Jump-Diffusion Models

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Jump-Diffusion Models Jump-Diffusion Models where F is the risk-neutral jump distribution. The jump compensator is then given by Jump-diffusion (JD) models are particular cases of Z exponential L´evymodels in which the frequency of µJ = −λ ξ F (dξ) jumps is finite. They can be considered as pro- totypes for a large class of more complex models To simplify the presentation, we henceforth assume such as the stochastic volatility plus jumps model zero dividends so thatµ ^ = r, the risk-free rate. of Bates [1]. Consider a market with a riskless asset (the Characteristic Function bond) and one risky asset (the stock) whose price Define the forward price F := S er T . If x := at time t is denoted by St. In a JD model, the SDE 0 t for the stock price is given as log St=F ) is a L´evyprocess, its characteristic func- iuxT tion φT (u) := E e has the L´evy-Khintchine dSt = µ St− dt + σ St− dZt + St− dJt (1) representation n 2 2 2 where Zt is a Brownian motion and φT (u) = exp i u (µJ − σ =2) T − u σ =2 T Z N iuξ o Xt +T e − 1 ν(ξ) dξ : (3) Jt = Yi i=1 Typical assumptions for the distribution of jump is a compound Poisson process where the jump sizes sizes are: normal as in the original paper by Merton Y are independent and identically distributed with [6] and double-exponential as in Kou [4]. In the i Merton model, the L´evydensity ν(·) is given by distribution F and the number of jumps Nt is a Poisson process with jump intensity λ. The as- λ (ξ − α)2 ν(ξ) = p exp − set price St thus follows geometric Brownian mo- 2 π δ 2 δ2 tion between jumps. Monte Carlo simulation of the process can be carried out by first simulating where α is the mean of the log-jump size log J and δ the standard deviation of jumps. This leads to the number of jumps Nt, the jump times, and then simulating geometric Brownian motion on intervals the explicit characteristic function between jump times. 1 φ (u) = exp i u ! T − u2 σ2 T The SDE (1) has the exact solution: T 2 2 2 2 St = S0 exp µ t + σ Zt − σ t=2 + Jt (2) +λ T ei u α−u δ =2 − 1 Merton [6] considers the case where the jump sizes In the double-exponential case Yi are normally distributed. −α+ ξ −α− ξ ν(ξ) = λ p α+ e 1ξ≥0 + (1 − p) α− e 1ξ<0 Risk-neutral drift where α+ and α− are the expected positive and If the above model is used as a pricing model, the negative jump sizes respectively and p is the rela- drift µ in (1) is given by the risk-neutral driftµ ^ tive probability of a positive jump. This gives the explicit characteristic function plus a jump compensator µJ : 1 φ (u) = exp i u ! T − u2 σ2 T µ =µ ^ + µJ T 2 p 1 − p To identify µJ , taking expectations of equation (1) +λ T − and from the definition ofµ ^, α+ − i u α− + i u with E[dSt] =µ ^ St dt = µ St dt 1 p 1 − p Z ! = − α2 − λ − +λ ξ F (dξ) St dt 2 α+ + 1 α− − 1 1 Pricing of European options with p Given a characteristic function, European call op- log(S=K) + r T σ T d1 = p + ; tions can be priced using Fourier methods as in σ T 2 Lewis [5]: p log(S=K) + r T σ T d2 = p − ; C(S; K; T ) σ T 2 p 1 Z 1 du = e−r T F − FK 2 1 Jump to Ruin π 0 u + 4 Yi In the case where e = 0 with probability 1, µJ = −iuk ×Re e φT (u − i=2) (4) λ and equation (6) simplifies to −λ T λ T where the log-strike k := log (K=F ). C(S; K; T ) = e CBS(S e ; K; r; σ; T ) (7) which is the Black-Scholes formula with a shifted Valuation equation interest rate r ! r + λ. This special case of the Assuming the process (1), and a constant risk-free