Money, Credit and Velocity

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Money, Credit and Velocity Money, Credit and Velocity MACK Ofl Shakespeare: “Neither borrower, nor a lender he and to examine empirical evidence bearing on their (Hamlet, 1, iii, 75, Polonius to Laertes) purported policy consequences. The analysis pre- Goethe: “Let us live in as small acircle as we will,we are sented in this article does not support the critics’ either debtors or creditors before we have had time to look assertions. This conclusion rests on two arguments. around.” (Elective Affinities, Bk. II, Ch. 4) First, the relation between money and credit requires thatthe amount ofcreditgranted match the anticipated amount ofmoney thatwill be available to settle the debtwhen it comes due. Thus, regulating R.ECENTLY, many critics of monetary policy, the rate ofmonetary growth, which in turn regulates and some monetary policymakers as well, have as- the anticipated future quantity of money, deter- serted that the links between monetary aggregates minesthe amount ofcreditand theconditions under and national economic policy variables—that is, which it is granted. This constraining influence of GNP, inflation and real economic growth—have monetary growth on creditwould be undone only if been severed by a host offinancial andcredit market the relation between money and income growth innovations. If these critics are correct, then a departed from its historical pattern. monetary policy based on targetingthe growth of a monetary aggregate would become increasingly That it has not is the second argument: the em- ineffective and inappropriate, as credit arrange- pirical evidence on velocity, the relation between ments are substituted for monetary payments.1 money growth and income growth, reveals no sig- nificant change during the last two years from its The purpose of this article is to provide a theo- previous history. Consequently, despite recent retical framework in which to assess these claims claims to the contrary, the growth of the monetary aggregates is still reliably linked to the economic variables of interest to policymakers. The author, an associate professor ofeconomics at The Pennsyl- vania State University, isa visiting scholaratthe FederalReserve Bankof St. Louis. ‘For examples, see Neil C. Berkman, “Abandoning Monetary MONEY, CREDIT AND EXCHANGE Aggregates,” in Controlling Monetary Aggregates Jil, pro- ceedings ofaconference sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank In contemporary societies, the exchange of goods of Boston (October 1980), pp. 76-100; Benjamin M. Friedman, is indirect The purchase or sale ofgoods, whether in “The Relative Stability of Money and Credit ‘Velocities’ in the United States: Evidence and SomeSpeculations,” NBER Work- organized markets or through informal arrange- ing PaperNo. 645 (March 1981);Anthony M. Solomon. “Finan- ments, is almost always in exchange for money or cial Innovation and Monetary Policy” (remarks before the Joint money-denominated promises. Direct bartering Luncheon of the American Economic and American Finance Associations, December28, 1981); James M. Tobin, “Inflation,” of one good for another is either nonexistent or in Encyclopedia of Economics, Douglas Creenwald, ed. unimportant (McGraw-Hill, 1982), pp. 510-23. Forthe contraryposition—i.e., that monetary policy should be undertaken through effective The reason for this is at once obvious, yet theo- control ofa monetary aggregate—see Milton Friedman, “Mone- retically challenging to elucidate. In the intro- tar~’Policy: Theoryand Practice ,“foun,al ofMoney, Credit and duction to his book, Theory of Money, Jurg Banking (February 1982), pp. 98-118; and Allan H. Meltzer, The Robert H. Rasche, Stephen H. Axilrod, and Peter Sternlight, Niehans observes: “Money, Credit, and Banking Debate: Is theFederal Reserve s Monetary Control Policy Misdirected?” Journal of Money, Economists (and laymen) have always felt that the Credit and Banking (February 1982), pp. 119-47. use ofa medium of exchange increases the efficiency 21 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS MAY 1982 ofan economy. The gain was usually considered tohe tam s what NI ilton Friecimain characterizes as large. it hats both qualitative and quantitive aspects. temporary abodes of purchasing power that are The qnaliative aspects appear when monetary ex- reatdilv convertible at low cost into an exchange change is compared with barter. Classical and nec)— medium .