Ec100 Economics a Microeconomics Michaelmas Term 2017/18 Alan Manning

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Ec100 Economics a Microeconomics Michaelmas Term 2017/18 Alan Manning Ec100 Economics A Microeconomics Michaelmas Term 2017/18 Alan Manning Contact details: Lecturer, Alan Manning, [email protected] Course Manager, Roberto Sormani, [email protected] Although I have tried to make sure these notes are clear and without error, there is always room for improvement. Please email corrections or suggested improvements to me or Roberto. Contents Page 1. Introduction 5 1.1 use of these notes 5 1.2 what is economics? 5 1.3 Markets 7 1.4 The Hockey Stick of History 9 1.5 Specialization and Exchange 10 1.6 Innovation and Exchange 10 1.7 Distribution and inequality 12 1.8 Economics as a science 13 1.9 Controversy in economics: positive and normative questions 14 2. A Simple Model of a Market 15 2.1 Economists and Models 15 2.2 A stylized Model of a market 15 2.2.1 Demand, supply and price 15 2.2.2 The market‐clearing price 16 2.2.3 Do prices always clear markets? 19 2.3 Comparative statics 19 2.3.1 A shift in the demand curve 20 2.3.2 A shift in the supply curve 20 2.3.3 The price elasticity of demand and supply 22 2.4 Bubbles 23 3. Are Market Outcomes Good or Bad 27 3.1 The Gains from Trade, absolute and comparative advantage 27 3.2 Free trade agreements 30 3.3 Uber 31 3.4 The Case for Markets, Consumer and Producer Surplus 31 3.5 Central Planning 34 3.6 The Sources of Market Failure 39 3.6.1 Equity Considerations 39 3.6.2 Market Pathologies 40 3.7 Wider Impacts of Markets on Attitudes 42 3.8 Conclusion 43 4. Household Behaviour 44 4.1 Consumer demand 44 4.1.1 The budget constraint 44 4.1.2 Indifference curves 45 4.1.3 Combining indifference curves and the budget constraint 48 4.2 Comparative statics 49 4.2.1 A change in income: the income effect 49 4.2.2 A change in prices: the substitution effect 50 4.3 Incentives 53 4.4 Labour Supply 53 4.4.1 Preferences and budget constraint 53 4.4.2 A change in non‐labour income 55 4.4.3 A change in wages 56 4.4.4 Application: the top rate of income tax 57 4.4.5 Application: helping the poor 57 5. Firms: Production and Prices 60 5.1 What do firms do? 60 5.2 Pricing 60 5.2.1 The revenue function, average revenue and marginal revenue 60 2 5.2.2 The cost function, average cost and marginal cost 63 5.2.3 Returns to scale 64 5.2.4 Profit maximization 66 5.2.5 Comparative statics: a change in costs 68 5.2.6 Entry and exit 68 5.2.7 Comparative statics: a change in demand 69 5.2.8 The mark‐up 71 5.3 Market Structure 72 5.3.1 Factors affecting the demand curve for a firm’s products 72 5.3.2 Forms of market structure 72 5.3.3 The sources of monopoly 72 5.3.4 Oligopoly 73 5.3.5 Monopolistic competition 74 5.3.6 Perfect competition 76 5.3.7 A normative comparison of market structures 79 5.4 Price Discrimination 81 6. Firms: Costs, Factor Demands and Innovation 83 6.1 The production function 83 6.1.1 average product and marginal product 83 6.1.2 Isoquants 84 6.1.3 Substitutes and complements in production 85 6.2 Cost minimization 86 6.2.1 Iso‐cost Curves 87 6.2.2 Changing the relative price of inputs: the substitution effect 88 6.3 The scale effect 89 6.4 Combining substitution and scale effects: factor demand curves 90 6.5 Application: The Labour Market Impact of Immigration 91 6.6 Application: the Employment Effect of a Minimum Wage 92 6.7 The sources of pay differentials 92 6.8 Monopsony 94 6.9 The Gender pay gap and the Equal Pay Act 95 6.10 The impact of a minimum wage in a Monopsonistic Labour Market 96 6.11 The impact of new technology on the demand for labour 98 6.12 Innovation 101 7. Inequality and Redistribution 104 7.1 Pen’s People’s Parade 104 7.2 Measuring Inequality: Lorentz Curves and Gini Coefficients 106 7.3 Variation in Income Inequality Across Countries and Over Time 107 7.4 The sources of income inequality 111 7.5 Redistribution 112 7.5.1 Why does redistribution exist? 114 7.5.2 Designing redistribution 115 7.5.3 Average and marginal tax rates 116 7.5.4 Universal Basic Income 118 7.6 The rise in the income shares of the top 1% 120 3 8. Externalities, public goods and common resources 127 8.1 What is an externality? 127 8.2 Why externalities are a source of market failure? 127 8.3 Policies for externalities 128 8.3.1 Markets and property rights 128 8.3.2 Taxes and subsidies 129 8.3.3 Regulation 130 8.3.4 Cap‐and trade: carbon markets 131 8.4 A typology of goods 132 8.5 Public goods 133 8.6 Common pool resources 134 9. Information and Markets 137 9.1 Asymmetric Information 137 9.2 The market for Lemons 137 9.3 Adverse selection 138 9.3.1 Health insurance 139 9.3.2 Interbank markets in the financial crisis 139 9.3.3 Bank runs 140 9.4 Moral Hazard 141 9.5 Application: Illegal online drugs markets 141 10. Conclusion 144 4 1. INTRODUCTION (Acemoglu, Laibson, List, Chapters 1 and 2) 1.1 Use of These Notes These notes are intended as ‘skeleton notes’ to explain what I say in the lectures and to follow, more or less, the structure of the lectures. They are intended to help students with understanding the overall structure of the course and as a bridge between the lectures and the textbook and other books. They are not intended as a substitute for the use of the textbook, Acemoglu, Laibson and List which provides explanations of the concepts in greater depth than these notes. 