Spatial Perspectives on New Theories of Economic Growth*

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Spatial Perspectives on New Theories of Economic Growth* View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by DSpace at VU Ann Reg Sci (1998) 32:7–37 © Springer-Verlag 1998 Spatial perspectives on new theories of economic growth* Peter Nijkamp1, Jacques Poot 2 1 Department of Spatial Economics, Free University Amsterdam, De Boelelaan 1105, 1081 HV Amsterdam, The Netherlands (Tel.: +31-20-44460 94; Fax: +31-20-44460 04; e-mail: [email protected]) 2 School of Economics and Finance, Victoria University of Wellington, P.O. Box 600, Wellington, New Zealand (Tel.: +64-4-4721000; Fax: +64-4-4955014; e-mail: [email protected]) Abstract. A new wave of interest in long-run economic growth emerged since the late 1980s. This paper uses a simple model to illustrate how tech- nological change can be endogenised in macroeconomic theories of growth and then surveys how – through factor mobility, the diffusion of innova- tions and trade – spatial interdependence in a system of regions can influ- ence technological change and growth. Endogenous technological change generates in our illustrative model long-run steady-state growth in a closed economy. However, it turns out that the dynamic impact of spatial inter- dependence depends on the specification of the model. Spatial conver- gence, a steady state with persisting spatial differences in growth rates and unstable growth are all theoretically possible. Issues relating to the role of aggregate demand and policy also receive attention. There is much scope for further theoretical and empirical work on endogenous growth in a spa- tial-economic context, while a better integration of micro and macro level approaches is also desirable. 1. Introduction The spatial-economic landscape exhibits a panorama of changing hills and valleys of welfare levels. Why growth rates differ between nations, or re- gions, is a fundamental question which has intrigued economists ever since Adam Smith’s (1776) “Inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations”. Research on the subject, however, has not been at a steady pace during the past two centuries. Instead, there have been several waves of in- * This is a revised version of a paper presented at the international seminar on Endogenous Growth and the Space Economy, 19–20 December 1996, Tinbergen Institute, Amsterdam. This paper was written while Poot was Visiting Professor at the Institute of Policy and Plan- ning Sciences of the University of Tsukuba, Japan. The hospitality of the Institute is gratefully acknowledged. 8 P. Nijkamp, J. Poot terest. Temporal and spatial differences in the standard of living were im- portant issues for classical economists such as Adam Smith, Malthus (1798) and Ricardo (1817). Except for Marx’s (1867) alternative interpreta- tion of the driving forces in long-term capitalist accumulation, further ma- jor theorising did not occur until the 20th century. During the first half of this century, Schumpeter (1934) laid the foundations for recent insights into the role of technological change and entrepreneurial competition in long- run development, while Harrod (1939) and, independently, Domar (1946) studied the growth of a Keynesian economy. In their model, the long run growth path would be likely to exhibit either growing unemployment or ac- celerating inflation. The second half of this century has seen two major waves of interest in the macroeconomics of growth. The first of these commenced with the seminal articles by Solow (1956) and Swan (1956), whose neoclassical growth model provided a more plausible description of the long-term path of the economy than the Harrod-Domar model. Yet the major weakness of the standard neoclassical model, and of the wave of theoretical contribu- tions which built upon it, was that it did not provide an explanation for the actual “engines” of long-run growth in income per worker, although its pre- dictions were consistent with several stylised facts of economic develop- ment. The reason for this deficiency was not that economists were ignorant about the causes of spatial or temporal differences in long-run growth rates but, instead, that causes of productivity improvements such as innovation, economies of scale and learning-by-doing had effects on the economy which violated the assumptions of perfect competition and constant returns to scale. As Krugman (1995) argued, the theoretical tools were not yet available in the 1950s to study such phenomena of increasing returns and imperfect competition within the accepted axiomatic neoclassical frame- work. Consequently, policy makers requiring advice on how to improve na- tional and regional growth rates needed to look elsewhere and the fields of development economics and regional economics emerged respectively as more pragmatic responses to fill this vacuum. Thus, theoretical and empiri- cal models of regional growth could build upon the idea of growth poles (Perroux 1955) or cumulative causation (Myrdal 1957; Kaldor 1970). When several North-American macroeconomists returned to the issue of