<<

EDWARD M. GRAMLICH The Universityof

Macro Policy Responses to Shocks

IN RECENT YEARS the standardview of the inflationprocess has become complicatedby the realizationthat inflationarybursts can emanatefrom supp'yas well as fromdemand disturbances. -side disturbances, re- flectedmainly in risingfood and oil , generatedsharp increases in generalprice levels in most countriesof the world duringthe 1973-75 period. The impact in the was magnifiedby -price catch-upsafter the endingof controls,the productivityslowdown, the de- cline in the dollar,and a numberof legislativemeasures resulting in higher costs and prices.More recently,the decline of oil productionin and risingfarm prices are kindling fears of new supply-shockinflation. Price shocks from the supply side differfrom traditionaldemand-pull disturbancesbecause they can occur even at low levels of aggregatede- mand. Indeed,both theoryand data suggestthat supplyshocks are more likely to be associatedwith recessionsthan with booms. Because this is so, standardremedies for dealing with supply-sideinflation are not readily apparent.Most economistsnow more or less agreethat aggregatedemand policy shouldnot permitunemployment to fall below its natural,or non- accelerating-, for any lengthof time. But whetherunemploy- ment shouldbe allowedto rise above its naturalrate in the presenceof a

NOTE: I have benefited from the insightful comments of several BPEA partici- pants, especially from discussions with , and comments on a draft by colleagues GardnerAckley, Robert S. Holbrook, Saul H. Hymans, George E. Johnson, and William S. Krasker. I would also like to thank Susan Albert, Gregory Dow, and Judith Pregulman for their highly competent re- search assistance.

0007-2303/79/0001-0125$00.25/0 ? Brookings Institution 126 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1979 price shockfrom the supplyside-and by how much and for how - is a much more difficultquestion. At one extreme, macro policy could "accommodate"the , using eithermonetary or to shift the aggregatedemand in an expansionarydirection, maintain un- employmentat its initial rate, and acceptwhatever inflation might ensue in the process.At the other extreme,monetary and fiscal policy could be used in an attemptto engineera recessionsufficiently deep to extinguish the shock-inducedinflation promptly. Somewhere in the middlewould be a class of macro policies aimed at a constant or adjustedgrowth path for nominal income. Under these compromisepolicies the higher price levels inducedby the shock (when spendingdemands are inelastic) will imply a temporaryperiod of both unemploymentand inflation,lasting until the higher unemploymentsufficiently reduces wage and price levels throughoutthe to permit a returnto the preshockunemploy- ment rate. The choice between policies depends on whetherthe social costs of the greaterinflation generated or permittedby the accommodating macropolicy outweighthe social costs of the greaterinflation and unem- ployment generatedby any of the nonaccommodatingstrategies. Ironi- cally, this raisesthe old questionof how to choose betweenmore inflation and more ,even in a view of the inflationprocess that may allowno long-termtrade-off between the two. In this paperI analyzeand comparethese policy choices.The aimis to summarizeand pinpoint the implicationsof various models of supply shocks and the inflationaryprocess, without advancing a particularpoint of view. The paperbegins with a reviewof two recentmodels of supply- shockprice increases, one developedby Gordonand one by Phelps.lThese models deal primarilywith the impact of supply shocks on and price levels and give only partialattention to inflationrates and the feedbackprocess. So I extend the models to include what Perry calls a "mainlinemodel" of the inflationprocess, featuring a pricemarkup equa- tion and a wage-adjustmentPhillips curve with both a price-wageand a wage-wage mechanism.2The model is solved to determine the conditionsunder which accommodatingand nonaccommodatingre- 1. Robert J. Gordon, "Alternative Responses of Policy to External Supply Shocks," BPEA, 1:1975, pp. 183-204; and Edmund S. Phelps, "- and Full-Employment ," Journal of , and Banking,vol. 10 (May 1978), pp. 206-21. 2. George L. Perry, "Slowing the Wage-Price Spiral: The Macroeconomic View," BPEA, 2:1978, pp. 259-91. EdwardM. Gramlich 127 sponseswould be appropriate.It is then fitted empiricallyand simulated in the traditionalway to measurethe degree of inflationand unemploy- ment generatedby variousmacro strategiesin responseto a price shock. Becausethe desirabilityof these outcomesdepends on the relativesocial costs of inflationand unemployment,I then try to these relative costs. Some attemptsto estimatethem based on the work of others are comparedwith the normativeimplications of my own model, and with inferencesbased on surveydata. Sensitivity tests are also madeto see how the desirabilityof variousstrategies is alteredwhen the parametersof the model changeand when differentconceptions of the social costs of infla- tion andunemployment are adopted. Up to this point the modelused to analyzeprice shocks and the simula- tion of this model are based on relativelystandard techniques. To round out the story, I also investigate the question of how supply shocks mightbe analyzedin some of the newerexpectations-oriented theories of the inflation process-the game-of-strategyview of Fellner and the rational-expectationsviews of Lucas, Sargentand Wallace, Barro, and others.3 As a finalprefatory comment, I note thatthe entirepaper deals with the macroresponse to price shocks, with no discussionof how shocksmight be preventedfrom occurring.One conclusionof the paperis that whether shocksgenerate lingering future inflation or currentand future unemploy- ment,they can havelarge social costs. Therewould then be greatpotential gainsin any microeconomicsupply-management measures that could be designedto preventshocks, or adjustmentsintended to neutralizetheir initialimpact on overallprice levels. But the detailsof how thesemeasures shouldbe constructedraise issues that are much more industry-specific than are the issues discussedhere. Despite theirimportance, I simplywill not addressthose questionsin this paper.4 3. William Fellner, Towards a Reconstruction of : Problems of Theory and Policy (American Enterprise Institute, 1976); Robert E. Lucas, Jr., "Expectationsand the Neutrality of Money," Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 4 (April 1972), pp. 103-24; Thomas J. Sargent and Neil Wallace, "'Rational' Expec- tations, the Optimal Monetary Instrument, and the Optimal Rule," Journal of , vol. 83 (April 1975), pp. 241-54; and Robert J. Barro, "UnanticipatedMoney Growth and Unemployment in the United States," AmericanEconomic Review, vol. 67 (March 1977), pp. 101-15. 4. This judgment also partly reflects my view that a good survey of those mea- sures already exists in Robert W. Crandall, "Federal Government Initiatives to Reduce the ," BPEA, 2:1978, pp. 401-40. 128 BrookingsPapers on Economic Activity, 1:1979

The Theoryof SupplyShocks, Price Levels, and Inflation Rates

Two papersmodel the relationshipbetween supply shocks and overall output,price, and employmentlevels. The Gordonmodel is a two-sector one in which outputis exogenousin one sector called the "farm"sector; pricesin it are set to equilibratedemand and supply;and overallprice and output levels are then determinedby the degree of accommodationim- plicit in the macro policy response.5Phelps' model containsone sector, withthe exogenoussupply of rawmaterials as one componentof an aggre- gate productionfunction that has the usual propertiesof concavityand linearhomogeneity.6 Gordon considers one case in whichprices and are perfectlyflexible and one in which they are completelyinflexible, but the standardcase for both models allowsfor some upwardadjustment in aggregateprice levels as outputand employmentincrease. Hence the solu- tion,of the price and wage sectors of the model (given by the aggregate supplyline, AS, in the diagrambelow) is upwardsloping. Under Gordon's assumptions,at anylevel of real aggregateemployment, the exogenousde- cline in farm suppliesraises farm and overallprices, hence shiftingup the aggregatesupply schedule to AS'; underPhelps' assumptions, the of materialslowers labor's marginalproduct and, with a fixed money wage, shifts up marginalcosts and prices to AS'. The aggregatedemand schedule for both models representsthe solution of the IS andLM equationsand is shownas the downwardsloping AD line in the diagram.The standardrationale for this slope is that the nominal quantityof money, M, is fixed along the schedule and will support a higherlevel of aggregatedemand for labor when prices,P, are lower and the real money is greater.This rationaleworks only when the IS curve is downwardsloping and the LM upwardsloping. The argument could be madeslightly more general and much more realistic by specifying in additionthat all governmentexpenditures are indexed but thatprogres- sive incometax schedulesare written in nominalterms, so thatwhen prices fall, real fall and aggregatedemand for labor againincreases. The impact on output and employmentof a supply shock in either model is found by shiftingthe aggregatesupply curve as shown,yielding temporarilya positive correlationbetween inflation (dP/P > 0) and un- 5. Gordon, "AlternativeResponses of Policy to External Supply Shocks." 6. Phelps, "Commodity-SupplyShock." Edward M. Gramlich 129 Price level, P

AS'

P2 P1

Po

N1 N- Employment rate, N

employment(N < N*, whereN* is the normalhigh-employment rate). The new -runequilibrium will be at (P1, N1) unless one of several eventsoccurs. First, there could be an endogenousshift in the AD schedule.The pos- sibilityis raisedby Phelps, and the shift could be eitherupward (limiting the employmentdecline but raisingthe price level further) or downward (magnifyingthe employmentdecrease but limitingthe priceincrease). An upward or outward shift can result because the marginaland average productsof labor are reducedby the materialsshortage; outputis reduced;and thus the money demandedat full employmentmay be reduced.A downwardor inwardshift can occurbecausethe of materialsalso reducesthe marginalproduct of capitaland real rates,hence tendingto raisemoney at full employment.It is diffi- cult to tell which effect will predominate,but using reasonablevalues of money-demandelasticities, Phelps establishesthat therewill be some re- ductionin employmentand increase in the pricelevel-that is, anyvertical upwardshift of the AD schedulewill be less thanthat of the AS schedule. Second, policy could accommodatethe shocks by shifting the AD 130 BrookingsPapers on Economic Activity, 1:1979 schedulesufficiently to maintainN = N*, in the processraising prices to