JD model where the stock price jumps to zero (or rate r, and further supposing that the market is ruin) whenever there is a jump, is the simplest pos- complete, the value V (S; t) of a European-style op- sible model of default. Equation (7) for the option tion satisfies: price in the jump-to-ruin model may also be derived from a Black-Scholes style replication argument us- @V 1 @2V @V Z ing stock and bonds of the issuer of the stock; upon + σ2 S2 + r S − r V + λ F (dξ) @t 2 @S2 @S default of the issuer, both stock and bonds jump to n @V o zero. The cost of funding stock with bonds of the V (S eξ; t) − V (S; t) − eξ − 1 S = 0 @S issuer is r + λ in this picture, which explains the (5)simple form (7) of the solution. where for ease of notation, V denotes V (S; t). Local volatility Equation (5) is a partial integro-differential equa- tion (PIDE) which can be solved using finite differ- There is a particulary simple expression for Dupire ence methods [2]. local volatility in the jump-to-ruin model. It is given by Gatheral [3] A Valuation Formula for European Options p 2 2 N(d2) σloc(K; T ; S) = σ + 2 λ σ T 0 Merton [6] derived an exact solution of the valua- N (d2) tion equation (5) for a European-style call option with p with strike K and time-to-expiration T which has log(S=K) + λ T σ T the form of an infinite sum of Black-Scholes-like d2 = p − ; σ T 2 terms: As K ! 1, d2 ! −∞ and the correction term 1 X e−λ T (λ T )n Z vanishes, and as K ! 0, the correction term ex- C(S; K; T ) = F (dξ) n! n plodes. In addition, as the hazard rate λ increases, n=0 so does d2, increasing local volatility for low strikes ξ µJ T × CBS(S e e ; K; r; σ; T ) K relative to high strikes. (6) where Fn is the distribution of the sum of n in- dependent jumps and CBS(·) denotes the Black- Scholes solution, which is given as −r T CBS(S; K; r; σ; T ) = SN(d1) − K e N(d2) 2 Normally distributed jumps [5] Lewis, A.L. (2000) Option Valuation under Stochastic Volatility with Mathematica Code, Fi- Merton [6] also shows that if jumps are normally nance Press, Newport Beach, CA. distributed with Y ∼ N(α; δ), equation (6) again i [6] Merton, R.C. (1976) Option pricing when un- simplifies considerably to give derlying stock returns are discontinuous. J. Finan- C(S; K; T ) cial Economics 3, 125{144. 1 0 X e−λ T (λ0 T )n = C (S; K; r ; σ ;T ) n! BS n n n=0 (8) with 2 λ0 = λ eα+δ =2 2 2 2 σn T = σ T + n δ 2 rn T = (r + µJ ) T + n α + δ =2 Each term CBS(S; K; rn; σn;T ) in equation (8) is the value of the option conditional on there being exactly n jumps during its life. Implied volatility smile If there were no jumps in this model, the im- plied volatility smile would be flat. Jumps in the JD stock price process induce an implied volatility smile whose short time limit (see e.g., [3]) is given as @ K σ2 (K; T ) ! −2 µ as T ! 0: @K BS J The greater µJ , because jumps are either more fre- quent or more negatively skewed, the more negative is the implied volatility skew. Jim Gatheral. References [1] Bates, D. (1996) Jumps and stochastic volatility: the exchange rate processes implicit in Deutschemark options. Rev. Fin. Studies 9, 69{ 107. [2] Cont, R. and Voltchkova, E. (2005). A fi- nite difference scheme for option pricing in jump- diffusion and exponential L´evy models, SIAM Journal on Numerical Analysis 43(4), 1596-1626. [3] Gatheral, J. (2006) The Volatility Surface, John Wiley & Sons, Hoboken, Chapter 5. [4] Kou, S. (2002) A jump-diffusion model for op- tion pricing. Management Science 48, 1086{1101. 3.