long-run growth in the mid 1980s, now with new tools to formulate equi- librium models with increasing returns and imperfectly competitive sectors, a revival of the field emerged starting with the influential articles by Paul Romer (1986) and Robert Lucas (1988). This literature describes macroeco- nomic outcomes in terms of microfoundations such as an intertemporal optimisation of consumption by rational and forward-looking households. However, the essence of this idea itself goes back to Ramsey (1928) and was earlier applied to growth modelling by Cass (1965) and Koopmans (1965). Parallel to the development of the new theoretical explanations, a vast literature on the empirics of growth emerged, commencing with the contri- New theories of economic growth 9 bution of Kormendi and Meguire (1985). Here the objective was not only to identify causes of growth, but also to find out whether growth rates across countries or regions converge or diverge over time. The importance of increasing returns, externalities and imperfect compe- tition for an understanding of the dynamics of economic development by means of the “New Growth Theories” has also led to two related research paradigms. One of these is the “New International Economics”, which pro- vides a reformulation of the theories of trade and trade policy (see e.g. Krugman 1988). The other is the “New Economic Geography”, which at- tempts to explain the spatial distribution of economic activity, both in terms of urban systems and in terms of regional development (see e.g. Krugman 1991; Fujita et al. 1995). The wave of “New Growth Theories” and its empirical counterpart has now reached a stage of maturity whose substantive contribution has already been assessed in special issues of major journals and general surveys (e.g. Ehrlich 1990; Stern 1991; Jones and Stokey 1992; Verspagen 1992; Romer 1994; Mankiw 1995; Jones and Manuelli 1997). There is also some dis- sent, e.g. Scott (1989) provides an alternative approach which rejects the use of the neoclassical production function. The empirical work on growth has benefited from new comparative data bases for a wide range of coun- tries in the world (e.g. Summers and Heston 1991; International Monetary Fund, various years; World Bank, various years). However, some of the conclusions regarding the determinants of growth drawn from such data ap- pear as yet rather fragile (Levine and Renelt 1992; Mankiw 1995). Theory and empirics are brought together skillfully in the textbook by Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995) which provides an advanced, but accessible, treatment of all the major issues in theoretical models of economic growth and the re- lated empirical investigations. Thus, the present paper does not purport to provide yet another broad survey. Instead, we will focus only on the spatial aspects of the neoclassi- cal and the new growth models. A distinction is made between differences in growth rates due to spatial variations in parameters which influence growth in closed economies and causes of differences in growth rates be- tween open economies. The predictions of the models are also compared with the main conclusions of the well-established literature on regional eco- nomic development. Finally, implications for regional policies are identified briefly. Many of the neoclassical and new growth models describe accumulation in closed economies. Explanations for spatial differences in growth rates between such economies must necessarily derive from differences in param- eters, initial conditions or other exogenous variables. Closed economy ex- planations of differences in growth rates are discussed in Sect. 2. At the regional level, there is spatial interaction in terms of trade, capi- tal flows, migration, diffusion of technological innovation and information exchanges. Thus, the closed economy models can provide at best a very limited understanding of regional growth. Section 3 considers the implica- tions of introducing factor mobility, trade, economic integration and innova- 10 P. Nijkamp, J. Poot tion diffusion into models of growth. It will become clear that the exten- sion of the new growth models to the case of open economies is not yet fully satisfactory, and much work remains to be done in this area (Barro and Sala-i-Martin 1995, p. 128). Section 4 focuses on the transitional dynamics in closed or open econo- mies. An understanding of the transitional dynamics will enable predictions to be made about convergence or divergence. An assessment of the some- times contradictory empirical evidence on this matter is provided. Section 5 compares the new theories of growth with the conventional theories of regional development. While some of these have built upon neoclassical theories (as surveyed in e.g. McCombie 1988a), the post-Key- nesian perspective which puts more emphasis on the role of demand in the economy and Kaldor’s formulation of technical change (Kaldor 1957), had tended to be more popular (McCombie 1988b). The contribution, and po- tential, of evolutionary economics for an understanding of the regional growth process is also briefly addressed in this context.