P2. Third,the initial changein prices in any of these scenarioscould en- gender expectationsof further changes, hence superimposingdynamic inflationaryreactions on the comparativestatic model. To deal with this problemit is necessaryto combine the Gordon-Phelpsanalysis with an explicitmodel of the inflationaryprocess. InitiallyI use the standardor mainlineview, in which wage setters agree on their contractsin an eco- nomicenvironment characterized by a stateof demandin the labormarket and a historyof past rates of increaseof both wages and prices. Thereis broadagreement that the inversefunction of the unemploymentrate, U-', serveswell as the demandproxy, but not much agreementabout how or why the past rates of wage or price increasesshould enter the analysis. The standardtextbook treatment introduces these termsthrough an adap- tive expectationsprocess: workers base wage behavioron some notion of expectedprice changes,which are in turn relatedto past price changes. In contrast,Perry views the process in terms of inertiaand catch-upsof wages and prices.7Nor is there agreementon whetherthe increases to which money wages are respondingare those of prices, as in the more commonview of the worldthat invokescost-of-living escalation, or other wages,as in the view describedby Hall, whichassumes a competitivelabor .8 Withouttaking sides, it is possible to write an expressionfor a gen- eralizedexpectations or inertiaPhillips curve incorporating both a price- wage and a wage-wagefeedback mechanism, (1) w = ao + ajU-1 + a2L(w) + a3L(p), wherep and w referto the percentagerate of changeof prices and wages, respectively,and the L operatorsignifies some distributedlag on previous changes.This modelimplies a short-runtrade-off between unemployment, U, and inflation,but a long-runtrade-off if the sum of the expectations- inertia coefficientsa2 + a3 is unity and if these wage changes are fully passedthrough into price changes. For the price equation,the standardmodel impliesthat prices are de- terminedby a proportionatemarkup over costs. To addressthe issue of

7. Perry, "Slowingthe Wage-PriceSpiral." 8. Robert E. Hall, "The Process of Inflation in the Labor Market," BPEA, 2:1974, pp. 343-93. EdwardM. Gramlich 131 the extent to which exogenous increases in materialscosts are passed throughinto the inflationprocess, the expressionis written (2) p = a4 + a5w + a6pc, whereP. is the exogenouspercentage rate of change of materialsprices anda, is the negativeof the percentagerate of increaseof outputper factor unit (labor plus materials). Measuresfor indirecttaxes and the cost of capitalgoods are omittedfor the sakeof simplicity:if they changepropor- tionately with wages and materialsprices, a5 + a6 should equal unity; otherwisethe sum of a5 and a6 should be less than unity.9While p, is the only explicit supply-shockterm in the equation,it shouldbe understood that any shiftin the expression,say througha productivityslowdown, will have a similarimpact on inflationand unemploymentand the response shouldbe the same as it wouldbe for a shock. The model can be solved by substitutingequation 1 into 2 and solvingrecursively backward. Two assumptionscan be made aboutPc- either that the entire rate of change of materialsprices is exogenous,or that only the relativerate of changeof materialsprices, p', is exogenous, where p= p + p'. Takingfirst the latter assumption,and assumingin additionthat lags in the wage equationlast one period, that a2 + a3 < 1, and that a5 + a6 = 1, yields an expression for the reduced-form inflation equation:

(3a) a,(1 - a2) ? aoa + (- a5~ )3aP a5(1 -a3- a2) + a5) P

+ a3+ (13 a5) E (a3 + a2)i-p'_j + a, E (a3 + a2)iU_l. a5 i=1 i_=o As a2 + a3approaches unity, so that the long-rununemployment-inflation -offvanishes, any previouslevel of U will have some impact on the currentinflation rate. Moreover, if there is some price-wagefeedback mechanism(a3 > 0), any previousprice shock will lead to some current inflation.But if eitherof these conditionsis not fulfilled,the inflationary impact of price shocks will graduallydiminish. These shocks will alter inflationrates in the short run, but they will not do so in the long run. Exactly how long the inflationaryimpact of a shock will persistthen be- comesan empiricalquestion depending on a2and a3. 9. In Gordon's most recent estimate of his structural price equation, the terms I have omitted did not have statistically significant coefficients. See Robert J. Gor- don, "Can the Inflation of the 1970s Be Explained?"BPEA, 1:1977, pp. 253-79. 132 BrookingsPapers on Economic Activity, 1:1979 The second way to solve the model is to take the entirerate of change of materialsprices, pc, as exogenous.The equationbecomes (3b) p _a4(1 - a2) + a0a5+ (1 - a5)p

+ (1 - a5)a5a3 E (a5a3 + a2)i-'p0_ + a5a, E (a5a3 + a2)iLUT2 i=1 i=O The conditionfor the long-termtrade-off to vanishand for shocksto per- sist now becomes a5a3 + a2 = 1. Because a5 will undoubtedly be close to unity,no largepractical difference exists between this formof the solution and thatgiven in equation3a, but in this solutionthe price-wagefeedback coefficient (a3 > 0) now has two effects. In addition to providingthe vehicle for shocks to be incorporatedinto the inflationaryprocess, it also makes the model slightlyless accelerationistbecause now wage changes are slightly diluted every time they feed throughthe price equationand then back into furtherwage changes.If the feedbackmechanism were of the wage-wagevariety (a, = 1, a3 = 0), this dampeningwould not exist and the model would remainaccelerationist even for a5 < 1. Equation3a or 3b providesthe reduced-formsolution of the price-wage sector. The next task is to use these equationsto find the optimalpolicy responseto a shock. This is done by findingthe minimumvalue for the loss function,

(4) SC = 2 < pi + b ui'

whereSC is ; t is the policymakinghorizon; r. is the social dis- countrate used to valuefuture inflation; r, is thatrate used to valuefuture unemployment(not necessarilythe same discountrate); and b is the all- importantparameter representing the socialcost of unemploymentrelative to that of inflation. The optimal response to a price shock can be found by substituting eitherof the reduced-formexpressions, say equation3a into 4, takingde- rivativeswith respectto unemployment(the variablemost directly con- trolledby macropolicy), and solvingthe model. If the policy horizonis assumedto be infinite,this procedureyields a set of equationsof the form: ~+ (5) uo = a,(, rp) (5) UO= jb(1 + r -a2- a3) . v 1/1 + r, EdwardM. Gramlich 133 In this solution,the generallevel of all unemploymentrates depends posi- tively on the short-runimpact of unemploymenton inflation, al, and negativelyon the relative social cost of unemployment,b. Even if the model is accelerationist(a2 + a3 = 1), the presence of discountingwill a general analytic solution for the unemploymentpath.'0 And as long as the discountrates are the same (ru = rn), the optimalpath implies that all unemploymentrates are the same-that is, that shocks are to be fully accommodated.Macro policy shouldmove the unemploymentrate to its optimallevel (the nonaccelerating-inflationrate of unemployment in the accelerationistcase) andhold it there,with or withoutshock. The question of whetheror not to accommodatethe shock then be- comes interestingwhenever any of the assumptionsof this simpleexercise are not fulfilled: First, if the policy horizonis not infinitebut finite,it will be desirable to eliminatethe shock-inducedinflation before some arbitrarydate. In this case, because the inflation-fightingimpact of unemploymentin the near term is more valuable, there should be a temporaryrecession, and the shock will not be fully accommodated."l Second, if the relative cost of unemployment,b, declines as inflation rises, a shock will raise the optimal unemploymentrate at the time it occurs, againimplying a less than fully accommodatingpolicy. Third, if any parametersof the model are not constantbut depend either on the state of the economy or some perceptionof government policy, nonaccommodativeresponses may become optimal. And fourth,if the economywas initiallyin a state of overemployment, a shock could triggeran adjustmentto a new higherunemployment rate and appearto signal a nonaccommodativepolicy response. The next sectionsof the paperinvestigate these matters.

A StandardEmpirical Model of the InflationProcess

I begin by fittinga standardmodel of the inflationprocess. The model containsfour sections.The first uses standardformulations of wage and 10. Modigliani and Papademos also discuss this issue; see and Lucas Papademos, "Optimal Demand Policies against ," Weltwirtschaft- lichesArchiv, vol. 114 (December 1978), pp. 736-82. 11. This is the same principle expressed in my previous work; see Edward M. Gramlich, "The Optimal Timing of Unemployment in a ,"BPEA, 1:1975, pp. 167-80. 134 BrookingsPapers on Economic Activity, 1:1979 price adjustmentto determinethe past historicalrelationship between in- flationand unemployment; the secondestimates, in severaldifferent ways, the key relativecost parameterin the social loss function;and the third estimatesthe apparentserial correlation, if any, of price shocks.The final section of the model, consistingonly of identities,shows how the various accommodatingand nonaccommodatingpolicy responses are to be defined.

THE INFLATION-UNEMPLOYMENT RELATIONSHIP The standardmainline model of the inflationprocess features a Phillips- curve wage equationsimilar to equation 1 and a price markupequation similarto 2. Both are fit to annualdata over the 1954-77 period. Begin- ning with the former, I define w as the percentagechange in average hourly earningsadjusted to exclude overtimeand interindustryshifts, U as the unemploymentrate using constant (1966) wage-weighteddemo- graphicproportions of the laborforce, andp as the rate of inflationin the consumerprice . The equationis (1') w =-0.394 + 6.895 U-1 + 0.3189 p-i (-0.4) (3.4) (2.9) + 0.4041 w-, + 0.1347 w-2, (1.7) (0.7) 1R2 = 0.834; Durbin-Watson = 1.74; standard error = 0.675. The figuresin parentheseshere and in subsequentequations are t-statis- tics. This equationis quite similarto that estimatedby Perry for the pre- controlsperiod.'2 Adding the last six yearsof turbulentdata has succeeded in loweringthe unemploymentcoefficient only slightly,and has raisedthe price-wagefeedback coefficient from Perry's 0.21 to 0.32. The cyclicalin- fluenceof unemploymenton wage changesis similarto thatfound in most wage-adjustmentequations estimated in the past decade.Also, as is com- mon currently,the model is nearlyaccelerationist, with the feedbackco- efficientssumming to 0.86, slightlymore than one-thirdof which is at- tributableto cost-of-livingescalation and the remainderto wage catch-up escalation.Dummies for the controlsperiod and a post-controlscatch-up 12. Perry, "Slowing the Wage-Price Spiral," p. 277, equation 3. In both this equation and in 2', I use one hundred times the change in the natural log of a vari- able as its percentagerate of change. EdwardM. Gramlich 135 weretried in otherversions of the equationand did not changethe results greatly,with one importantexception. There is some collinearitybetween the catch-updummy (with a value of one in 1974 and 1975) and the laggedprice-inflation term, for the obvious reasonthat the post-controls periodwas the one historicalepisode in whichthe growthof pricesdiffered markedlyfrom that of wages.When this catch-updummy is included,the price-wagefeedback coefficient drops to 0.11, belowPerry's value of 0.21. In additionto the usual types of ,then, there is the specific possibilitythat the price-wagefeedback coefficientcould be well below 0.32, a possibilityI will deal withbelow. This expressionis then combinedwith a price markupequation along the lines of equation2. The modelis not as elaborateas that estimatedby Gordonbecause I omittedhis indirecttax, capitalcost, and cyclicalterms. (I triedthe last, but found themto have the wrongsign.) To simplifythis analysis,the price equationis fit with averagehourly earnings as the inde- pendentvariable and the consumerprice index as the dependentvariable. It would have been more appropriateto use labor compensation(includ- ing fringebenefits) as the independentvariable and the nonfarmdeflator as the dependentvariable, but the errorsintroduced by my simplification seem modest and can be adjustedfor. The variableused for the materials price changeis the componentof the producerprice index called "crude materialsfor furtherprocessing"-a weightedaverage of the for foodstuffsand feedstuffs(with an officialweight as of December1978 of 0.59), fuel (weight = 0.15), and other nonfood materials (weight = 0.26). When equation2 was fittedin unconstrainedform with the lagged dependentvariable to allow for a delayedresponse, the sum of the long- run coefficientsa, and a6 exceeded unity, an inadmissibleresult. So the equationwas reestimatedwith the long-runcoefficients constrained to sum to unityby subtractingp-1 from the othervariables; it also includesdum- mies for controls, D71.72, and post controls, D7475, periods. These had highlysignificant impacts and this time did not distortthe othercoefficients in the equation.The equationis