1.2 What is Economics? Perhaps the most famous definition of economics is due to Lionel Robbins, who was an LSE professor and has the library building named after him. He defined economics as “the science which studies human behaviour as a relationship between ends and scarce means which have alternative uses”. There are several elements of this and we will discuss them in turn but let’s start with the last part. Saying we have scarce means is saying that we don’t have unlimited resources available to us so that we have to make choices about the way in which we use those resources. We cannot get everything that we would like so we have to prioritise. In the words of another LSE alumnus, Mick Jagger, “you can’t always get what you want”. This part of Robbins’ definition can be used to justify a very wide definition of economics. You have one vote, and several political parties competing for that vote, so you have to choose which party to vote for. In most societies you can marry just one person so you have to make a choice about who your spouse is going to be. These topics are not the traditional subject matter of economics. Something closer to traditional economics is the choice you make about what to spend your limited income on. But, there are people calling themselves economists writing about topics which seem closer to political science or sociology or some other social science. However we will not be discussing these applications of “economics” in this course. Choices are necessary because people have limited resources relative to their desires. The general approach that economics takes to understanding people’s choices is that individuals weigh up the costs and benefits of different courses of action and the choose the one that they think offers the greatest benefits relative to costs. We will see lots of examples of this later on in the course. One implication of this is that people are likely to respond to incentives, by which I mean that if you alter the costs and benefits of different actions you are likely to alter people’s behaviour. If the benefit from one course of action rises, people are more likely to take that course of action. A focus on incentives is a key part of the way in which economists think about many issues as we will see later on in the course. I have emphasised how Robbins’ definition of economics can be interpreted in a very broad way to encompass most if not all of the decisions that people have to make. But there is another sense in which Robbins’ definition is very narrow. If you are alone on a desert island with limited resources, you will have to make choices about what to do with those resources. Should you use the wood to build a fire to try and attract passing ships, or should you build a shelter against the storms? But you are just an isolated individual on your desert island and the decisions that you make affect no‐one but yourself. But most of the decisions that we make affect others, not just ourselves. We are much more interested in the interactions between people, something not mentioned at all in Robbins’ definition. 5 Humans are social animals and have always lived in groups, interacting with each other.
Recommended publications
  • Michael Amior and Alan Manning the Persistence of Local Joblessness
    Michael Amior and Alan Manning The persistence of local joblessness Article (Accepted version) (Refereed) Original citation: Amior, Michael and Manning, Alan (2017) The persistence of local joblessness. American Economic Review. ISSN 0002-8282 © 2018 American Economic Association This version available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/86558/ Available in LSE Research Online: January 2018 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright © and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. This document is the author’s final accepted version of the journal article. There may be differences between this version and the published version. You are advised to consult the publisher’s version if you wish to cite from it. The Persistence of Local Joblessness By Michael Amior and Alan Manning∗ Differences in employment-population ratios across US commut- ing zones have persisted for many decades. We claim these dispar- ities represent real gaps in economic opportunity for individuals of fixed characteristics. These gaps persist despite a strong migratory response, and we attribute this to high persistence in labor demand shocks. These trends generate a \race" between local employment and population: population always lags behind employment, yield- ing persistent deviations in employment rates.