Recommended publications
  • CR Traverse Analysis Progenitors & Pioneers
    Traverse Analysis: Progenitors and Pioneers 14th History of Economic Thought Society of Australia Conference The University of Tasmania, Hobart, Australia. 11th July 2001 Colin Richardson* School of Economics University of Tasmania ABSTRACT Traverse analysis has two progenitors (David Ricardo, Karl Marx) and five pioneers: Michal Kalecki, Adolph Lowe, Joan Robinson, J.R. Hicks, and John Hicks. Defined as the dynamic disequilibrium adjustment-path that connects an initial with a different terminal state of economic growth, the traverse comes in four “flavours”. There are neoclassical (J.R. Hicks), neo-Austrian (John Hicks), observed (Ricardo, Marx, Kalecki, Robinson), and instrumental (Lowe) traverses. These terms are explained and the seven seminal contributions are summarised and commented upon in this paper. * I am indebted to Dr Jerry Courvisanos for his supervision and comments in writing this paper. Scholarship support from The University of Tasmania is also gratefully acknowledged. 2 Introduction Nobel laureate economist Robert Solow once quipped: “The traverse is the easiest part of skiing but the most difficult part of economics”. Later, Joseph Halevi and Peter Kriesler (1992, p 225) complained that “The traverse is at the same time one of the most important concepts in economic theory, and also one of the most neglected.” This paper outlines briefly the history of economic thought between 1821 and 1973 concerning this difficult, important and neglected theoretical construct. Traverse analysis has two progenitors (David Ricardo, Karl Marx) and five pioneers: Michal Kalecki, Adolph Lowe, Joan Robinson, J.R. Hicks, and John Hicks. Defined as the dynamic disequilibrium adjustment-path that connects an initial with a different terminal state of economic growth, the traverse comes in four “flavours”.
    [Show full text]
  • Earle Page and the Imagining of Australia
    ‘NOW IS THE PSYCHOLOGICAL MOMENT’ EARLE PAGE AND THE IMAGINING OF AUSTRALIA ‘NOW IS THE PSYCHOLOGICAL MOMENT’ EARLE PAGE AND THE IMAGINING OF AUSTRALIA STEPHEN WILKS Ah, but a man’s reach should exceed his grasp, Or what’s a heaven for? Robert Browning, ‘Andrea del Sarto’ The man who makes no mistakes does not usually make anything. Edward John Phelps Earle Page as seen by L.F. Reynolds in Table Talk, 21 October 1926. Published by ANU Press The Australian National University Acton ACT 2601, Australia Email: [email protected] Available to download for free at press.anu.edu.au ISBN (print): 9781760463670 ISBN (online): 9781760463687 WorldCat (print): 1198529303 WorldCat (online): 1198529152 DOI: 10.22459/NPM.2020 This title is published under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial- NoDerivatives 4.0 International (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0). The full licence terms are available at creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/legalcode This publication was awarded a College of Arts and Social Sciences PhD Publication Prize in 2018. The prize contributes to the cost of professional copyediting. Cover design and layout by ANU Press. Cover photograph: Earle Page strikes a pose in early Canberra. Mildenhall Collection, NAA, A3560, 6053, undated. This edition © 2020 ANU Press CONTENTS Illustrations . ix Acknowledgements . xi Abbreviations . xiii Prologue: ‘How Many Germans Did You Kill, Doc?’ . xv Introduction: ‘A Dreamer of Dreams’ . 1 1 . Family, Community and Methodism: The Forging of Page’s World View . .. 17 2 . ‘We Were Determined to Use Our Opportunities to the Full’: Page’s Rise to National Prominence .