(2') p -p-i = -1.207 + 0.6632 (w -p-) + 0.0953 (p -p-1) (-3.8) (5.5) (4.0) -1.210 D71,72+ 2.753 D74,75, (-2.1) (4.5) A2 = 0.777; Durbin-Watson = 1.61; standarderror = 0.753. 136 BrookingsPapers on Economic Activity, 1:1979 The productivitytrend is 1.21 percentper year;the fit is reasonablygood; andthe priceindex for crudematerials is highlysignificant. Solving for the long-runcoefficients of w and p, yields values of 0.874 and 0.126, respec- tively. The implicationsof this two-equationmodel canbest be summarizedby solvingthe equationstogether and findingthe impliedlong-run inflation- unemploymentrelationship. After a slight adjustmentin the constantto accountfor the fact that the consumerprices rise on average0.2 percent a year more rapidlythan the nonfarmdeflator and that gross compensa- tion rises on average 0.4 percent per year more rapidly than average hourlyearnings, the long-runequations are (3a') p -10.77 + 48.46 U-1 + 0.4655 p', when relativecrude prices are exogenous,and (3b') p = -7.28 + 33.06 U-1 + 0.3177 p6, when absolutecrude prices are exogenous, wherep' andpc are now to be interpretedas trendrates of changein rela- tive or absoluteprices of crudematerials.'3 The stable-priceunemployment rate, U*, is found to equal 4.5 percent in both equations;this is slightlymore than the averagevalue of 4.1 per- cent over the 1954-77 periodand correspondsto a noninflationaryofficial unemploymentrate of 6.2 percentin 1978, which is approximatelywhat otherinvestigators such as Hall, Modiglianiand Papademos, Wachter, and Caganhave found.'4At this unemploymentrate, a one percentagepoint

13. The constant adjustment is derived as follows. The equation that should be fit is p,n= ao + a1W, + a2p0, where p,n is the rate of change of the nonfarm de- flator, and w. is that of gross compensation. During the period, w_ = w + 0.4 and p = p,n + 0.2. Substitutingyields p - 0.2 + a0 + alw + 0.4al + a2p,. Therefore 0.2 + 0.4a, = 0.2 + (0.4) (0.87) = 0.55 is added to the constant in the consumer price, average hourly earnings equation. This value should be subtracted from the constant of equation 2' to find the unemployment rate at which an equation of pn on W. would show stable prices, and at which equation 2' would show prices rising at 0.55 percent a year. 14. See Hall, "The Process of Inflation";Modigliani and Papademos, "Optimal Demand Policies"; Michael L. Wachter, "The Changing Cyclical Responsiveness of Wage Inflation,"BPEA, 1:1976, pp. 115-59; and Phillip Cagan, "The Reduction of Inflation and the Magnitude of Unemployment,"in William Feliner, ed., Contempo- rary Economic Problems (American EnterpriseInstitute, 1977), pp. 15-52. EdwardM. Gramlich 137 rise in unemploymentwould lower the inflationrate by 0.2 percentage point in the firstyear, a flat short-runtrade-off relationship with a slope somewhatbelow what other investigatorshave found, but certainlynot outsidethe rangeof estimatesof valuesof this parameter.15

THE SOCIAL COSTS OF INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT The various social costs of inflation and unemploymenthave beert enumeratedmany times.16 Inflation generates information costs, efficiency costs, and distributionallosses that are especially serious for the aged; unemploymentimplies an outputand income gap that may disadvantage all incomegroups but is particularlyharmful to those with lower incomes. But to analyzepolicy choices in the presenceof price shocks, it is neces- saryto knowmore than that both unemploymentand inflation entail social costs-in particular,how great are these relative costs in quantitative terms? The literatureon programevaluation suggests many ways to answer such a question.A first method might be called the revealedpreference technique.As appliedto this problem,the reasoningwould be as follows. If there is a nonvanishinglong-run trade-off relationship, policymakers have alreadyhad to select a point on the trade-offcurve, and the slope of the curveat thatpoint can be examinedto findthe implicitmarginal rate of substitutionof policymakers.The trade-offin the above model is just barelynonvanishing, perhaps by enoughto make such a comparisonpos- sible. While the weighted unemploymentrate (and implicit point of tangency) has varied,it has averaged4.1 percentover the 1954-77 pe- riod,just slightlybelow the impliednoninflationary rate of 4.5 percent.At U = 4.1, the implied marginal rates of substitutionin the long-run trade-offrelationship are given by 48.5 x 4. 1-2 = 2.9 when changesin relative crude materialsprices are exogenous, and 33.1 x 4. 1-2 = 2.0 whenchanges in absolutecrude prices are exogenous. Both tangencysolu- tions are shown in fiaure 1. Hence this revealedpreference method sug- 15. See Arthur M. Okun, "Efficient Disinflationary Policies," American Eco- nomic Review, vol. 68 (May 1978, Papers and Proceedings, 1977), pp. 348-52. 16. Most recently by Gardner Ackley, "The Costs of Inflation," and , "The Private and Social Costs of Unemployment,"in , vol. 68 (May 1978, Papers and Proceedings, 1977), pp. 149-54, and 155-58, respectively. 138 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1979

Figure1. The Long-RunPhillips Curveand OptimalInflation-Unemployment Combination

Inflationrate, p

12 - Relative pc exogenous

9 Absolute Pc exogenous

6

3 Tangenecy point: b = 2 ~ ~ b= .

0 Unemployment rate, U 2 4 4.5

Source: Derived by solving text equations 1' and 2' for the implied long-run inflation-unemployment relationship and adjusting for the greater average increase in consumer prices relative to the nonfarm and gross compensation relative to average hourly earnings, as described in text note 13. The pc term is the trend percentage rate of change in the absolute price of crude materials; pc is the trend rate of change in the of crude materials, or pc - p; b is marginal rate of substitution be- tween unemployment and inflation or, alternatively, the relative social cost of unemployment. The tangency points determine the optimal long-run trade-off. The figure assumes that policymakers have chosen a trade-off at which the weighted unemployment rate is 4.1 percent, its average over the 1954-77 period. EdwardM. Gramlich 139 gests that an added percentagepoint of unemploymentis between two andthree times as costlyas an addedpercentage point of inflation."7 A second approachto estimatingthe relative costs of unemployment and inflationmight be called the directestimation technique. As applied by Modiglianiand Papademos,'8it involves comparingthe costs of the outputloss of an addedpercentage point of unemployment,3 percentof GNP accordingto Okun'slaw, with the costs of an added point of infla- tion. To computethe last, they deal with only the transfercosts of inflation,those representingtransfers from creditorswhen actualinflation rates exceed those anticipatedat the time financialcontracts were signed. Modiglianiand Papademosignore the correspondinggains to debtorsby virtue of what might be known as the robberytheorem-robbeiy is not costless even thoughit is "only a transfer";indeed it is at least as costly as the size of the transfer.Because the total value of fixedmoney claims in the economy is about 1.5 times GNP, a one percentagepoint rise in the inflationrate lowers the real value of these claims by approximately1.5 percentof GNP. This yields an estimatefor b, the relativesocial cost of unemployment,of 2 (3/1.5), similarto that of the revealedpreference value. The next methodsfocus more directlyon voter preferences.One ap- proachis to use the Universityof Michigan'sindex of consumersentiment to measurethe relativeunpopularity of inflationand unemployment.Con- sumptionstudies by Suits and Sparks,Hymans, and Justerand Wachtel have establishedthat movements in the index can help explainmovements in consumption,assuming that consumersfeel betteroff and hence spend more when the index is high.19A furtheranalysis by Lovell then shows that movementsin the index can, in turn, be explainedby stock prices, inflation,and unemployment.The index is lowered by 0.88 point with an additionalpercentage point of unemployment,and by 1.23 pointswith 17. Although the social discount rate on inflation should enter into the calcula- tion of the optimum [b = a1a5(1 + rp) U-2/(1 + rp - a2 - a3)], its quantitative impact is small for small values of rp. Hence I assumed it to be zero in this calcula- tion and in the figure. 18. Modigliani and Papademos, "OptimalDemand Policies." 19. See Daniel B. Suits and Gordon R. Sparks, "ConsumptionRegressions with QuarterlyData," in James S. Duesenberryand others, eds., The Brookings Quarterly Econometric Model of the United States (Rand McNally, 1965), pp. 203-23; Saul H. Hymans, "Consumer Durable Spending: Explanation and Prediction," BPEA, 2:1970, pp. 173-99; F. Thomas Juster and Paul Wachtel, "Inflation and the Con- sumer,"BPEA, 1:1972, pp. 71-114. 140 BrookingsPapers on Economic Activity, 1:1979 an addedpercentage point of inflation.20Hence the impliedvalue of b is 0.72 (0.88/1.23). Unlike all other techniques,this indirectsurvey mea- sureweights unemployment less than inflation,and thus even less than it is weightedin the commonly used economic discomfortindex (which sumsinflation and unemployment rates, thus assumingb is 1). A nrtoredirect alternative is to use answersto the Galluppoll question, "Whatdo you thinkis the most importantproblem facing the countryto- day?" were asked this questiontwenty-eight times since 1957, and time-serieschanges in the answeringpattern are known to be corre- lated with actuallevels of inflationand unemployment.The basic idea is to explainthe percentof householdsresponding that the most important problemwas inflationor unemploymentwith variousmathematical con- structionsof actualinflation or unemploymentindicators as independent variables. In principlethere are two waysin whichthe equationscould be fit. One way is in unconstrainedform, using as the dependentvariable the simple percentageof familiesresponding inflation or unemployment:

Pr(p) = f(pe, p - pe, U - U*, UU*),

Pr(U) = f(pe, p - pe, U - U*, UU*), wherePr(p) and Pr(U) measurerespectively the percentof familiesre- spondinginflation or unemployment;pe, some version of the expected rate of inflation;p pe, the unanticipatedrate; U - U*, cyclicalunem- ployment; and UU*, the official global unemploymentrate when the constant-weightunemployment is at its noninflationaryvalue.21 This rate in unconstrainedform allows implied costs of inflationand unemploy- ment to dependdifferently on anticipatedand unanticipatedinflation and cyclical and noncyclical unemployment.Quadratic terms can also be used as neededto test for any nonlinearitiesin the social cost function. The problemwith the unconstrainedtechnique is that it does not force respondentsto tradeoff inflationand unemployment.Inflation and unem- ploymentare commonanswers to the question,averaging 28 percentand

20. Michael C. Lovell, "Why Was the Consumer Feeling So Sad?" BPEA, 2:1975, pp. 473-79. 21. Because the constant-weightvalue of the noninflationaryrate is a constant, convertingit to an overall basis as shown is the only way I know to allow respondents to express their satisfaction or dissatisfactionwith the level of unemployment at full employment. EdwardM. Gramlich 141 10 percent,respectively, of the responsesduring the period.But they are not the only answers,and to the extent that householdschange their re- sponseto inflationfrom, say, crimein the streets,the interpretationwould be differentthan if inflationgained at the expenseof unemployment.The way to overcome this difficultyis to fit regressionswith the dependent variabledefined as Pr (p) /[Pr (p) + Pr ( U) ]. Table 1 provides some illustrativeequations, fit first in an uncon- strainedform, to explain the total percentageof householdsresponding inflationor unemployment.Equations 1-1 through1-4 explainthe percent respondinginflation; 1-5 through1-8, the percentresponding unemploy- ment. In table 1 the expected rate of inflation,pe, is computed as the averageannual rate over the eightquarters before the questionwas asked, and it can be seen that expectedinflation always has a muchlarger coeffi- cient than unexpectedinflation (p - pe). This could reflecta numberof factors-that the householdsare not yet informedof 'beliefs that they should alreadyhave protectedthemselves against anticipated inflation;that it maybe difficultto protectoneself (for example,many may still be looking for an easy way to save at a positive after-taxreal ); that people do not fear somethinguntil they expectit; or that I may not have createda good proxyfor expectedinflation. Whatever the expla- nation, this particularway of disaggregatingthe inflationterm does not give verysensible results. Hence in all equationsexcept 1-1 and 1-5, I have simplyused the contemporaneousinflation rate as the independentvari- able. Regardingother aspects of the implied loss function, the unemploy- ment rate at high employment,UU*, has a large coefficientin the unem- ploymentequations (equations 1-5 and 1-6), which indicatesthat trend unemploymentis by no means viewed as costless by respondents.The variablehas so little variancethat its t-statisticis usually low, however. When quadraticterms were tried in equations 1-3 and 1-4 for inflation and 1-7 and 1-8 for unemployment,p2 and (U - U* ) 2 invariablytook on the wrongsign, indicatingthat the loss functionimplicit in these answers does not imply increasingmarginal cost as the rate of eitherinflation or unemploymentrises. The most reliable equationsappear to be 1-2 and 1-6. They can be interpretedas follows. Holding unemploymentconstant, an added per- centagepoint of inflationraises the numberof respondentswho thinkthat inflationis the nation'smost serious problemby 4.14 percentagepoints .t 8 oo e ^ t t < o > QO=~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~t443 )

o~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~Lt t N rAS o C's S g b~00en b b F b b b Os o 6)

I~~~~~~~~~ct V- eq V- o ;) c Is 0??

3 CZ *L. . . . . XX

o~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~C0 o oo c8855

ae s Ej ~~~~~~~~t- t- V- t_ . O t1 I.- CS,gQe^0

iEs W G ,,) - r=? gi c~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~o. ,@O

3~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ t) 0, 0 s2y

_i E5 g cl t 3 3 i 4 T k ; t | 8 o ...R 5 > a : cs @ ;8 O , m.~~~~~~~~~~~~~4o , '5 *" i ! N G ^ dx m XD, CX:ew98;Qa~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~U EdwardM. Gramlich 143 (equation 1-2). Holding inflationconstant, an added percentagepoint of cyclical unemployment(U - U*) raises the numberof respondents who think that unemploymentis the nation's most serious problemby 5.30 percentagepoints (equation 1-6). If social costs increase in some proportionto the numberof peoplewhose views aboutthe most important problemare changed,the impliedestimate of the social cost of unemploy- mentrelative to that of inflationis 1.28 (5.30/4.14). This time the value of b is somewhatgreater than unity, but not as high as that given by the revealedpreference technique. Table2 showsthe resultswhen percentages of respondentsstating infla- tion and employmentare constrainedto add to 100. Since they do add to 100, only one type of equationneeds to be fit. I fit the one with infla- tion responsesin the numerator,and the implied coefficientsfor unem- ploymentare the negativesof those in the table. Equation2-1 of table 2 confirmsthe aboveresult that expectedinflation has a muchmore adverse impactthan unexpectedinflation, and in fact this time the latter has the wrong sign. The trend unemploymentrate, UU*, continuesto have the propersign and a large impact,but is statisticallyinsignificant. Equation 2-2 uses a differentvariant of the expectedinflation rate as the indepen- dent variable,simply the nominal interestrate on long-termbonds (as- sumedto equal r + pe, where r is the real interestrate). The results are essentiallythe same,and unanticipatedinflation, while now displayingthe propersign, has a much smallerestimated impact than expectedinflation (because the coefficientfor p is below that for r + pe). Equation 2-3 adopts the successfulforms of table 1, and shows that trend unemploy- ment has effectivelybeen eliminated.Equation 2-4, which uses quadratic terms,shows againthat both are of the wrongsign. The impliedestimate of b in equation2-3 jumpsto 3.96 (11.73/2.96)-now a point of unem- ploymentis viewedas nearlyfour times as harmfulas a point of inflation. There are, of course, serious flaws in all these approachesfor mea- suringb. The revealedpreference notion dependson my own estimatesof the slope of the long-runinflation-unemployment trade-off; it is based on particularhistorical events such as the VietnamWar, and relies on a very strong assumptionof how underlyingpreferences are reflectedin actual policy decisions.The directestimation approach quantifies only one type of cost of inflation,and very crudelyat that. The index of consumersenti- mentmethod is indirect,and it is essentiallydesigned to determinewhether householdswill consumeheavily, not to assessperceptions of social prob- Eco^ 42

cx | I ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ S o~~; Dc3

X kb o'~~0. * k * cl .0 D q . a 2 X | X - mX - g - n tj.

m; ? 0 v1 < IC^5 p2C

a X - E O co n OCc c O o W J-4

i t 6 | a+ a + a,~~~~0 t C1 0) aq;?

V Q N ^ t F ~~~~O C; . ; : EdwardM. Gramlich 145 lems. The problemwith the Gallup poll methods is that people are not beingasked to act on theirpreferences, only to state them-a well-known and fundamentalproblem with using survey data. Further,the respon- dents, like economists,may not understandthe natureand seriousnessof the inflationproblem very well; they may overstatethe seriousnessif they believethat pricesgo up becauseof inflationand that moneyincomes rise as a result of their hard work. Or they may understatethe seriousness becausethey do not understandthe subtletiesof efficientresource alloca- tion. Moreover,expectations are relevant.If people, based on historical experience,hold regressiveexpectations about unemployment and extrap- olative expectationsabout inflation,a rise in the inflationrate will capi- talize futurefears much more than will a rise in unemployment,overstat- ing the relativecosts of currentinflation and thus understatingb. This may also be the reasonwhy expectedinflation is consideredso painful.Finally, the surveyapproach does not addressthe key distributionalissue: if either inflationor cyclical unemploymentwere to be particularlypainful to a certainsubgroup of the population,as both certainlyare, changesin eco- nomic conditionsmay add little to the numberof answersin the popula- tion at largebut a lot to some conceptionof overallsocial costs or aggre- gate pain. About the only point the survey approachhas in its favor is that for once social planners are asking people their preferences,not tellingthem. Returningnow to the question of whether or not to accommodate shocks, if the resultsof this section can be believed at all, two important implicationsare that the loss functionappears to be approximatelylinear, with no discernible change in the marginal rate of substitutionover observed ranges of variationof inflation and unemployment,and that anticipatedinflation appearsto be at least as unpleasantto people as unanticipatedinflation. The first conclusiontends to supportthe superi- ority of shock-accommodatingpolicies, although, as was mentioned above,other conditions must also be satisfied.The secondconclusion dic- tates againstan excessive discount of future inflationbecause it can be anticipated,and tendsto lowerrp and raisethe futurecosts of any inflation that follows an initialshock. The more detailed evaluationsof various policy responses to price shocksthen require quantitative estimates of b. These are distributedover a fairlywide range,but it shouldbe somewhatreassuring that quite diver- gent analyticaltechniques for measuringthem, each one imperfectin its 146 BrookingsPapers on Economic Activity, 1:1979 own way, gave estimatesthat were at least halfway consistent.Ranked fromlow to high, and comparedwith the economicdiscomfort index, the estimatesare as follows.

Method Value of b Index of consumersentiment (Lovell) 0.7 Economic discomfort index 1.0 UnconstrainedGallup poll (table 1, equations1-2 and 1-6) 1.3 Direct estimation(Modigliani and Papademos) 2.0 Revealedpreference (absolute Pc exogenous) 2.0 Revealedpreference (relative Pc exogenous) 2.9 ConstrainedGallup poll (table 2, equation2-3) 4.0

An added percentagepoint of unemploymentappears to be from nearly one to four times as painful as an added percentagepoint of inflation, withboth a medianand mean estimate of abouttwo.