    [Show full text]
  • Minimum Wages and Employment: a Case Study of the Fast-Food Industry in New Jersey and Pennsylvania
    Minimum Wages and Employment: A Case Study of the Fast-Food Industry in New Jersey and Pennsylvania On April 1, 1992, New Jersey's minimum wage rose from $4.25 to $5.05 per hour. To evaluate the impact of the law we surveyed 410 fast-food restaurants in New Jersey and eastern Pennsylvania before and after the rise. Comparisons of employment growth at stores in New Jersey and Pennsylvania (where the minimum wage was constant) provide simple estimates of the effect of the higher minimum wage. We also compare employment changes at stores in New Jersey that were initially paying high wages (above $5) to the changes at lower-wage stores. We find no indication that the rise in the minimum wage reduced employment. (JEL 530, 523) How do employers in a low-wage labor cent studies that rely on a similar compara- market respond to an increase in the mini- tive methodology have failed to detect a mum wage? The prediction from conven- negative employment effect of higher mini- tional economic theory is unambiguous: a mum wages. Analyses of the 1990-1991 in- rise in the minimum wage leads perfectly creases in the federal minimum wage competitive employers to cut employment (Lawrence F. Katz and Krueger, 1992; Card, (George J. Stigler, 1946). Although studies 1992a) and of an earlier increase in the in the 1970's based on aggregate teenage minimum wage in California (Card, 1992b) employment rates usually confirmed this find no adverse employment impact. A study prediction,' earlier studies based on com- of minimum-wage floors in Britain (Stephen parisons of employment at affected and un- Machin and Alan Manning, 1994) reaches a affected establishments often did not (e.g., similar conclusion.
    [Show full text]
  • Privatization and the Decline of Labour's Share
    Privatization and the Decline of Labour’s Share: International Evidence from Network Industries Ghazala Azmat,AlanManning†and John Van Reenen‡ January 2011 Abstract Some authors have suggested that the deregulation of product and labour markets is responsible for the decline in labour’s share of GDP. A simple model predicts that privatization is associated with a lower labour share, due to job shedding. We test this hypothesis by focusing on privatization of network industries in the OECD. We find that, on average, privatization accounts for a fifth of the fall of labour’s share and over half in Britain and France. The e§ect is due to lower employment, but it is partially o§set by higher wages and falling barriers to entry, which dampen profit margins. JEL classification: E25, E22, E24, L32, L33, J30 Keywords: Labor share, Wages, Privatization, Entry Regulation. Universitat Pompeu Fabra and Barcelona GSE. Address: Department of Economics and Business, Uni- versity Pompeu Fabra, Ramon Trias Fargas 25-27, 08005 Barcelona, Spain. Email: [email protected]. Tel.: +34-93542-1757. †London School of Economics and Centre for Economic Performance. Address: Centre for Economic Performance, LSE, Houghton Street, London WC2A 2AE, UK. Email: [email protected]. Tel: +44(0)20- 7955-6078. ‡London School of Economics and Centre for Economic Performance, NBER and CEPR. Address: Centre for Economic Performance, LSE, Houghton Street, London WC2A 2AE, UK. Email: [email protected]. Tel: +44(0)20 7955 6976 1 INTRODUCTION Capitalists are grabbing a rising share of national income at the expense of workers1.