Recommended publications
  • Numerical Solution of Jump-Diffusion LIBOR Market Models
    Finance Stochast. 7, 1–27 (2003) c Springer-Verlag 2003 Numerical solution of jump-diffusion LIBOR market models Paul Glasserman1, Nicolas Merener2 1 403 Uris Hall, Graduate School of Business, Columbia University, New York, NY 10027, USA (e-mail: [email protected]) 2 Department of Applied Physics and Applied Mathematics, Columbia University, New York, NY 10027, USA (e-mail: [email protected]) Abstract. This paper develops, analyzes, and tests computational procedures for the numerical solution of LIBOR market models with jumps. We consider, in par- ticular, a class of models in which jumps are driven by marked point processes with intensities that depend on the LIBOR rates themselves. While this formulation of- fers some attractive modeling features, it presents a challenge for computational work. As a first step, we therefore show how to reformulate a term structure model driven by marked point processes with suitably bounded state-dependent intensities into one driven by a Poisson random measure. This facilitates the development of discretization schemes because the Poisson random measure can be simulated with- out discretization error. Jumps in LIBOR rates are then thinned from the Poisson random measure using state-dependent thinning probabilities. Because of discon- tinuities inherent to the thinning process, this procedure falls outside the scope of existing convergence results; we provide some theoretical support for our method through a result establishing first and second order convergence of schemes that accommodates thinning but imposes stronger conditions on other problem data. The bias and computational efficiency of various schemes are compared through numerical experiments. Key words: Interest rate models, Monte Carlo simulation, market models, marked point processes JEL Classification: G13, E43 Mathematics Subject Classification (1991): 60G55, 60J75, 65C05, 90A09 The authors thank Professor Steve Kou for helpful comments and discussions.
    [Show full text]
  • A Tree-Based Method to Price American Options in the Heston Model
    The Journal of Computational Finance (1–21) Volume 13/Number 1, Fall 2009 A tree-based method to price American options in the Heston model Michel Vellekoop Financial Engineering Laboratory, University of Twente, PO Box 217, 7500 AE Enschede, The Netherlands; email: [email protected] Hans Nieuwenhuis University of Groningen, Faculty of Economics, PO Box 800, 9700 AV Groningen, The Netherlands; email: [email protected] We develop an algorithm to price American options on assets that follow the stochastic volatility model defined by Heston. We use an approach which is based on a modification of a combined tree for stock prices and volatilities, where the number of nodes grows quadratically in the number of time steps. We show in a number of numerical tests that we get accurate results in a fast manner, and that features which are essential for the practical use of stock option pricing algorithms, such as the incorporation of cash dividends and a term structure of interest rates, can easily be incorporated. 1 INTRODUCTION One of the most popular models for equity option pricing under stochastic volatility is the one defined by Heston (1993): 1 dSt = µSt dt + Vt St dW (1.1) t = − + 2 dVt κ(θ Vt ) dt ω Vt dWt (1.2) In this model for the stock price process S and squared volatility process V the processes W 1 and W 2 are standard Brownian motions that may have a non-zero correlation coefficient ρ, while µ, κ, θ and ω are known strictly positive parameters.