SERIAL CORRELATION OF PRICE SHOCKS One relativelyminor issue that also comes up in the analysis of re- sponsesto shocksis the questionof serialcorrelation. When a price shock occurs,is it more likely to reverseitself (as mightbe the case in Gordon's farm sector) or repeatitself (as with growingscarcities of needed mate- rials)? The issue of serial correlationdoes not change the underlying analytics in any obvious respect because follow-on shocks can be re- spondedto in the same way as can initial shocks (as long as they remain exogenous), but still it is interestingto estimatethe degreeof serialcorre- lation to computerealistic estimates of the amountof inflationand unem- ploymentimplied by standardresponses to initialshocks. Beginningwith the stochasticpart of equations 1' and 2', not much evidenceseems to exist of eitherpositive or negativeserial correlationin the equation residuals themselves. Both equations satisfy the Durbin- Watsontest for the absenceof serial correlationat the 95 percentconfi- dencelevel. But the residualsare not the only source of shocks in the model. The other source is the price term for crude materialsin equation 2'. The equationsin table 3 investigatewhether this rate of change is serially correlatedby fitting a series of autoregressiveequations. Equations 3-1 and 3-2 explain the gross rate of change of crude materialsprices, p0, 00

~~~~~ /~ ~ ~~~~

0 0 5O

'-4 00 ~ ~ ~ 55) II

CD * *en 0 CII xu

o I-~~~~~~c

00

0

0

0

.,, an**0 o ~~~~~~' 5e~~~~~~~~~5e~ ~ ~ ~ omaw

?0 0' -4 ~ ~ ~ - f4*~~~ * * * * * *~ ~ ~ ~

o -- '~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~0 00 0 0

0~~~~~~~~~~ 4 1 Clh C; c1* C;d..~.j*f 148 BrookingsPapers on Economic Activity, 1:1979 withautoregressive lags up to threeyears; 3-3 and 3-4 explainthe relative rate of changeof crudematerials prices (p', wherep' = P- p). Com- parisonof the two pairsof equationsindicates whether or not any endog- enous serialcorrelation component operates through the generalrate of inflation. All equationsdisplay reasonably good evidenceof some serialcorrela- tion. Farmprice movementsseem to follow a two-yearcycle (based on workSaul Hymansshowed me from the Universityof Michigan'secono- metricmodel), apparentlyleading to the negativecoefficients for the two- yearlag terms.The one- and three-yearlag termsindicate positive serial correlation,suggesting that price shocks generallyare not reversedbut are augmentedby future shocks. Approximatelyhalf of this autoregres- sionis eliminatedwhen relativechanges in crudeprices are used. Whether in absoluteor relativeterms then, price shockswill be moreof a sourceof continuinginflation, as opposedto one-timeincreases in price levels, than wouldat firstbe apparent.

ACCOMMODATING AND NONACCOMMODATING POLICIES To complete the model it is necessaryto add some equationsto in- corporatethe government'spolicy response. At one extreme,if the re- sponsewere to be completeaccommodation of price shocks, such equa- tions would be unnecessary:then the unemploymentrate would be held at some predeterminedlevel regardlessof any shocks, and the resulting inflationwould be given by the wage-pricefeedback model describedin equations1 and 2 above. Calculationswould be just as unnecessaryfor the other extremepolicy of extinguishingprice-shock inflation immedi- ately: there the unemploymentrate would simply be allowed to rise by the amountappropriate to hold inflationconstant. But regardlessof the desirabilityof these strategies,they may not be feasible. By the time a shock is felt, it may be too late to preventthe unemploymentrate from risingin a strictaccommodation policy, and it will almostcertainly be too late to magnify the rise in unemploymentunder an extreme policy to extinguishinflation. The only realistic approachmight be to use some variantof a strategyof nominalincome growth,and then more detail in the modelis necessaryto determinethe pathto be takenby unemployment andinflation rates. The most obvious nominal income strategy is the constant growth EdwardM. Gramlich 149 rule-macro policy operatesto keep nominalGNP growingat some pre- determinedrate.22 Expressed in percentagechanges,

(6) p+y = Z, wherey is the percentagerate of growthof real output and z is the pre- determinedtarget growth for nominal income. For this paper I do not want to get into the questionof whetherthe authoritiesmust take activist policy measuresto keep nominalincome growthat rate z. I assumethat macro authoritiescan follow such a policy, whetheror not the growthof moneyincome is constantautomatically. The other equationrelates cyclical changesin the unemploymentrate to cyclicalchanges in real outputby Okun's3:1 relationship,

(7) y -l-I0. 03 (U -U*), where Y is the level of real output and Y* is that at high employment (U*), assumedto grow at a constanttrend rate. Because the growthof nominalincome will not be alteredin responseto a price shock,the shock will first raise p and lower y in equal amounts,resulting in a temporary rise in unemploymentby equation7. This unemploymentwill gradually curb the inflation,actually leading in the intermediaterun to some over- shooting and a reductionin the inflationrate relative to the level prior to the shock. The lower inflationthen will lead to higher GNP growth, lower unemployment,and so forth. The process will oscillate to a point at which unemploymentreturns to its natural rate, GNP grows at its long-runrate, and the inflationaryimpact of the shock dies out. The main problemwith the constantgrowth strategy is that the cycles in unemploymentmay be excessivelylong. Becauseprices and wages re- spond sluggishlyto utilizationchanges in this model, cyclical unemploy- mentpersists until the inflationrate declinessufficiently to restorethe real growthrate, whichmay take some years.Particularly when an accommo- dative policy is optimal,it should be feasible for policy to improvethe constantgrowth outcome. The way to do this would be to introducea laggedfeedback rule, under which the growthof nominalincome is set by

(8) p + y =z - ) -).

22. As stated in Gordon, "Alternative Responses of Policy to External Supply Shocks." 150 BrookingsPapers on Economic Activity, 1:1979 When there is underutilizationin the previousperiod, [(Y/Y*) - 1] 1 is less than zero, and the growth of nominal income is raised by some fraction X. In this way, persistentcycles in unemploymentcan be com- bated, though at the cost of a slower rate of decline of the inflationrate from the initialpost-shock level.

Assessmentof AlternativeResponse Strategies

In this section I use the model describedabove to estimatethe social costs of variouspolicies of responseto shocks.Above I showedthat, under a set of simplifyingassumptions, accommodative policies will in general be preferred:here the approachis to tally up the social costs to measure the marginof superiority,and to observehow this marginchanges if some of the simplifyingassumptions are relaxed. The basic approachis to simulate the model in the presence of an assumedprice shock. Because it is easier to understandthe resultsif the systemis in an optimumposition before the shock, I try to place it there. Using the revealedpreference assumption and my model preciselyas esti- mated,this preshockequilibrium would be a weightedunemployment rate of 4.1 percent (5.8 percentofficial rate for 1978). If the trade-offwere really vanishing,even thoughmy estimatesdo not quite suggestthat, the preshockoptimum would be the nonaccelerating-inflationunemployment rate-the NAIRU-of 4.5 percent.There is obviouslynot a large differ- ence betweenthe two, but for the sake of argumentI followed the natural rate rule and chose the preshockequilibrium of 4.5 percent.At that point the impliedvalue of b in my estimatedmodel is 2.4 (when relativechanges in crudematerials prices are exogenous). The resultsare based on comparisonsof the model simulatedwith 1978 historicalvalues, a control simulationin which the prices of crudemate- rials are assumedto be stable, and a set of experimentalsimulations in which the prices of crudematerials are assumedto rise by 10 percentin year 1, with follow-on shocks as dictated by the serial correlationas- sumption.Macro policy is assumedto respondaccording to each of four strategies:complete accommodation, with U remainingat its "optimum" value of 4.5 percent throughout;the lagged feedback nominal income growth policy (equation 8); the strategy of constant nominal income growth (equation 6); and complete extinguishingof the shock-induced inflationover a three-yearperiod. EdwardM. Gramlich 151 In each case I computethe differencebetween experimental and con- trol simulationvalues for the rate of inflationand unemploymentand the discountedsum over an infinitehorizon. Three discountrates are tried: zero, as if society's stake in either preservingthe value of the dollar or avoiding unemploymentwere as strong tomorrow as it is today; the "goldenrule" rate of 3 percent;and 6 percent,arbitrarily higher than the golden rule rate to approximatewhat mightbe the real marginalproduct of . One could also argue (just for inflation) that if any shock- createdinflation is capitalizedin future contracts,it entails lower social costs in the future or, effectively,a higher discountrate. The firstset of resultsis given in table 4. Here no serial correlationof the priceincrease of materialsis assumedand the coefficientsof the model are taken as estimatedin equations 1' and 2'. Columns 1 and 2 show the resultswhen the inflationaryshock is completelyaccommodated: the initialimpetus declines sharply at first,but afteryear 4 decays at a much slower rate (a5a3 + a2 from equation 3b). The cumulated sum of inflation impactsin this case is 3.29 for the one-timeincrease in materialsprices of 10 percent. In columns 3 and 4 at least some rise in unemploymentis allowed,and the inflationaryimpact is less. The closest to the accommo- dation strategyis the lagged feedback strategy (with X = 1): here the nominalgrowth in incomeis adjustedto eliminateutilization gaps in pre- vious years, and some reductionoccurs in cumulatedinflation and some increasein cumulatedunemployment. The strict constantgrowth rule is shownin columns5 and 6, featuringa relativelyabrupt decline of inflation but unemploymentthat persists well past the firstfive years.The complete extinguishingor "coldturkey" strategy shown in columns7 and 8 is even more extreme: simply letting unemploymentrise the requisite amount to eliminatethe inflationover a three-yearperiod. The cumulativeunem- ploymentin that strategyis less than that in the constantnominal income strategybecause inflation is not allowedto be incorporatedinto .23 The social costs impliedby variousstrategies appear at the bottom of the table. If b = 2.4, as would be impliedby my price-wageequations if the startingpoint were an optimum,it can be seen thatthe accommodative strategyis indeed superior.The social costs that accompanythe shock are only slightlyhigher in the lagged feedbackpolicy, but they approxi- matelydouble in the strategiesin columns7 and 8. 23. This is the same principle that is illustrated in Gramlich, "Timing of Unem- ployment in a Recession." 9 .0 :Z) 11.1 Iz" t tn ON 11:41 4 Cd ON 00 00 C; C; C; cri Cd

