueva historia económica, metodología en historia económica, comunidad científica, paradigma de investigación científica, métodos en ciencias sociales. Clasificación JEL: N01, A12, B41. Abstract: This paper aims at assessing the main contributions of cliometrics toward the global and disciplinary integration of social sciences.
    [Show full text]