    [Show full text]
  • Local Volatility Modelling
    LOCAL VOLATILITY MODELLING Roel van der Kamp July 13, 2009 A DISSERTATION SUBMITTED FOR THE DEGREE OF Master of Science in Applied Mathematics (Financial Engineering) I have to understand the world, you see. - Richard Philips Feynman Foreword This report serves as a dissertation for the completion of the Master programme in Applied Math- ematics (Financial Engineering) from the University of Twente. The project was devised from the collaboration of the University of Twente with Saen Options BV (during the course of the project Saen Options BV was integrated into AllOptions BV) at whose facilities the project was performed over a period of six months. This research project could not have been performed without the help of others. Most notably I would like to extend my gratitude towards my supervisors: Michel Vellekoop of the University of Twente, Julien Gosme of AllOptions BV and Fran¸coisMyburg of AllOptions BV. They provided me with the theoretical and practical knowledge necessary to perform this research. Their constant guidance, involvement and availability were an essential part of this project. My thanks goes out to Irakli Khomasuridze, who worked beside me for six months on his own project for the same degree. The many discussions I had with him greatly facilitated my progress and made the whole experience much more enjoyable. Finally I would like to thank AllOptions and their staff for making use of their facilities, getting access to their data and assisting me with all practical issues. RvdK Abstract Many different models exist that describe the behaviour of stock prices and are used to value op- tions on such an underlying asset.
    [Show full text]
  • THE BLACK-SCHOLES EQUATION in STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY MODELS 1. Introduction in Financial Mathematics There Are Two Main Approache
    THE BLACK-SCHOLES EQUATION IN STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY MODELS ERIK EKSTROM¨ 1,2 AND JOHAN TYSK2 Abstract. We study the Black-Scholes equation in stochastic volatility models. In particular, we show that the option price is the unique classi- cal solution to a parabolic differential equation with a certain boundary behaviour for vanishing values of the volatility. If the boundary is at- tainable, then this boundary behaviour serves as a boundary condition and guarantees uniqueness in appropriate function spaces. On the other hand, if the boundary is non-attainable, then the boundary behaviour is not needed to guarantee uniqueness, but is nevertheless very useful for instance from a numerical perspective. 1. Introduction In financial mathematics there are two main approaches to the calculation of option prices. Either the price of an option is viewed as a risk-neutral expected value, or it is obtained by solving the Black-Scholes partial differ- ential equation. The connection between these approaches is furnished by the classical Feynman-Kac theorem, which states that a classical solution to a linear parabolic PDE has a stochastic representation in terms of an ex- pected value. In the standard Black-Scholes model, a standard logarithmic change of variables transforms the Black-Scholes equation into an equation with constant coefficients. Since such an equation is covered by standard PDE theory, the existence of a unique classical solution is guaranteed. Con- sequently, the option price given by the risk-neutral expected value is the unique classical solution to the Black-Scholes equation. However, in many situations outside the standard Black-Scholes setting, the pricing equation has degenerate, or too fast growing, coefficients and standard PDE theory does not apply.
    [Show full text]
  • MERTON JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL VERSUS the BLACK and SCHOLES APPROACH for the LOG-RETURNS and VOLATILITY SMILE FITTING Nicola Gugole
    International Journal of Pure and Applied Mathematics Volume 109 No. 3 2016, 719-736 ISSN: 1311-8080 (printed version); ISSN: 1314-3395 (on-line version) url: http://www.ijpam.eu AP doi: 10.12732/ijpam.v109i3.19 ijpam.eu MERTON JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL VERSUS THE BLACK AND SCHOLES APPROACH FOR THE LOG-RETURNS AND VOLATILITY SMILE FITTING Nicola Gugole Department of Computer Science University of Verona Strada le Grazie, 15-37134, Verona, ITALY Abstract: In the present paper we perform a comparison between the standard Black and Scholes model and the Merton jump-diffusion one, from the point of view of the study of the leptokurtic feature of log-returns and also concerning the volatility smile fitting. Provided results are obtained by calibrating on market data and by mean of numerical simulations which clearly show how the jump-diffusion model outperforms the classical geometric Brownian motion approach. AMS Subject Classification: 60H15, 60H35, 91B60, 91G20, 91G60 Key Words: Black and Scholes model, Merton model, stochastic differential equations, log-returns, volatility smile 1. Introduction In the early 1970’s the world of option pricing experienced a great contribu- tion given by the work of Fischer Black and Myron Scholes. They developed a new mathematical model to treat certain financial quantities publishing re- lated results in the article The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities, see [1]. The latter work became soon a reference point in the financial scenario. Received: August 3, 2016 c 2016 Academic Publications, Ltd. Revised: September 16, 2016 url: www.acadpubl.eu Published: September 30, 2016 720 N. Gugole Nowadays, many traders still use the Black and Scholes (BS) model to price as well as to hedge various types of contingent claims.