    [Show full text]
  • Life of Trevor Swan
    Trevor Winchester Swan AO ANU Inaugural Trevor Swan Distinguished Lecture by Peter L. Swan∗ 23 May 2006 New Lecture Theatre, John Curtin School of Medical Research, Bldg 54, Garran Rd, ANU 4.30pm-6.00pm ANU has chosen an ideal time to launch this new distinguished lecture series in Trevor’s honour as it is the 50th anniversary of the publication of Trevor’s most famous work on growth theory (Swan, 1956). I congratulate ANU for taking this important initiative. Trevor was born on 14th of January 1918 to George Henry and Clara Ellison Swan (nee Grant), one of four siblings with a brother, Laurence, and two sisters, Clarice and Hazel. Picture 1, below, is of George and Clara. Trevor had a strong resemblance to his father. George was a tramways engineer in charge of a depot. George’s father, Henry William Swan, was born in England in 1848 and migrated to Australia. He was an "inspector of nuisances" in Sydney, which seems to be like a Health Inspector would be now, and which included keeping the noise down, rowdy kids, flying kites, etc.1 Trevor died of cancer on January 15th, 1989. A lot of what I recount below has been better said by Noel Butlin and Bob Gregory (1989) in their Economic Record appreciation. ∗Contact details: Peter L. Swan, School of Banking and Finance, UNSW, tel. 02 9385 5871; email: [email protected]. I wish to thank Robert Dixon, Alan Hall and Barbara Spencer for comments. 1 Family information supplied by Lesley Booth. Trevor’s academic brilliance shone through early, topping his primary school in all subjects, excelling at debating at Canterbury Boy's High, John Howard’s high school, and coming dux in 1936.
    [Show full text]
  • Solow's Growth Model As a Multipurpose Design
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Halsmayer, Verena Working Paper From Long-Run Utopia to Technical Expertise: Solow's Growth Model as a Multipurpose Design CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2014-09 Provided in Cooperation with: Center for the History of Political Economy at Duke University Suggested Citation: Halsmayer, Verena (2014) : From Long-Run Utopia to Technical Expertise: Solow's Growth Model as a Multipurpose Design, CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2014-09, Duke University, Center for the History of Political Economy (CHOPE), Durham, NC This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/149721 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu From Long-Run Utopia to Technical Expertise Solow’s Growth Model as a Multipurpose Design by Verena Halsmayer CHOPE Working Paper No.
    [Show full text]
  • Trevor Swan and the Neoclassical Growth Model
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES TREVOR SWAN AND THE NEOCLASSICAL GROWTH MODEL Robert W. Dimand Barbara J. Spencer Working Paper 13950 http://www.nber.org/papers/w13950 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 April 2008 This paper was prepared for presentation at the conference, HOPE 2008:"Robert Solow and the Development of Growth Economics", organized by the History of Political Economy group, Duke University, April 25-27, 2008. The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2008 by Robert W. Dimand and Barbara J. Spencer. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Trevor Swan And The Neoclassical Growth Model Robert W. Dimand and Barbara J. Spencer NBER Working Paper No. 13950 April 2008, Revised June 2008 JEL No. B2,B3,B4,O41 ABSTRACT Trevor Swan independently developed the neoclassical growth model. Swan (1956) was published ten months later than Solow (1956), but included a more complete analysis of technical progress, which Solow treated separately in Solow (1957). Reference is sometimes made to the "Solow-Swan growth model", but more commonly reference is made only to the "Solow growth model". This paper examines the history of Swan’s development of the growth model, the similarities and differences between the approaches of Swan and Solow and the reasons why Swan's contribution has been overshadowed.