~ classical economists were graphic in describing the double coincidence of wants of the hungry tailor and the shivering baker which would he necessary for Second, if the purchase of tlte good to be financed an e xchalt go ill a I~arte r eco nout van cI the narrow by the proceeds front the sale of another good pre- limitations it imposes on the division of lahor. The cedes the sale of that other good, then the anticipated use of’ us oncy wool cI increase cc-el hue by freeing future sale proceeds may he used to ntediate the exchange from the shackles of the double coinci’- 2 earlier purchase. Of cotuse, an exchange arrange- dence of wants. ment like this is a fitmiliar part of modern economies; such purchases are said to he macic “on credit.’’ Robert Clower succinctly summarized the results Credit is granted b sellers or other third party of these advantages as imposing a constraint on ‘the lenders to buyers precisely on the basis of the exchange process: ‘ Money buys goods and goods buyers anticipattecl future receipts (with the lender buy money; but goods do not bny goods.’’~In other concurring) and, of course, is measured in utonetary words, it is the nature of a system of monetary ex- units. As a consequence. credit is as much of a change to replace the cumbersome barter exchange medium of exchange as is money-.8 of goods with two non—synchronized monetized exchanges: at sale of goods for money and a later While both credit and money atre used to mediate purchase of goods by money. This exchange attrib- exchainge, they are obviously different entities. The ute in turn has implications for both the appropriate qttautity of money circulating in ant economy is at definition of money and for the monetary- arrange- stock; its units are used repeatedly itt at sequeitce of ments used in exchange.4 exchamges. Credit, on the other hand, is a flow and is transaction—specific; it can only mediate the trains— First, the period between the sale of one good fbr action fkr which it was created.~ money and the subsequent purchase of another good may be long ettonglt or predictable enough to allow t the interim holding of funds in a non—transaction Two good s tISalt are Pc ii ec-t sobs tito tes atre ectsn Ontical Iv tltt’ saltic’ account. This implies that the appropriate monetary good. If two dluraslsle goods are cssstlessly translorosalsle. sloe intts he cstls c-’ r, tlteis tlsc v are pe rfec:t oils sti totes i It ails Ityento i-v - On aggregate may not be narrowly defined money (i.e., tlsis criterion, if the cost of trasnsferrisg funds froloasaviogs Ml), bitt a broader aggregate (e.g., M2) which con- ascc 000 t to a’ dIe itt all id ascd ow) t1 (Sr tts cat rid’ nc-v cv crc’ xc’to. t Iteli, cleat rI v, sasvhtgs scudssiitts wot tIc be eco ‘soiss i call v in cli itin gu is1 able flsno dci I and aicco outs tsr dill-re!)c-v at nd cviso Ici hc’ cxc I saili gr- istccl iat - Cooce rse lv, if th cc cit sts of trat)) STi~cv crc’ proIs il si ti ye1 ~ lasrgc’. sasc-iogs ascconitts would not Its’ at closc’ sohstitote for burg Niebasits, the ?heor o/i/oslc-lf (jtslsits Hopkins University t deinaotcl deposits. llencc’, ass Fniedloaso and Schwasrtz aarglls’, tlsc’ l rcss. 1978), is 2. qnes tict is of cc-I tact in~n c-v is caoti sot be sc ttli’d on an at pri sri I sat s’s. an sert \V. Clow Cr, ‘‘A Recoit siderastisSn of tlt e NI i e rolou it clation 0 ]s sit is as,) c’inparic:as I it’ stion xv it i cIt, iii pairt, dlepc’Id 5 015 liow of Nitti,ctarv The it rv,’’ Ue.s te,l butt it it Jo 01(1? (NI arc’lt 1967). c:o stlv ill te r—dlepOsit trasi n ft. rs a,rd - ~t6. Also, see Karl Brunner and Allan H, Meluer, ‘‘The Uses of °‘l’lsis olsservastion li its I ccl Clocvc’ r ails cI oth cr5 tss as rgtt t’ tIlast sIllnd NI toca N lo isti V iit Ut c Titeon of Ai Exchange Econctits y,’’ A; car— 1 1 IIseal Snrc’ of c-s-cdit tic ~ii/c?~ /ftp or ist c’ of c-red it be’ in c-lu c ccl an t ltd a(~ossEcas ;iis;;i ic Rei - ic Ic (Decent her 1971), pp - 784—805. p0 lit-v ri-I c’vasnt conc:ept of 111011ev: ‘‘for mdlsat pratcticasl l~ NI iI ton Fric’di 0 am and A itI las 5(11w asrtz cI C Sc ri hecl tlt is attn ho te ass poses, ‘ntis rs c’ v’ shcsul cI ht-’ tint sit lc’recI tcs md sidle Iraid e c-ri-cl it ass tlte Se itarati rut of the act of ~torchase f rot it tlte act of sale,’’ hi It well as c-u nt’s d’V a, Ic1 dIe It) sn dl dcc piss its. litsI sc- rt IV. Clocvc’ critic-ired the itt c-cl ~II lit of cxcit ange attproach as Ite fog titi I narrow Tlsecsrc’ticasl F; son dlast sins of Nit ltd tasr>- Pol ic:v,’’ in hissIt’ tc; 5-if 5 to calptsire the essential nature of lnonc’v: T/~c’oojcis~c?Mossetos-sj Pcs?it-sy iii t?sc’ 1970.s, (;ecsrgi- Clasytisu, jcslsn C. Gilbert audI Rohert Seclgccic:k, ecls - (Oxford University Press.