    [Show full text]
  • Sensitivity Estimation of Sabr Model Via Derivative of Random Variables
    Proceedings of the 2011 Winter Simulation Conference S. Jain, R. R. Creasey, J. Himmelspach, K. P. White, and M. Fu, eds. SENSITIVITY ESTIMATION OF SABR MODEL VIA DERIVATIVE OF RANDOM VARIABLES NAN CHEN YANCHU LIU The Chinese University of Hong Kong 709A William Mong Engineering Building Shatin, N. T., HONG KONG ABSTRACT We derive Monte Carlo simulation estimators to compute option price sensitivities under the SABR stochastic volatility model. As a companion to the exact simulation method developed by Cai, Chen and Song (2011), this paper uses the sensitivity of “vol of vol” as a showcase to demonstrate how to use the pathwise method to obtain unbiased estimators to the price sensitivities under SABR. By appropriately conditioning on the path generated by the volatility, the evolution of the forward price can be represented as noncentral chi-square random variables with stochastic parameters. Combined with the technique of derivative of random variables, we can obtain fast and accurate unbiased estimators for the sensitivities. 1 INTRODUCTION The ubiquitous existence of the volatility smile and skew poses a great challenge to the practice of risk management in fixed and foreign exchange trading desks. In foreign currency option markets, the implied volatility is often relatively lower for at-the-money options and becomes gradually higher as the strike price moves either into the money or out of the money. Traders refer to this stylized pattern as the volatility smile. In the equity and interest rate markets, a typical aspect of the implied volatility, which is also known as the volatility skew, is that it decreases as the strike price increases.
    [Show full text]
  • Implied Volatility Modeling
    Implied Volatility Modeling Sarves Verma, Gunhan Mehmet Ertosun, Wei Wang, Benjamin Ambruster, Kay Giesecke I Introduction Although Black-Scholes formula is very popular among market practitioners, when applied to call and put options, it often reduces to a means of quoting options in terms of another parameter, the implied volatility. Further, the function σ BS TK ),(: ⎯⎯→ σ BS TK ),( t t ………………………………(1) is called the implied volatility surface. Two significant features of the surface is worth mentioning”: a) the non-flat profile of the surface which is often called the ‘smile’or the ‘skew’ suggests that the Black-Scholes formula is inefficient to price options b) the level of implied volatilities changes with time thus deforming it continuously. Since, the black- scholes model fails to model volatility, modeling implied volatility has become an active area of research. At present, volatility is modeled in primarily four different ways which are : a) The stochastic volatility model which assumes a stochastic nature of volatility [1]. The problem with this approach often lies in finding the market price of volatility risk which can’t be observed in the market. b) The deterministic volatility function (DVF) which assumes that volatility is a function of time alone and is completely deterministic [2,3]. This fails because as mentioned before the implied volatility surface changes with time continuously and is unpredictable at a given point of time. Ergo, the lattice model [2] & the Dupire approach [3] often fail[4] c) a factor based approach which assumes that implied volatility can be constructed by forming basis vectors. Further, one can use implied volatility as a mean reverting Ornstein-Ulhenbeck process for estimating implied volatility[5].