    [Show full text]
  • Proposal for a Master of Public Policy Submitted by the Graduate School of International Relations and Pacific Studies Universit
    Proposal for a Master of Public Policy Submitted by The Graduate School of International Relations and Pacific Studies University of California, San Diego March 2014 Table of Contents Executive Summary……………………………………………………………………3 Section 1.0: Introduction…........................................................................................... 4 1. Historical Development of the Field and Departmental Strength……………… 5 2. Aims and Objectives…………………………………………………………… 6 Distinctiveness of the IR/PS MPP……………………………………………... 7 3. Timetable for Development of the Degree…………………………………….. 9 4. Relation to Existing Campus Programs………………………………………..10 5. Interrelationship Between IR/PS MPP and Other UC Programs………………10 6. Program Governance………………………………………………………… 11 7. Plan for Evaluation…………………………………………………………… 12 Section 2.0: Program Requirements and Curriculum……………………………. 12 1. Undergraduate Preparation…………………………………………………… 12 2. Language Requirement………………………………………………………. 13 3. Program of Study…………………………………………………………….. 13 Language Requirement………………………………………………………. 16 Sample Program of Study……………………………………………………. 16 Examination or Capstone…………………………………………………….. 17 Teaching Responsibilities……………………………………………………. 17 Normative Time……………………………………………………………… 17 Section 3.0: Projected Need………………………………………………………… 17 1. Student Demand for the Program……………………………………………. 17 2. Job Placement for MPPs……………………………………………………… 19 3. Importance to the Discipline…………………………………………………. 22 4. Importance to Society………………………………………………………… 22 5. Research and Professional Interests
    [Show full text]
  • Cv Peter Swan
    CURRICULUM VITAE OF PETER LAWRENCE SWAN AO AM FRSN FASSA PhD (Monash) DATE OF THIS SUMMARY: 06 April 2018 DATE OF BIRTH: 13 February 1944; Melbourne MARITAL STATUS: Married with a son and a daughter and four grandchildren. ADDRESS: School of Banking and Finance, UNSW Business School University of New South Wales (UNSW), Sydney, NSW 2052 Australia Telephone: +612 9385 5871 Mobile: +61(0)418 601 392 Fax: (02) 9385 6347 Email: [email protected] RESEARCH PROFILE https://scholar.google.com.au/citations?user=jJuB7lcA AAAJ&hl=en 3,042 cites as of 6/04/2018. h-index 27, i10-index 61; 222 titles. Web of Science: 37 articles and 603 cites. https://www.researchgate.net/profile/Peter_Swan. 156 publications; 6,009 reads; 1,516 citations; score 30.34. January 2018 http://ssrn.com/author=136389 53 papers, 15,438 downloads; Ranked 1,814 out of 314,100 authors by download, April 2018. http://ideas.repec.org/e/psw4.html ; 46 articles and one book chapter. Ranked in top 2% globally for journal pages weighted by impact factors. Within top 5% authors according to 9 criteria out of 35,000 authors. http://citec.repec.org/p/s/psw4.html2 https://theconversation.com/profiles/peter-swan- 101534/dashboard 9 articles and 58,845 reads as of 24/0/2018. https://www.linkedin.com/in/peterswan (5,583 connections) Numerous recent newspaper articles, e.g., The NewsDaily http://thenewdaily.com.au/money/finance- news/2017/02/08/ahmed-fahour-executive-pay/ ABC Radio National Drive (Victoria) 2017/02/08: Is Australia Post CEO Ahmed Fahour's salary too high? on RN Drive – RN.