Recommended publications
  • The Origins of Velocity Functions
    The Origins of Velocity Functions Thomas M. Humphrey ike any practical, policy-oriented discipline, monetary economics em- ploys useful concepts long after their prototypes and originators are L forgotten. A case in point is the notion of a velocity function relating money’s rate of turnover to its independent determining variables. Most economists recognize Milton Friedman’s influential 1956 version of the function. Written v = Y/M = v(rb, re,1/PdP/dt, w, Y/P, u), it expresses in- come velocity as a function of bond interest rates, equity yields, expected inflation, wealth, real income, and a catch-all taste-and-technology variable that captures the impact of a myriad of influences on velocity, including degree of monetization, spread of banking, proliferation of money substitutes, devel- opment of cash management practices, confidence in the future stability of the economy and the like. Many also are aware of Irving Fisher’s 1911 transactions velocity func- tion, although few realize that it incorporates most of the same variables as Friedman’s.1 On velocity’s interest rate determinant, Fisher writes: “Each per- son regulates his turnover” to avoid “waste of interest” (1963, p. 152). When rates rise, cashholders “will avoid carrying too much” money thus prompting a rise in velocity. On expected inflation, he says: “When...depreciation is anticipated, there is a tendency among owners of money to spend it speedily . the result being to raise prices by increasing the velocity of circulation” (p. 263). And on real income: “The rich have a higher rate of turnover than the poor. They spend money faster, not only absolutely but relatively to the money they keep on hand.
    [Show full text]
  • Some Answers FE312 Fall 2010 Rahman 1) Suppose the Fed
    Problem Set 7 – Some Answers FE312 Fall 2010 Rahman 1) Suppose the Fed reduces the money supply by 5 percent. a) What happens to the aggregate demand curve? If the Fed reduces the money supply, the aggregate demand curve shifts down. This result is based on the quantity equation MV = PY, which tells us that a decrease in money M leads to a proportionate decrease in nominal output PY (assuming of course that velocity V is fixed). For any given price level P, the level of output Y is lower, and for any given Y, P is lower. b) What happens to the level of output and the price level in the short run and in the long run? In the short run, we assume that the price level is fixed and that the aggregate supply curve is flat. In the short run, output falls but the price level doesn’t change. In the long-run, prices are flexible, and as prices fall over time, the economy returns to full employment. If we assume that velocity is constant, we can quantify the effect of the 5% reduction in the money supply. Recall from Chapter 4 that we can express the quantity equation in terms of percent changes: ΔM/M + ΔV/V = ΔP/P + ΔY/Y We know that in the short run, the price level is fixed. This implies that the percentage change in prices is zero and thus ΔM/M = ΔY/Y. Thus in the short run a 5 percent reduction in the money supply leads to a 5 percent reduction in output.
    [Show full text]
  • Answer Key to Problem Set 4 Fall 2011
    Answer Key to Problem Set 4 Fall 2011 Total: 15 points 1(4 points, 1 point for (a) and 0.5 point for each effect ).a. If the Fed reduces the money supply, then the aggregate demand curve shifts down. This result is based on the quantity equation MV = PY, which tells us that a decrease in money M leads to a proportionate decrease in nominal output PY (assuming that velocity V is fixed). For any given price level P, the level of output Y is lower, and for any given Y, P is lower. b. In the short run, we assume that the price level is fixed and that the aggregate supply curve is flat. In the short run, the leftward shift in the aggregate demand curve leads to a movement such that output falls but the price level doesn’t change. In the long run, prices are flexible. As prices fall, the economy returns to full employment. If we assume that velocity is constant, we can quantify the effect of the 5-percent reduction in the money supply. Recall from Chapter 4 that we can express the quantity equation in terms of percentage changes: %∆ +%∆ =%∆ +%∆ If we assume that velocity is constant, then the %∆ =0.Therefore, %∆ =%∆ +%∆ We know that in the short run, the price level is fixed. This implies that the %∆ =0.Therefore, %∆ =%∆ Based on this equation, we conclude that in the short run a 5-percent reduction in the money supply leads to a 5-percent reduction in output. In the long run we know that prices are flexible and the economy returns to its natural rate of output.