5 en en en 00 O O t'- 00 00 C; C; C; C; C; -o 0 4) 0 Cld4-1-C,3 Cd cld -a Cd ?: o

> Jz! 4., .5 C) 1.0r- 00 4-1 0 cn cn b-0 C;C; C; a) C's co v) .zz -4-b 0 Cld 00 .7t: U4 r 06 0 M C) coo V--4 00 cn >1 00 Cf) C14 0 0 4j C; C; C; C; C; C; C; C; Po

& >1 U -4 1-4 4-1 0 4-4 -0 0 44 Cld 4-1 \.O 0 4-r C; C; C; C; C; c; c; 0 cj 4., Cld Cd 10 00 11) cq A. CIS W 0 C C's -57 AO a 4-1 0 C's b,6 CN tn te) r- ON \10 o oo en .- o 9 4-1 C) 00 C.)11) oo o N r. 0 'o' C) C; C; C; C; 4 .-O.1 .24-1 R. u Cd WC13

r. 4-1 4-1 0 4-1 pa >, 4-1 4-1 4-10 0 0. 4-' 4-1 Clda 4., Cld U 0 tu 10C.,10 I.. 0 (1)> 0 10 0 0 E 0 Q 4-4 cd 't 4., 4., 41 C C C 0 o u.5 u C's cd tn en 00 ON "-4 0 6 C'd 0 4-1 ".SC's U C; C; C; C C 0 0 0.4.1 9 V> 8r Cld x Ct . 4-1 0 a 'a Cd 0 -l'- 'n 6 -C,S C,S -u 0 o 0 O.Z ow t. 2 C.) 4-1 0 0 4- Z CIS 10 Cld en \10 4- 00co'S 4 4 0.) O O 0 0 Z 4-1 4- 4- 4-1CW 0 0 0 - C,3 c; c; C 0 -0 Cd L. L. 4- 0 11) 4-1 -0 Izi r. 0 u9 9 4 Cd U. W-H "9-;u 0 cd k; -0 cn Cd 0. 0 44 Cd EdwardM. Gramlich 153 The bottom two lines of the table then conduct sensitivitytests on b, using values of 1.4 and 3.4, respectively.The low value of b obviously impliesthat before the shock the economyshould have been operatingat a higherunemployment rate to be optimal (assumingmy model is cor- rect), and at a lower ratefor the highervalue of b. In the formercase, the accommodativepolicy is no longer optimal,though it is still to be pre- ferred over the nonaccommodationstrategies. In the latter case, with a high b, the marginof superiorityof the accommodationstrategy is much greater.Among the lesser conclusions,the lagged feedbackrule appears to be a reasonablereal worldproxy for a perhapsinfeasible strict accom- modationstrategy, and the cold turkeystrategy always outperformsthat of constantnominal growth. If unemploymentis to rise, it is best to take the increasequickly. The next set of simulationsin table 5 is aimed at introducingsome technical issues into these calculations. Columns 1 through 4 assume some serialcorrelation of shocks,with a one-periodautoregressive scheme and a coefficientof 0.5 (similarto equation3-2 in table 3). For simplicity, only the extremeaccommodation and extinguishingpolicies are shown. When the shock is accommodated,it can be seen that shock-induced inflationpersists much longer, addingto a cumulatedsum nearlytwice as large as that in table 4. But because of the nonlinearityin the ,unemployment must rise more than twice as much as it did in the simulationsof table4 to extinguishthe shock. Columns5 through8 in table 5 move in the other direction.For these the serial correlationis removedand the price-wagefeedback coefficient (from equation1') is loweredto 0.1 1-its valuewhen price controldum- mies are used in the wage change equation-with the difference (0.32 - 0.1 1) addedto the wage-wagefeedback coefficient. In this case the in- flationaryimpact of the shockvanishes much more quickly, and the cumu- lativesum of inflationis cut by about 15 percent;and, againbecause of the nonlinearityof the Phillips curve, the cumulativesum of unemployment necessaryto extinguishthe shock is cut almost in half. In this case the strategyof immediatelyextinguishing the shock narrowlysurpasses ac- commodation when b = 1.4. These simulationsthen generallyconfirm the superiorityof accommo- dationstrategies. When the systemis assumedto be neara social optimum before the shock, and under the assumptionthat my model is correct, accommodationstrategies generally entail about half the social cost of CC 0 O O O

N ll-r 00 00 0 C) 0 t-- 00 00

C; C; C; C; C; C; C; C;

P

bo

cri

cd

to cd Cd tn tn :Z) cli cli C4 q cl tn C) en N tn "-.4 e4.) en "-.4 T--4 00 en 0 0 C; C; C; C; C el c-I 0 0 'o

(U 0 L

0 O O O 00 No 4-4 0 V) C14 tn tn W) 0 0.0 4 -4 -j VCL .1cii 0U) u W cl 1-4 j ;. .(2 cq 40-4 Cd tn cn 0

0 v> 110) 0 C) -o IT O cl en 0 0 4-4 C; C; C; C; C; -0 0

o cli o C13u 0;:., VZ X 0 C'3cc 0 Cl a0. 0 w CD .1 40.

tr; if; tr; r. Im 0

tn 0% 00 vi V WI ;i l) W; -C,3ow I-o rA CD C) CD 0 CD a ., tj Z cl w 0 P, Xi cq 0 .0 U 0 0 o o 0 co"W.- C, 4) .0 0 bD,d o 4: C,3 0 0 cl O O C; C-q Q'a c3 cq rA p

C14 cn 'Irt tn (Z) Z 44 < " u 0 . . cg C.) (A co 4 0 .6 EdwardM. Gramlich 155 nonaccommodationstrategies. If these assumptionsare relaxed and b is allowedto take on highervalues, this marginof superioritywidens. And even when b is allowedto take on lower values, as if the economyshould have had a higher unemploymentrate all along, the accommodation strategy still compares rather favorably with the nonaccommodation strategies.

The Game-of-StrategyView

An importantpotential defect in the foregoingestimation and simula- tion approachfor analyzingresponses to price shocks is that it ignores feedbackfrom the economic environmentto the coefficientsthemselves. As a consequence,the standardsimulation approach may vastlyoverstate the social costs of a nonaccommodatingpolicy because it ignoresimpor- tant informationabout governmentintentions. One articulationof this idea is implicitin Fellner'sgame-of-strategy view of the inflationprocess.24 In this view any past inflationdata are generatedin an environmentchar- acterizedby a set of measuredvariables (unemployment rates and so on) and unmeasuredvariables, such as the perceived view of the private sectoron how seriousthe governmentis aboutdisinflation. If the govern- ment were known to be lax in fightinginfla-tion, private wage and price setterswould not reduce wage or price inflationmuch when unemploy- ment hit-they would wait out the period of unemploymentwith what appearstatistically as sluggishwages and prices. If, on the other hand, they knew that the governmentmeant business about fightinginflation, they would fear losses of and sales from holding to their sluggish wages and prices,and they would reduceinflation more quickly. The mainpractical relevance of Fellner'spoint today lies in the transi- tional unemploymentcosts of curing an entrenchedinflation: will those costs be small (with Fellner's backbone) or large (as predictedby a standardmodel such as the one I have estimated)?But the same point also has implicationsfor the responseto shocks: the governmentcannot afford to be accommodativebecause that would destroy its inflation- fighting credibility.If everyone knew that the governmentwould not accommodateshocks, the private sector would not pass them through for the same reason it would not maintainsluggish price and wage re- 24. William Fellner, Towards a Reconstruction of Macroeconomics. 156 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1979 sponses. Moreover, accommodatingany shock opens up a brave new worldin which the governmentcan rationalizeany inflationby calling it a shock. Finally, accommodationof positive shocks, even if offset by aggregatedemand reductionsfollowing negative price shocks, will be inflationaryon averageif more adverseshocks occur than favorableones (for example,it is normalwhen Iran is producingoil at full capacity,a shockwhen that productionis below). At the verbal level, I think, little disagreementwould arise with the proposition that expectations of the likely governmentmacro policy response to movementsin unemploymentand inflation are potentially importantin influencingthe price and wage change curves. This is pre- sumably why some adherentsof the standardmodel emphasize wage standards,guideposts, and the like. But going from this view to a knowl- edge of exactly how standardmodels of the inflationaryprocess must be modifiedto deal with the phenomenonis a far more difficultstep. In his 1977 article, Fellner himself adjusts the standardmodel in a ratherarbitrary way. His point of departureis Cagan'sempirical model of the inflationprocess, a close cousin of the standardmodel with three exceptions.Cagan does not disaggregatethe process into separateequa- tions for wages and prices, assumesthat the model is accelerationistin the long run, fits a parameterrepresenting the speed of adjustmentof inflationaryexpectations, and describesthe short-runtrade-off relation- ship as linear.25Rather than measuringthe degreeof accelerationand the speed of adjustmentof expectations,as in the standardmodel, the Cagan model constrainsthe former and estimates only the latter. When the standardmodel is nearly accelerationist,as most are, the propertiesof both models become similar,though as an empiricalmatter Cagan does find a greaterslope of the short-runPhillips curve than occurs in most standardmodels. To allowfor a credibleanti-inflationary strategy, Fellner adjustsCagan's model by arbitrarilydoubling the speed of adjustmentof expectations,cutting approximatelyin half the cumulativeunemploy- ment cost necessaryto cure inflation.If this procedurewere applied to the unemploymentimpacts of nonaccommodativepolicies in the simula- tions of table 4, those impacts might similarlybe cut in half, greatly reducingthe marginof superiorityof the accommodatingstrategies. If, on the otherhand, the policy were accommodative,it would demonstrate

25. Cagan, "The Reduction of Inflation,"and William Fellner, "Guide to the Vol- ume," in Fellner, ed., Contemporary Econiomic Problems, pp. 15-52 and 1-14, respectively. EdwardM. Gramlich 157 customarylaxity and no adjustmentswould be needed in the calculated socialcosts. To see whether Fellner has a point in scaling down the costs of a nonaccommodativepolicy, I first examine the econometricevidence a little more carefully and then discuss an apparentlyignored political aspect of the problem. Regarding the econometric evidence, Fellner himself shows great disdainabout any econometricevidence taken from periods of policy laxity. But laxity, credibility,and backbone are not mutuallyexclusive concepts-the government,after all, has alwaysmen- tioned the goal of ,and the government'sactions are suffi- ciently randomthat some price and wage settersmust have believed the governmentwould follow this goal, at least in some past periods. Any recession,and particularlythose before inflationaccelerated in the mid- sixties, might thereforebe taken as evidence of a governmentresolve to fight inflation (or an inabilityto stop cyclical unemployment).If this is so, the standardmodel shouldoverpredict price and wage increasesin all those in which governmentinflation-fighting resolve is per- ceived and underpredictwhen it is not. Because the standardinflation modeldescribed above fits the sameshort-run slope to cyclicalmovements in the weightedunemployment rate, this test then involves comparingin- flationresiduals in the earlyresolve period with the later accommodation period. Theseresiduals in the fiverecession years in the 1954-77 sampleperiod are given in table 6. The actual unemploymentpeak in the 1970-71 periodwas in 1971, but becausethat year was complicatedby the price- wage freeze, I used 1970 instead. Column 1 shows the wage-inflation residualsfrom equation 1'; column 2, the price-inflationresiduals from equation2'; column3, the priceresiduals corrected for deviationsin com- pensationfrom averagehourly earningsand in the CPI from the non- farm deflator;and column4, the simultaneoussolution for the corrected price-equationresiduals, as if I had calculateda dynamicsimulation of the modelbeginning in the recessionyear.26