    [Show full text]
  • Option Pricing with Jump Diffusion Models
    UNIVERSITY OF PIRAEUS DEPARTMENT OF BANKING AND FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT M. Sc in FINANCIAL ANALYSIS FOR EXECUTIVES Option pricing with jump diffusion models MASTER DISSERTATION BY: SIDERI KALLIOPI: MXAN 1134 SUPERVISOR: SKIADOPOULOS GEORGE EXAMINATION COMMITTEE: CHRISTINA CHRISTOU PITTIS NIKITAS PIRAEUS, FEBRUARY 2013 2 TABLE OF CONTENTS ς ABSTRACT .............................................................................................................................. 3 SECTION 1 INTRODUCTION ................................................................................................ 4 ώ SECTION 2 LITERATURE REVIEW: .................................................................................... 9 ι SECTION 3 DATASET .......................................................................................................... 14 SECTION 4 .............................................................................................................................α 16 4.1 PRICING AND HEDGING IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS ....................................... 16 4.2 CHANGE OF MEASURE ............................................................................................ρ 17 SECTION 5 MERTON’S MODEL .........................................................................................ι 21 5.1 THE FORMULA ........................................................................................................... 21 5.2 PDE APPROACH BY HEDGING ................................................................ε ............... 24 5.3 EFFECT
    [Show full text]
  • The Equity Option Volatility Smile: an Implicit Finite-Difference Approach 5
    The equity option volatility smile: an implicit finite-difference approach 5 The equity option volatility smile: an implicit ®nite-dierence approach Leif B. G. Andersen and Rupert Brotherton-Ratcliffe This paper illustrates how to construct an unconditionally stable finite-difference lattice consistent with the equity option volatility smile. In particular, the paper shows how to extend the method of forward induction on Arrow±Debreu securities to generate local instantaneous volatilities in implicit and semi-implicit (Crank±Nicholson) lattices. The technique developed in the paper provides a highly accurate fit to the entire volatility smile and offers excellent convergence properties and high flexibility of asset- and time-space partitioning. Contrary to standard algorithms based on binomial trees, our approach is well suited to price options with discontinuous payouts (e.g. knock-out and barrier options) and does not suffer from problems arising from negative branch- ing probabilities. 1. INTRODUCTION The Black±Scholes option pricing formula (Black and Scholes 1973, Merton 1973) expresses the value of a European call option on a stock in terms of seven parameters: current time t, current stock price St, option maturity T, strike K, interest rate r, dividend rate , and volatility1 . As the Black±Scholes formula is based on an assumption of stock prices following geometric Brownian motion with constant process parameters, the parameters r, , and are all considered constants independent of the particular terms of the option contract. Of the seven parameters in the Black±Scholes formula, all but the volatility are, in principle, directly observable in the ®nancial market. The volatility can be estimated from historical data or, as is more common, by numerically inverting the Black±Scholes formula to back out the level of Ðthe implied volatilityÐthat is consistent with observed market prices of European options.
    [Show full text]
  • Quantification of the Model Risk in Finance and Related Problems Ismail Laachir
    Quantification of the model risk in finance and related problems Ismail Laachir To cite this version: Ismail Laachir. Quantification of the model risk in finance and related problems. Risk Management [q-fin.RM]. Université de Bretagne Sud, 2015. English. NNT : 2015LORIS375. tel-01305545 HAL Id: tel-01305545 https://tel.archives-ouvertes.fr/tel-01305545 Submitted on 21 Apr 2016 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. ` ´ THESE / UNIVERSITE DE BRETAGNE SUD present´ ee´ par UFR Sciences et Sciences de l’Ing´enieur sous le sceau de l’Universit´eEurop´eennede Bretagne Ismail LAACHIR Pour obtenir le grade de : DOCTEUR DE L’UNIVERSITE´ DE BRETAGNE SUD Unite´ de Mathematiques´ Appliques´ (ENSTA ParisTech) / Mention : STIC Ecole´ Doctorale SICMA Lab-STICC (UBS) Th`esesoutenue le 02 Juillet 2015, Quantification of the model risk in devant la commission d’examen composee´ de : Mme. Monique JEANBLANC Professeur, Universite´ d’Evry´ Val d’Essonne, France / Presidente´ finance and related problems. M. Stefan ANKIRCHNER Professeur, University of Jena, Germany / Rapporteur Mme. Delphine LAUTIER Professeur, Universite´ de Paris Dauphine, France / Rapporteur M. Patrick HENAFF´ Maˆıtre de conferences,´ IAE Paris, France / Examinateur M.