    [Show full text]
  • The Quantity Theory, Inflation, and the Demand for Money
    Quantity Theory, Inflation, and the Demand for Money This lecture examines the link between the quantity theory of money and the demand for money with special emphasis placed on how much the quantity of money demanded is affected by changes in the interest rate. The Classical Quantity Theory of Money A. Velocity of money and the equation of exchange 1. The velocity of money (V) is the average number of times per year that a dollar is spent buying goods and services in the economy , (1) where P×Y is nominal GDP and MS is the nominal money supply. 2. Example: Suppose nominal GDP is $15 trillion and the nominal money supply is $3 trillion, then velocity is $ (2) $ Thus, money turns over an average of five times a year. 3. The equation of exchange relates nominal GDP to the nominal money supply and the velocity of money MS×V = P×Y. (3) 4. The relationship in (3) is nothing more than an identity between money and nominal GDP because it does not tell us whether money or money velocity changes when nominal GDP changes. 5. Determinants of money velocity a. Institutional and technological features of the economy affect money velocity slowly over time. b. Money velocity is reasonably constant in the short run. 6. Money demand (MD) a. Lets divide both sides of (3) by V MS = (1/V)×P×Y. (4) b. In the money market, MS = MD in equilibrium. If we set k = (1/V), then (4) can be rewritten as a money demand equation MD = k×P×Y.
    [Show full text]
  • Money and Banking in a New Keynesian Model∗
    Money and banking in a New Keynesian model∗ Monika Piazzesi Ciaran Rogers Martin Schneider Stanford & NBER Stanford Stanford & NBER March 2019 Abstract This paper studies a New Keynesian model with a banking system. As in the data, the policy instrument of the central bank is held by banks to back inside money and therefore earns a convenience yield. While interest rate policy is less powerful than in the standard model, policy rules that do not respond aggressively to inflation – such as an interest rate peg – do not lead to self-fulfilling fluctuations. Interest rate policy is stronger (and closer to the standard model) when the central bank operates a corridor system as opposed to a floor system. It is weaker when there are more nominal rigidities in banks’ balance sheets and when banks have more market power. ∗Email addresses: [email protected], [email protected], [email protected]. We thank seminar and conference participants at the Bank of Canada, Kellogg, Lausanne, NYU, Princeton, UC Santa Cruz, the RBNZ Macro-Finance Conference and the NBER SI Impulse and Propagations meeting for helpful comments and suggestions. 1 1 Introduction Models of monetary policy typically assume that the central bank sets the short nominal inter- est rate earned by households. In the presence of nominal rigidities, the central bank then has a powerful lever to affect intertemporal decisions such as savings and investment. In practice, however, central banks target interest rates on short safe bonds that are predominantly held by intermediaries.1 At the same time, the behavior of such interest rates is not well accounted for by asset pricing models that fit expected returns on other assets such as long terms bonds or stocks: this "short rate disconnect" has been attributed to a convenience yield on short safe bonds.2 This paper studies a New Keynesian model with a banking system that is consistent with key facts on holdings and pricing of policy instruments.
    [Show full text]
  • Ch 30 Money Growth and Inflation
    LECTURE NOTES ON MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES Peter Ireland Department of Economics Boston College [email protected] http://www2.bc.edu/peter-ireland/ec132.html Copyright (c) 2013 by Peter Ireland. Redistribution is permitted for educational and research purposes, so long as no changes are made. All copies must be provided free of charge and must include this copyright notice. Introduction Remember Ch our 30 previous Money example from Chapter Growth 23, “Measuring and the Inflation Cost of Living.” In 1931, the Yankees paid Babe Ruth an annual salary of $80,000. But then again, in 1931, an ice cream cone cost a nickel and a movie ticket cost a quarter. The overall increase in the level of prices, as measured by the CPI or the GDP deflator, is called inflation. Although most economies experience at least some inflation most of the time, in the 19th century many economies experienced extended periods of falling prices, deflation or . And deflation became a threat once again in the US during the recession of 2008 and 2009. Further, over recent decades, there have been wide variations in the inflation rate as well: from rates exceeding 7 percent per year in the 1970s to the current rate of about 2 percent per year. And in some countries during some periods, extremely high rates of inflation have been experienced. In Germany after World War I, for instance, the price of a newspaper rose from 0.3 marks in January 1921 to 70,000,000 marks less than two years later. These episodes of extremely high inflation are called hyperinflations.