26. The corrections are necessary because the compensation index is stochasti- cally related to average hourly earnings, and consumer prices are similarly related to the nonfarm business deflator.I am interestedin the residual for the nonfarm deflator as a function of gross compensation. The equation in note 13 gives pn,= ao + al(w2 + r1) + a2pc, where r1 is the residual of the equation relating rates of change of compensation to average hourly earnings. If p = pn,+ r2, with r2 as the residual relating inflation rates, p = ao + a,(w + rl) + a2Pc + r2. The correction then in- volves subtractingoa1r1 + r2 from the p residual. 158 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1979 Table 6. Residualsfrom the StandardInflation Model in RecessionYears, 1954-75% Percentagepoints Correctedp Sinigle Simultaneous w p equation solution Year (1) (2) (3) (4) 1954 -0.6 -0.9 0.2 -0.2 1958 -0.5 0.2 -0.3 -0.7 1961 -0. 1 -0.3 -0.5 -0.6 1970 -0.2 1.1 -0.3 -0.4 1975 0.6 -1.0 -0.3 0.1 Source: Text equations 1' and 2'. a. The wage, w, and price, p, variables used in the equations are the percentage rate of change in ad- justed average hourly earnings and the , respectively. The residuals in column I are from text equLation1' and in column 2, from text equation 2'. Column 3 corrects the residuals in column 2 for deviations in compensation from average hourly earnings and the CPI from the nonfarm deflator, as deseribed in the text, note 26. Column 4 presents corrected residuals from a simnultaneoussolution for the price equation residuals, as though a dynamic of the model was conducted beginning in the recession year.

The wage-equationresiduals in the first three recessions are indeed negative,indicating some overpredictionof wagegrowth in theseinflation- resolve periods. These residuals are small relative to the equation's standarderror, averagingless than one-half a standarddeviation, but sufficientlygreat that they doublethe short-runslope of the Phillipscurve (averaging0.4 for 1.5 percentagepoints of unemployment).The idea also works in the latter two "nonresolve"recessions, underpredictingwage changesby an averageof 0.2 percentagepoint. The illustrationis perhaps particularlystrong in the 1975 recession,when the governmentpromised an expeditiousreturn to full employmentthroughout. Hence thereis some evidencefrom these residualson wage changesthat resolve matters. The signalsfrom the price equationare less clear. Using the residuals from column 3, which are correctedfor randomblips in the relationship betweenthe CPI and the nonfarmdeflator and betweengross compensa- tion and averagehourly earnings,the price equation is found to over- predictin two of the three early recessions,and both the later ones. The averageoverprediction in the early recessionsis 0.2, again small relative to the equation'sstandard error and the residualcorrections, but not very small relative to the flat short-runslope of the Phillips curve. When I put these correctedresiduals together with the wage residualsby solving the model simultaneously,the result is an averageoverprediction in the early recessionsof 0.5. Enormousuncertainties exist in all of this, but if a large share of the overpredictioncan be attributedto Fellner'spoint, EdwardM. Gramlich 159 his procedureof arbitrarilydoubling the short-runslope of the Phillips curveturns out to be a reasonableway to correctthe estimates.Adding these adjustmentsto the simulationsof table 4 would indeed approxi- matelycut in half all impliedfigures of cyclicalunemployment cost on the rightside of the table. Turningfrom this econometrictest to a morebasic discussion,the idea thatprivate price and wage settershave some idea of how the government will deal with inflationand unemploymentis not new and has been dis- cussedmany times in both a favorableand an unfavorablelight. Without repeatingall the points that have been made, I would like to highlight one other aspect of the theory,which to my knowledgehas not received extensivediscussion. The generalpoint of view of any kind of credibility model of the inflationprocess is a divergenceof interestsof the public and private sector. The private sector has one objective (raising wages or prices) and the governmenthas another (holding them down). This sets up the bargaining-perceptionsituation that Fellner emphasizes: if the privatesector feels the governmenthas a stronghand, it can be bluffed into less inflationarycontracts by the fear of anticipatedunemployment once the governmentplays its cards. But there are at least three distinct problemswith the view: -The view hinges on the assumptionthat estimatedco- efficientsof short-runPhillips curves will change,a necessarilyspeculative assertion.If they do not, or do not change much, the temporaryunem- ploymentcost may force officialsto abandonthe strategyand returnto highemployment. Horizon-If the temporaryunemployment required to root out in- flation lasts past the next election, elected officials may not implement policies that improvethe nation'swelfare (essentiallythe problemof the political ). In effect, the interestrate relevantfor the offi- cials is far higherthan the ratesused in tables 4 and 5. Interestgroups-Even if the medianvoter were convincedthat some temporaryunemployment was necessaryto cureinflation, strong pressure groupsmay be able to defeat such a policy. As a case in point, George Meany'sapparent response to PresidentCarter's new religionabout fight- ing inflationseems more likely to change the identity of the President thanthe bargainingstrategy of the unions. These criticismsare not necessarilydevastating to Fellner'sargument becausethey do not deal with the question:who is to be blamedif private 160 BrookingsPapers on Economic Activity, 1:1979 price and wage settersdo not believe or accept the government'sresolve in fightinginflation, and if their actions lead to high unemployment?If somehowthe governmentcan establisha above the fray, it may not be forced to take responsibilityfor the high unemployment-which followed logically from private actions and from the fact that nobody took the governmentseriously. But here the Keynesiantradition gets in the way. After three decadesof economists'proclaiming that unemploy- ment is not inevitableand can be cured by governmentmacro policies, it will now be difficultfor economiststo state that unemploymentis the fault of the private sector. More realistically,the governmentwill be blamed for high unemployment,just as it often takes credit for high employment. It then becomesdifficult to know how seriouslyto take Fellner'sobjec- tion to the standardmodel, and my objectionsto his objection.Today it is true that the percent of respondentswho answerthat inflationis the nation's most importantproblem is rising daily-as my regressionsin tables 1 and 2 predict-and this should give electedofficials new resolve in theirfight against inflation. Perhaps price and wage settersin the econ- omy will perceivethis and respondto expectedunemployment with more restraintthan they appearto displayin responseto actualunemployment. But as soon as unemploymentrises, the same regressionspredict that voterswill then begin to fear unemploymentalso, and that is likely to sap the resolve of officialsand leave us with the same old lax policies and the sameold flat short-runtrade-off curve. In this sense,the ultimateobstacle to acceptingthe empiricalrelevance of Fellner's argumentmay be the seeminglyinnocuous coefficient of cyclical unemploymentin the Gallup poll regressions.Price-setting and wage-settingbehavior might not be in- flationaryif sufficientresolve were shown. But can that ever happenin a democracywhere people fear unemploymenttoo, begin to worryabout it once it startsrising, and may evenblame it on the government?

RationalExpectations

Fellner'sinflation-fighting credibility plays the role of a variableomitted fromstandard econometric models whose presence would alter the results. A morefundamental restructuring of the standardmodel has been under- takenby Lucas, Sargentand Wallace,Barro, and others of the rational EdwardM. Gramlich 161 expectationsschool.27 In this section I examine how a rationalexpecta- tions model treatsresponses to price shocks. I begin with three caveats. The first is that the model used here is a somewhatgeneralized version used by Fischer, of which the pure rationalexpectations model is a special case.28Fischer's model assumes that price and wage setters make rational expectations forecastswhen they sign theirprice-wage contracts, but that once signed, these contractsfix wages and prices over some horizon.29If the contract period is short relative to the inside informationlag of the ,the pure rationalexpectations result emerges and the optimal rule for monetarypolicy is simplyto let the money supplygrow at a con- stantrate even if policy is concernedwith minimizing the varianceof cycli- cal unemployment.But if the contractperiod is long relativeto the inside lag of the monetaryauthority, the modelbecomes more Keynesianand the authorityshould respondto shocks in a way that reflectsits view of the social costs of unanticipatedinflation and cyclical unemployment. The second caveataddresses the typesof pricesincorporated in rational expectationsmodels. All such modelsexplain cyclical unemployment as a negativefunction of errorsin forecastingprices: if prices and wages are lowerthan anticipated,firms and labor temporarily supply less outputand unemploymenttemporarily rises aboveits naturalrate. Implicit in this be- havioris the fact that prices are taken to be the "internal"ones received for sales of and services,rather than pricespaid to exogenoussup- pliers.With a supplyshock operating in the Gordon-Phelpsmanner, how- ever, unemploymentwould increasewhile prices and wages were higher than expected, violating the usual rational expectationsbehavior. The best way aroundthis difficultyis to build a rational expectationsmodel with both internal and external prices, letting temporarydeviations in aggregatesupply dependdifferently on which type of price is incorrectly predicted.I will not do that, but will reinterpretprices in the rationalex-

27. Lucas, "Expectationsand the Neutrality of Money"; Sargent and Wallace, "Rational Expectations";and Barro, "UnanticipatedMoney Growth." 28. , "Long-TermContracts, Rational Expectations,and the Opti- mal Money Supply Rule," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 85 (February 1977), pp. 191-205. 29. Edmund S. Phelps and John B. Taylor have an alternative version of such a model, but it incorporates a whole system and is much more difficultto use. See "StabilizingPowers of Monetary Policy Under Rational Expec- tations," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 85 (February 1977), pp. 163-90. 162 BrookingsPapers on Economic Activity, 1:1979 pectationsmodel as only internalprices, and will discussqualitatively the types of resultsthat should emergefrom such a model. The thirdcaveat deals with the relationshipbetween aggregatesupply and unemployment.The standard rational expectations model treats aggregatesupply as fixed, and has actual output vary around accordingto a set of terms representingunexpected changes in macropolicy and a residual.Because supply is fixedand demand variable, the residualis reallyto be interpretedas a demandshock. But in this paper I am interestedin the properresponse to supply residuals,and for these it is clear that supply-induceddrops in actualoutput will also lower full- employmentoutput in the short run, without directlyraising unemploy- ment. I deal with this by addingan explicit relationshipexplaining cycli- cal unemployment. The modelcan be expressedin threeequations:

(9) Y = Y* + 0.5c,(P - E_1P) + 0.5c,(P - EL2P) + u

(10) Y= c2M-P-v

(11) U- U* = -c3(Y- Y* - u).

Here the operatorE_i refersto the expectationof a variablemade in the ith previous period. Following the usual rational expectationsconven- tions, the entiremodel is in log form and all variables(except the unem- ploymentrates) are expressedthat way. Equation9 is the modifiedaggre- gate supply equationof Lucas, where Y* is definedas the fixed normal long-termlevel of outputand P is definedas the internalprice level. Devi- ations in actual outputfrom Y* are made a positive functionof misfore- casts in internal prices in t - 1 and t - 2, with the c1 coefficient giving the implied short-termelasticity. I have formulatedthe model as if all con- tractslasted for two years,so the 0.5 coefficientsreflect the proportionsof price and wage contracts signed in each year, which incorporatethat year'sexpectations about internalprices. Equation 10 is an aggregatedemand equation that is here made mone- taristfor simplicity;it would be possible to includefiscal variablesin 10, but that would add complexitywithout leading to any additionalinsights on how policy should react.Equation 11 then expressesthe link between aggregatesupply and the cyclicalunemployment rate, U - U* (not in log form). Percentagerises in Y above Y* will make cyclicalunemployment negativeaccording to the coefficientof Okun'slaw, c3. EdwardM. Gramlich 163 The influenceof price shocks of varioussorts can then be describedin termsof the u and v residuals.Take firstthe Gordon-Phelpssupply shock wherefarm outputis abruptlylowered by a crop failure.This entersthe model as a direct reductionin Y, or a negativeu. Its direct influenceon cyclicalunemployment is neutralizedby includingu in equation 11. But there will be an indirectinfluence on both unemploymentand internal pricelevels workingthrough the v term.If spendingdemands for farmout- put are price inelastic,the negativeu will raise the money income of the farmsector, raise transactions needs for that sector,and thusimply a posi- tive v. If the FederalReserve does not accommodatethese transactions surprises,the negative u must thus lower internal price levels through equation10. A secondtype of priceshock could be a pureprice disturbance,such as a rise in the price of internationallytraded goods. This type of shock will have no direct influenceon real output (u = 0), but if the demandfor importsis price inelastic,it will again raise the transactionsdemand for money, and imply that v > 0, thus tendingto lower internalprices for a given M. Finally, there could be a shock that lowers outputwithout any directeffect on internalprices, say with a dropin productivityor a strike. In this case outputis down, u < 0, but thereis no directeffect on velocity and v is equalto zero. The model can be solved by substitutingequations 9 and 10 together to solve for P, taking expectations,and insertingthe calculatedexpres- sions for (P - E1P) and (P - E2P) back into the expression for Y. The reduced-formequation for Y becomes

(12) Y = Y* + O.5u - O.5civ + 1 - 0.5c [c2(M - E_1M)

+ (1 + cl)c2(M - E_2M) + EU1(u+ v) + (1 + cl)E-2(u + v)]. This expressioncan thenbe insertedinto 10 and 11 to obtainthe reduced- form expressionfor internalprice levels and unemployment.It has the standardrational expectations that real output equals its trend value, with a series of stochasticterms that were impossibleto forecast when price and wage contractswere set, and with two termsreferring to surprisesin monetarypolicy. If the had a one-period inside lag and all contractshad been signedin the previousyear (all E-2 terms are absent), only unanticipatedmonetary changes could influence real output-the most well-knownrational expectationsresult. But as 164 BrookingsPapers on Economic Activity, 1:1979 Fischershowed, if the inside lag is one period and some contractslast for two periods, it is possible even for systematic monetary changes to stabilizeoutput. Macroor monetarypolicy is introducedin the model by writinga reac- tion functionfor the FederalReserve. Assuming again that it has a one- periodinside lag, it can set monetarypolicy only on the basis of informa- tion fromthe previousperiod. If thereis no serialcorrelation of residuals, even this is impossiblebecause it has no informationabout the present period. But if there is serial correlation,an equationexpressing the be- haviorof the FederalReserve is

(13) M = M* + c4u-1 + cv-1,

whereM* is a predeterminedtrend amount and the c4 and c5 coefficients determinein generalhow the FederalReserve should respondto shocks. Using anotherbasic assumption of rationalexpectations, the privatesector can be assumedto know both the FederalReserve's reaction coefficients and all the informationit has;no residualmonetary surprises are assumed. The model can be solved by substituting13 into 12 and minimizing some loss function of the policymaker.The loss function minimizedby Fischerdepended simply on the varianceof Y aroundY*, but to preserve the spiritof this paper,I shouldmake it dependon U and also includean inflationterm. At that point, some of the simplificationsI have made to adjustto the rationalexpectations model becometroublesome. One prob- lem is that the rationalexpectations loss functionincludes only unantici- pated inflationrates (P - E2P) because all anticipatedinflation has al- ready been adjustedfor in previous price and wage contracts and is thereforecostless (an assumptionthat does not squarewith my survey resultsdescribed above). Anotherserious problem is that the price levels that enterthe rationalexpectations model are only internalprices, and any externalinflation is thereforealso viewed as costless. This makesno logi- cal sense, so I will not presenta formal optimalpolicy exercise.But it is possible to determinequalitatively how macro policy should respondto shocksin the rationalmodel. The simplestcase is that of a purequantity disturbance, such as a dip in .In this case u is less than zero, but unemploymentdoes not rise (equation 11). There is no direct effect on internalprices (v = 0), but as a result of the drop in Y, too much money is chasing too few goods and internalprices are bid up, temporarilylowering unemployment EdwardM. Gramlich 165 throughthe aggregatesupply expression. If the FederalReserve did noth- ing, inflationwould be up and unemploymentdown, and both signals would suggestthat monetarypolicy ought to tighten.The implicationof such a strategywould be similar to the immediaterecession, or cold turkey,policy describedfor the standardmodel. Next, take the case of a pure price disturbance,such as a rise in prices of importswith inelastic demand. As was said above, v is positiveand u is zero in such a case. The pureprice disturbanceraises the overallinflation rate but, because of the positive v, internalprices will be lowered and unemploymentraised. The optimalmonetary response here depends on that greatunknown, the social cost of unemploymentversus that of infla- tion. For low b values,the FederalReserve will tightenor not accommo- date;for high b values it will accommodatethis type of shock. If the loss functionwere written solely in termsof internalinflation rates, the Federal Reservewould unambiguouslyaccommodate this shock, showingexactly whythat approach is not fruitful. The last case of a supplyshock is the Gordon-Phelpscrop failure,the one withwhich the paperbegan. Because u changesalong with v, this case appearsto be differentfrom the pureprice disturbance,but in fact it is not. The reasonis that the u changeis neutralizedin the unemploymentequa- tion, implyingno initial rise in unemployment.While it is true that Y drops,as in the case of the quantitydisturbance, the fact that demandfor farmproducts is price inelasticassures that internalprices will also drop, andthat unemployment will eventuallyrise by this indirectchannel. Hence in this case, as in the standardmodel, the shock will temporarilyincrease both overall inflationrates and unemploymentrates, and again put the FederalReserve in the dilemmait has had throughoutthe paper. It will either accommodatethe shock or not, dependingon its view of the rela- tive cost of unemploymentversus that of inflation. At this level, then, the rationalexpectations responses look much the same as those impliedby the standardmodel. One new featureemerges: If the FederalReserve's inside lag is long relativeto the contractperiod, it should not do anythingat all. But otherwise the Federal Reserve will have to choose between inflationand unemploymentin the same tradi- tional way. The main differencebetween the rationalexpectations model and the standardmodel is not in the directionof the macro policy re- sponse,but in differencesin social costs amongthe variouspolicies. In the standardmodel the differencesbetween various policies can in- 166 BrookingsPapers on Economic Activity, 1:1979 volve substantialamounts of inflationor unemployment,persisting over a substantiallength of time. But in the rationalmodel these differences,and indeed the social costs of a shock, are negligible: as soon as last year's roundof wage contractshas lapsed, expectationsbecome rationalagain and past price shocks become irrelevantin determiningfuture levels of bothoutput and prices.

Implications

Perhapsthe most importantresult of this examinationof supplyprice shocksin the standardmodel is that whateverthe macroresponse, shocks are very costly. If their unemploymentimpact is minimizedby accom- modatingpolicies, the shock-inducedinflation can lingerfor severalyears. If their inflationaryimpact is minimizedby an immediaterecession, the cost in terms of high unemploymentis sizable. Various intermediateap- proaches are possible, but all result in some combinationof persistent unemployment,persistent inflation, or both. If nothingelse, this drama- tizes the need for policies other than macro responsesto minimizeprice shocks. But it may be that such policies cannot be designed,and that macro authoritieswill have to live with exogenousprice shocks.Then the choice of macro policy responsesto shocks cannot easily be divorcedfrom the questionof wherethe economyshould have been beforethe shock.It can be shown theoreticallythat in a simplemodel in which the policymaking horizonis infinite,the parametersof both the behavioralmodel and the social loss functionare constant,and optimalitywas initiallyachieved, it will be optimalfor policy to accommodatethe shock and preventthe un- employmentrate from changing.Because there appearsto be little evi- dence of shifts eitherin behavioralor social loss coefficients,that model may be a reasonablefirst approximationto reality.Accommodation pol- icies are thus likely to be less costly, thoughby marginsthat vary from small to large underdifferent interpretations of the marginalsocial costs of unemploymentand inflation.