    [Show full text]
  • LOUSY and LOVELY JOBS: the RISING POLARIZATION of WORK in BRITAIN Maarten Goos and Alan Manning*
    LOUSY AND LOVELY JOBS: THE RISING POLARIZATION OF WORK IN BRITAIN Maarten Goos and Alan Manning* Abstract—This paper shows that the United Kingdom since 1975 has The basic idea is the following. The SBTC hypothesis exhibited a pattern of job polarization with rises in employment shares in the highest- and lowest-wage occupations. This is not entirely consistent predicts that demand for “skilled” jobs is rising relative to with the idea of skill-biased technical change as a hypothesis about the that for “unskilled” jobs, while the ALM hypothesis sug- impact of technology on the labor market. We argue that the “routiniza- gests a more subtle impact of technology on the demand for tion” hypothesis recently proposed by Autor, Levy, and Murnane (2003) is a better explanation of job polarization, though other factors may also be labor of different skills. The routine tasks in which technol- important. We show that job polarization can explain one-third of the rise ogy can substitute for human labor include jobs like craft in the log(50/10) wage differential and one-half of the rise in the log(90/ manual jobs and bookkeeping jobs that require precision 50). and, hence, were never the least-paid jobs in the labor market. The nonroutine tasks which are complementary to I. Introduction technology include skilled professional and managerial jobs that tend to be in the upper part of the wage distribution. The CONOMISTS writing about the impact of technology nonroutine manual tasks that make up many of the most Eon the labor market in recent years have tended to unskilled jobs such as cleaning are not directly affected by emphasize the role played by skill-biased technical change technology, but the impact of technology in other parts of (SBTC), the idea that technology is biased in favor of the economy is likely to lead to a rise in employment in skilled workers and against unskilled workers.
    [Show full text]
  • The Fall of the Labor Share and the Rise of Superstar Firms∗
    The Fall of the Labor Share and the Rise of Superstar Firms∗ David Autor, MIT and NBER David Dorn, University of Zurich and CEPR Lawrence F. Katz, Harvard University and NBER Christina Patterson, Chicago Booth and NBER John Van Reenen, MIT and NBER October 2019 Quarterly Journal of Economics, Forthcoming Abstract The fall of labor's share of GDP in the United States and many other countries in recent decades is well documented but its causes remain uncertain. Existing empirical assessments typically rely on industry or macro data, obscuring heterogeneity among firms. In this paper, we analyze micro panel data from the U.S. Economic Census since 1982 and document empirical patterns to assess a new interpretation of the fall in the labor share based on the rise of \superstar firms.” If globalization or technological changes push sales towards the most productive firms in each industry, product market concentration will rise as industries become increasingly dominated by superstar firms, which have high markups and a low labor share of value-added. We empirically assess seven predictions of this hypothesis: (i) industry sales will increasingly concentrate in a small number of firms; (ii) industries where concentration rises most will have the largest declines in the labor share; (iii) the fall in the labor share will be driven largely by reallocation rather than a fall in the unweighted mean labor share across all firms; (iv) the between-firm reallocation component of the fall in the labor share will be greatest in the sectors with the largest increases in market concentration; (v) the industries that are becoming more concentrated will exhibit faster growth of productivity; (vi) the aggregate markup will rise more than the typical firm’s markup; and (vii) these patterns should be observed not only in U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Monopsony in Motion: Imperfect Competition in Labour Markets
    Monopsony in Motion: Imperfect Competition in Labour Markets Alan Manning Chapter 1 Introduction Introduction What happens if an employer cuts the wage they pay their workers by one cent? Much of labour economics is built on the assumption that all existing workers immediately leave the firm as that is the implication of the assumption of perfect competition in the labour market. In such a situation an employer faces a market wage for each type of labour determined by forces beyond their control at which any number of these workers can be hired but any attempt to pay a lower wage will result in the complete inability to hire any of them at all. The labour supply curve facing the firm is infinitely elastic. In contrast this book is based on two assumptions about the labour market. They can be stated very simply: S there are important frictions in the labour market S employers set wages The implications of these assumptions can also be stated simply. The existence of frictions means that there are generally rents to jobs i.e if an employer and worker are forcibly separated one or, more commonly, both of the parties would be made worse-off. This gives employers some market power over their workers as a small wage cut will no longer induce them to leave the firm. The assumption that employers set wages then tells us that employers exercise this market power. But, with these two assumptions, it is monopsony not perfect competition that is the best simple model to describe the decision problem facing an individual employer.