    [Show full text]
  • Problem Set 5 – Some Answers FE312 Fall 2010 Rahman
    Problem Set 5 – Some Answers FE312 Fall 2010 Rahman 1) Suppose that real money demand is represented by the equation (M/P)d = 0.25*Y. Use the quantity equation to calculate the income velocity of money. V = 4. 2) Assume that the demand for real money is (M/P)d = 0.6*Y – 100i, where Y is national income and i is the nominal interest rate. The real interest rate r is fixed at 3 percent by the investment and saving functions. The expected inflation rate equals the rate of nominal money growth. a) If Y is 1000, M is 100, and the growth rate of nominal money is 1%, what must i and P be? Given the quantity theory of money, we know that inflation will simply equal the growth rate of money (provided that output is constant). Given the Fisher equation, this means that i = 4 percent. Thus, plugging into our money demand equation above, we get P = 0.5. b) If Y is 1000, M is 100, and the growth rate of nominal money is 2%, what must i and P be? Here i would be 5%, and P would be 1. 3) Econoland finances government expenditures with an inflation tax. a) Explain who pays the tax and how it is paid. Everyone in the economy ends up paying in some way, but the costs come in the more subtle forms of social costs. b) What are the costs from this tax? Just be able to tick off the costs described in the text, both anticipated and unanticipated.
    [Show full text]
  • Will the U.S. Velocity of Money Step up Again? New Evidence from the Random Walk Hypothesis
    Undergraduate Economic Review Volume 10 Issue 1 Article 14 2013 Will the U.S. Velocity of Money Step up Again? New Evidence from the Random Walk Hypothesis Anh Thu Tran Xuan Carroll University - Waukesha, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.iwu.edu/uer Part of the Macroeconomics Commons Recommended Citation Tran Xuan, Anh Thu (2013) "Will the U.S. Velocity of Money Step up Again? New Evidence from the Random Walk Hypothesis," Undergraduate Economic Review: Vol. 10 : Iss. 1 , Article 14. Available at: https://digitalcommons.iwu.edu/uer/vol10/iss1/14 This Article is protected by copyright and/or related rights. It has been brought to you by Digital Commons @ IWU with permission from the rights-holder(s). You are free to use this material in any way that is permitted by the copyright and related rights legislation that applies to your use. For other uses you need to obtain permission from the rights-holder(s) directly, unless additional rights are indicated by a Creative Commons license in the record and/ or on the work itself. This material has been accepted for inclusion by faculty at Illinois Wesleyan University. For more information, please contact [email protected]. ©Copyright is owned by the author of this document. Will the U.S. Velocity of Money Step up Again? New Evidence from the Random Walk Hypothesis Abstract The recent decrease in U.S. money velocity raises debates about its unit root behavior. This paper revisited the random walk hypothesis (RWH) of the U.S. money velocity in 1960-2010 and two sub-periods 1960-85 and 1986-2010 by applying the Variance Ratio methodologies, including new nonparametric tests by Wright (2000) and Belaire-Franch and Contreras (2004).
    [Show full text]
  • 4 How Fast Is That Buck? the Velocity of Money
    4 How fast is that buck? The velocity of money How often does a dollar bill change hands? This quantity, known as the velocity of money, is relevant because it influences inflation: higher velocity of money has the same effect as an increase in the quantity of money; if money works harder, you need less of it (see inset). The relativity of money Economics has its own version of Einstein’s E=MC2. It is Irving Fisher’s equation of exchange: Here M denotes the total money supply, V the velocity of money, P the price level and T the amount of transactions. The formula is simple and intuitively appealing, but estimating the actual values for these variables is not straightforward, to put it mildly. Perhaps the most enigmatic of all is V, the velocity of money: how often does a dollar or euro change hands? We can rewrite Fisher’s equation to , but while M is measurable, PT is much harder to obtain. We measure changes to P through price level indices, but for the formula we need the value of all transactions, i.e. the average price times the volume of all transactions, including intermediate goods and asset transactions. One way to estimate the speed of cash is to look directly at consumer cash behaviour. A Federal Reserve survey, for example, that finds that physical currency turns over 55 times per year, i.e. about once a week.1 We can combine this with data on banknote fitness and replacement by the Federal Reserve. The Federal Reserve inspects notes returned by banks and replaces the ones that are worn out.