    [Show full text]
  • Empirical Performance of Alternative Option Pricing Models For
    Empirical Performance of Alternative Option Pricing Models for Commodity Futures Options (Very draft: Please do not quote) Gang Chen, Matthew C. Roberts, and Brian Roe¤ Department of Agricultural, Environmental, and Development Economics The Ohio State University 2120 Fy®e Road Columbus, Ohio 43210 Contact: [email protected] Selected Paper prepared for presentation at the American Agricultural Economics Association Annual Meeting, Providence, Rhode Island, July 24-27, 2005 Copyright 2005 by Gang Chen, Matthew C. Roberts, and Brian Boe. All rights reserved. Readers may make verbatim copies of this document for non-commercial purposes by any means, provided that this copyright notice appears on all such copies. ¤Graduate Research Associate, Assistant Professor, and Associate Professor, Department of Agri- cultural, Environmental, and Development Economics, The Ohio State University, Columbus, OH 43210. Empirical Performance of Alternative Option Pricing Models for Commodity Futures Options Abstract The central part of pricing agricultural commodity futures options is to ¯nd appro- priate stochastic process of the underlying assets. The Black's (1976) futures option pricing model laid the foundation for a new era of futures option valuation theory. The geometric Brownian motion assumption girding the Black's model, however, has been regarded as unrealistic in numerous empirical studies. Option pricing models incor- porating discrete jumps and stochastic volatility have been studied extensively in the literature. This study tests the performance of major alternative option pricing models and attempts to ¯nd the appropriate model for pricing commodity futures options. Keywords: futures options, jump-di®usion, option pricing, stochastic volatility, sea- sonality Introduction Proper model for pricing agricultural commodity futures options is crucial to estimating implied volatility and e®ectively hedging in agricultural ¯nancial markets.
    [Show full text]
  • Stochastic Volatility and Black – Scholes Model Evidence of Amman Stock Exchange
    R M B www.irmbrjournal.com June 2017 R International Review of Management and Business Research Vol. 6 Issue.2 I Stochastic Volatility and Black – Scholes Model Evidence of Amman Stock Exchange MOHAMMAD. M. ALALAYA Associate Prof in Economic Methods Al-Hussein Bin Talal University, Collage of Administrative Management and Economics, Ma‟an, Jordan. Email: [email protected] SULIMAN ALKHATAB Professer in Marketing, Al-Hussein Bin Talal University, Collage of Administrative Management and Economics, Ma‟an, Jordan. AHMAD ALMUHTASEB Assistant Prof in Marketing, Al-Hussein Bin Talal University, Collage of Administrative Management and Economics, Ma‟an, Jordan. JIHAD ALAFARJAT Assistant Prof in Management, Al-Hussein Bin Talal University, Collage of Administrative Management and Economics, Ma‟an, Jordan. Abstract This paper makes an attempt to decompose the Black – Scholes into components in Garch option model, and to examine the path of dependence in the terminal stock price distribution of Amman Stock Exchange (ASE), such as Black – Scholes’, the leverage effect in this paper which represents the result of analysis is important to determine the direction of the model bias, a time varying risk, may give fruitful help in explaining the under pricing of traded stock sheers and traded options in ASE. Generally, this study considers various pricing bias related to warrant of strike prices, and observes time to time maturity. The Garch option price does not seem overly sensitive to (a, B1) parameters, or to the time risk premium variance persistence parameter, Ω = a1+B1, heaving on the magnitude of Black –Scholes’ bias of the result of analysis, where the conditional variance bias does not improve in accuracy to justify the model to ASE data.
    [Show full text]