    [Show full text]
  • Reservation Wages and the Wage Flexibility Puzzle
    IZA DP No. 9717 Reservation Wages and the Wage Flexibility Puzzle Felix Koenig Alan Manning Barbara Petrongolo February 2016 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor Reservation Wages and the Wage Flexibility Puzzle Felix Koenig London School of Economics and CEP-LSE Alan Manning London School of Economics and CEP-LSE Barbara Petrongolo Queen Mary University London, CEP-LSE and IZA Discussion Paper No. 9717 February 2016 IZA P.O. Box 7240 53072 Bonn Germany Phone: +49-228-3894-0 Fax: +49-228-3894-180 E-mail: [email protected] Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published in this series may include views on policy, but the institute itself takes no institutional policy positions. The IZA research network is committed to the IZA Guiding Principles of Research Integrity. The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Bonn is a local and virtual international research center and a place of communication between science, politics and business. IZA is an independent nonprofit organization supported by Deutsche Post Foundation. The center is associated with the University of Bonn and offers a stimulating research environment through its international network, workshops and conferences, data service, project support, research visits and doctoral program. IZA engages in (i) original and internationally competitive research in all fields of labor economics, (ii) development of policy concepts, and (iii) dissemination of research results and concepts to the interested public. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion.
    [Show full text]
  • Full Issue Download
    The Journal of The Journal of Economic Perspectives Economic Perspectives The Journal of Winter 2021, Volume 35, Number 1 Economic Perspectives Symposia Minimum Wage Alan Manning, “The Elusive Employment Effect of the Minimum Wage” Arindrajit Dube and Attila Lindner, “City Limits: What Do Local-Area Minimum Wages Do?” Jeffrey Clemens, “How Do Firms Respond to Minimum Wage Increases? Understanding the Relevance of Non-Employment Margins” Price V. Fishback and Andrew J. Seltzer, “The Rise of American Minimum Wages, 1912–1968” A journal of the Polarization in Courts American Economic Association Adam Bonica and Maya Sen, “Estimating Judicial Ideology” Daniel Hemel, “Can Structural Changes Fix the Supreme Court?” Economics of Higher Education 35, Number 1 Winter 2021 Volume David Figlio and Morton Schapiro, “Stafng the Higher Education Classroom” John Bound, Breno Braga, Gaurav Khanna, and Sarah Turner, “The Globalization of Postsecondary Education: The Role of International Students in the US Higher Education System” W. Bentley MacLeod and Miguel Urquiola, “Why Does the United States Have the Best Research Universities? Incentives, Resources, and Virtuous Circles” Articles Florian Scheuer and Joel Slemrod, “Taxing Our Wealth” Daron Acemoglu, “Melissa Dell: Winner of the 2020 Clark Medal” Recommendations for Further Reading Winter 2021 The American Economic Association The Journal of Correspondence relating to advertising, busi- Founded in 1885 ness matters, permission to quote, or change Economic Perspectives of address should be sent to the AEA business EXECUTIVE COMMITTEE office: [email protected]. Street ad- Elected Officers and Members A journal of the American Economic Association dress: American Economic Association, 2014 Broadway, Suite 305, Nashville, TN 37203.
    [Show full text]
  • Minimum Wages and Firm Profitability
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MINIMUM WAGES AND FIRM PROFITABILITY Mirko Draca Stephen Machin John Van Reenen Working Paper 13996 http://www.nber.org/papers/w13996 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 May 2008 We would like to thank Charles Brown, Alan Manning, Steve Pischke, the Editor, two anonymous referees and participants at seminars in the Low Pay Commission, LSE, the Society of Labour Economists conference in Boston and the Department of Work and Pensions conference at the University of York for a number of helpful comments. The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. © 2008 by Mirko Draca, Stephen Machin, and John Van Reenen. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Minimum Wages and Firm Profitability Mirko Draca, Stephen Machin, and John Van Reenen NBER Working Paper No. 13996 May 2008 JEL No. J23,L25 ABSTRACT Although there is a large literature on the economic effects of minimum wages on labour market outcomes (especially employment), there is much less evidence on their impact on firm performance. In this paper we consider a very under-studied area - the impact of minimum wages on firm profitability. The analysis exploits the changes induced by the introduction of a national minimum wage to the UK labour market in 1999, using pre-policy information on the distribution of wages to construct treatment and comparison groups and implement a difference in differences approach.