    [Show full text]
  • From the Great Depression to the Great Recession
    Money and Velocity During Financial Crises: From the Great Depression to the Great Recession Richard G. Anderson* Senior Research Fellow, School of Business and Entrepreneurship Lindenwood University, St Charles, Missouri, [email protected] Visiting Scholar. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, St. Louis, MO Michael Bordo Rutgers University National Bureau of Economic Research Hoover Institution, Stanford University [email protected] John V. Duca* Associate Director of Research and Vice President, Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, P.O. Box 655906, Dallas, TX 75265, (214) 922-5154, [email protected] and Adjunct Professor, Southern Methodist University, Dallas, TX December 2014 Abstract This study models the velocity (V2) of broad money (M2) since 1929, covering swings in money [liquidity] demand from changes in uncertainty and risk premia spanning the two major financial crises of the last century: the Great Depression and Great Recession. V2 is notably affected by risk premia, financial innovation, and major banking regulations. Findings suggest that M2 provides guidance during crises and their unwinding, and that the Fed faces the challenge of not only preventing excess reserves from fueling a surge in M2, but also countering a fall in the demand for money as risk premia return to normal. JEL codes: E410, E500, G11 Key words: money demand, financial crises, monetary policy, liquidity, financial innovation *We thank J.B. Cooke and Elizabeth Organ for excellent research assistance. This paper reflects our intellectual debt to many monetary economists, especially Milton Friedman, Stephen Goldfeld, Richard Porter, Anna Schwartz, and James Tobin. The views expressed are those of the authors and are not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Banks of Dallas and St.
    [Show full text]
  • What Drives Money Velocity?
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Benati, Luca Working Paper What drives money velocity? Discussion Papers, No. 17-07 Provided in Cooperation with: Department of Economics, University of Bern Suggested Citation: Benati, Luca (2017) : What drives money velocity?, Discussion Papers, No. 17-07, University of Bern, Department of Economics, Bern This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/204907 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Faculty of Business, Economics and Social Sciences Department of Economics What Drives Money Velocity? Luca Benati 17-07 December 2017 DISCUSSION PAPERS Schanzeneckstrasse 1 Postfach CH-3001 Bern, Switzerland http://www.vwi.unibe.ch What Drives Money Velocity?∗ Sophie Altermatt Luca Benati University of Bern† University of Bern‡ Abstract SinceWorldWarII,permanentinterestrateshockshavedrivennearlyallof the fluctuations of U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Why Has Deflation Continued Under Extraordinary Monetary Expansion?
    PDPRIETI Policy Discussion Paper Series 19-P-028 Why has Deflation Continued under Extraordinary Monetary Expansion? KOBAYASHI, Keiichiro RIETI The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry https://www.rieti.go.jp/en/ RIETI Policy Discussion Paper Series 19-P-028 October 2019 Why has deflation continued under extraordinary monetary expansion?1 Kobayashi, Keiichiro The Tokyo Foundation for Policy Research, RIETI, Keio University, CIGS Abstract We propose a theoretical argument for a new rational expectations equilibrium hypothesis in the intergenerational economy, where each generation is intergenerationally altruistic and rational. The intergenerationally-rational expectations equilibrium implies that deflation can continue under an extreme increase in money supply. Keywords: Deflationary equilibrium, transversality condition, zero nominal interest rate policy. JEL classification: E31, E50, The RIETI Policy Discussion Papers Series was created as part of RIETI research and aims to contribute to policy discussions in a timely fashion. The views expressed in these papers are solely those of the author(s), and neither represent those of the organization(s) to which the author(s) belong(s) nor the Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry. 1I thank Makoto Yano and seminar participants at Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry (RIETI) for encouraging and useful comments. All remaining errors are mine. This study is conducted as a part of the Project “Microeconomics, Macroeconomics, and Political Philosophy toward Economic Growth” undertaken at RIETI. 1 1. Transversality condition and the velocity of money Observing the monetary policy in Japan for the last three decades, we have a question whether the velocity of money may be endogenous and responsive to the policy changes.
    [Show full text]