    [Show full text]
  • Download File Elusive-Employment-Effect-Working-Paper
    Washington Center 1500 K Street NW, Suite 850 for Equitable Growth Washington, DC 20005 Working paper series The Elusive Employment Effect of the Minimum Wage Alan Manning June 2016 http://equitablegrowth.org/the-elusive-employment-effect-of-the-minimum-wage/ ©2016 by Alan Manning All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. The Elusive Employment Effect of the Minimum Wage Alan Manning Centre for Economic Performance London School of Economics May 2016 Abstract There is a huge body of empirical research on the employment effect of the minimum wage that has failed to clearly demonstrate the negative effect that so many economists strongly believe to find. This paper reviews the reasons for this and argues that the literature needs to re­focus to further our knowledge on the topic. I would like to thank James Bishop, Jeff Borland, Arin Dube, Stephanie Koo, David Mare, and particularly Vincenzo Scrutinio, for help with this paper 1 Introduction It is over 25 years since Charlie Brown invited readers of the Journal of Economic Perspectives to think about the question ’Minimum Wage Laws: Are They Over-rated?’ with the final sentence “the minimum wage is over-rated by its critics as well as its supporters” (p144) (Brown, 1988). At the time, there was a strong academic consensus that the minimum wage caused job losses, was not well-targeted on those it set out to help, and dominated by other policies to help the poor like the EITC.
    [Show full text]
  • Explaining Job Polarization: Routine-Biased Technological Change and Offshoring
    Explaining Job Polarization: Routine-Biased Technological Change and Offshoring By MAARTEN GOOS,ALAN MANNING AND ANNA SALOMONS This paper documents the pervasiveness of job polarization in 16 West- ern European countries over the period 1993-2010. It then develops and estimates a framework to explain job polarization using routine- biased technological change and offshoring. This model can explain much of both total job polarization and the split into within-industry and between-industry components (JEL: J21, J23, J24) The ‘Skill-Biased Technological Change’ hypothesis (SBTC) – see Autor and Katz (1999), Goldin and Katz (2008, 2009) and Acemoglu and Autor (2011) for excellent overviews – arose from the observation that demand is shifting in favor of more ed- ucated workers. In spite of its success in explaining many decades of data, however, SBTC cannot explain the recent phenomenon of job polarization as documented by Au- tor, Katz and Kearney (2006, 2008) and Autor and Dorn (2013) for the US and Goos and Manning (2007) for the UK. Job polarization has also been documented for Germany (Spitz-Oener 2006; Dustmann, Ludsteck and Schönberg 2009) and there are indications it is pervasive in European countries (Goos, Manning and Salomons 2009; Michaels, Natraj and Van Reenen 2013). The first contribution of this paper is to show that job polarization is pervasive across advanced economies by showing it holds in 16 Western- European countries. The main hypotheses put forward to explain job polarization are that recent technologi- cal change is biased towards replacing labor in routine tasks (what we call routine-biased technological change, RBTC) and that there is task offshoring (itself partially influenced by technological change), and that both of these forces decrease the demand for middling relative to high-skilled and low-skilled occupations (Autor, Levy and Murnane 2003; Au- tor, Katz and Kearney 2006, 2008; Goos and Manning 2007; Autor and Dorn 2013).
    [Show full text]
  • Explaining Job Polarization in Europe: the Roles of Technology, Globalization and Institutions Maarten Goos, Alan Manning and Anna Salomons
    ISSN 2042-2695 CEP Discussion Paper No 1026 November 2010 Explaining Job Polarization in Europe: The Roles of Technology, Globalization and Institutions Maarten Goos, Alan Manning and Anna Salomons Abstract This paper shows the employment structure of 16 European countries has been polarizing in recent years with the employment shares of managers, professionals and low-paid personal services workers increasing at the expense of the employment shares of middling manufacturing and routine office workers. To explain this job polarization, the paper develops and estimates a simple model to capture the effects of technology, globalization, institutions and product demand effects on the demand for different occupations. The results suggest that the routinization hypothesis of Autor, Levy and Murnane (2003) is the single most important factor behind the observed shifts in employment structure. We find some evidence for offshoring to explain job polarization although its impact is much smaller. We also find that shifts in product demand are acting to attenuate the polarizing impact of routinization and that differences or changes in wage-setting institutions play little role in explaining job polarization in Europe. JEL Classifications: J21, J23, J24 Keywords: Labor Demand, Technology, Globalization, Institutions This paper was produced as part of the Centre’s Labour Markets Programme. The Centre for Economic Performance is financed by the Economic and Social Research Council. Acknowledgements We thank David Autor, David Dorn, Francis Green, Thomas Lemieux, Stephen Machin, Guy Michaels, John Van Reenen and numerous seminar participants for excellent suggestions. Maarten Goos is an Assistant Professor in the Department of Economics, Catholic University of Leuven, Belgium.
    [Show full text]