    [Show full text]
  • From Long-Run Utopia to Technical Expertise Solow's Growth Model As
    From Long-Run Utopia to Technical Expertise Solow’s Growth Model as a Multipurpose Design by Verena Halsmayer CHOPE Working Paper No. 2014-09 April 2014 From Long-Run Utopia to Technical Expertise Solow’s Growth Model as a Multipurpose Design Verena Halsmayer DK The Sciences in Historical, Philosophical and Cultural Contexts (FWF Grant W1228-G18), University of Vienna [email protected]. October 31, 2013 Abstract Combining concrete policy-oriented modeling strategies of World War II with what was received as traditional neoclassical theory, in 1956 Robert Solow constructed a simple, clean, and smooth-functioning “design” model that served many different purposes. As a working object it enabled experimentation with long-run equilibrium growth. As an instrument of measurement it was applied to time series data. As a prototype it was supposed to feed into larger-scale econometric models that were, in turn, thought of as technologies for policy advice. Used as a teaching device, Solow’s design became a medium of “spreading the technique,” and one of the symbols for neoclassical macroeconomics that soon became associated with MIT. Keywords: model, modeling, Robert Solow, growth theory, growth, neoclassical growth model, linear programming, dynamic programming, design model, Harvard Economic Research Project, Massachusetts Institute of Technology. JEL Codes: B22, B23, B31, B40, O4, Z1 On January 10, 1954, the journalist and author Godfrey Blunden sent a letter to Harold Isaacs, a member of the Department of Political Science at MIT, asking for help on a novel he planned to write: The novel […] is about some New York and Connecticut people, among them a mathematician.
    [Show full text]
  • The Neoclassical Growth Model and 20 Century Economics
    The Neoclassical Growth Model and 20 th Century Economics by Mauro Boianovsky and Kevin D. Hoover 29 January 2009 Introduction to Mauro Boianovsky and Kevin D. Hoover, editors, Robert Solow and the Development of Growth Economics. Conference volume from the 20 th annual History of Political Economy Conference, forthcoming as a special issue of History of Political Economy 2009 and as a hardbound volume. While growth has been a central element of economic thought at least since the physiocrats and Adam Smith, the modern analysis of growth using formal models began only in the middle of the 20 th century. Largely thanks to Robert Solow’s two articles, “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth” (1956) and “Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function” (1957), growth economics developed into a major area of research in macroeconomics and economic theory, attracting the attention of a significant part of the economics profession. The current volume collects most of the papers from the 20 th annual History of Political Economy Conference held 25­27 April 2008 at Duke University. The conference addressed the history of modern growth economics, taking Solow’s key papers from the 1950s as its anchor. The conference was not about Solow’s work per se, but addressed the intellectual currents that formed the background to that work and the history of the growth economics that it subsequently informed. The conference considered the rise of growth economics as an active field of research in the 1950s, its extension to several branches of the discipline in the 1960s, its decline in the 1970s, and its return to the center­stage of macroeconomics over the last 20 years.
    [Show full text]
  • Glenn Stevens: the Inaugural Warren Hogan Memorial Lecture
    Glenn Stevens: The Inaugural Warren Hogan Memorial Lecture Text of The Inaugural Warren Hogan Memorial Lecture by Mr Glenn Stevens, Governor of the Reserve Bank of Australia, at the School of Economics, University of Sydney, Sydney, 8 December 2011. * * * It is a very great pleasure, as a former student of Professor Warren Hogan, to give this lecture in his memory. Thank you to the Hogan family, many of whom are here this evening, and to the School of Economics at the University of Sydney for giving me this honour. Before recounting one or two personal reminiscences, it is appropriate to say something about his life. Many fascinating details of it are revealed in the interview with John Lodewijks, and the eulogy by Tony Aspromourgos, both fittingly published in the Economic Record.1 Warren Pat Hogan was born in Papakura, just south of Auckland, New Zealand, in 1929. He completed his undergraduate and Master’s education at Auckland University College, where he was taught by Colin Simkin, who later was also at the University of Sydney. He married Ialene, a fellow student in the same faculty, in 1952. Hence it is not altogether surprising that Hogan’s children seemed drawn to economics. Four of the five children, and several of the grandchildren, have degrees in economics. After gaining early work experience at the Reserve Bank of New Zealand, Hogan, with a young family in tow, came to Australia in the mid 1950s, where he gained a PhD from the Australian National University in 1959, his research being on growth theory. His supervisor for that work was Trevor Swan, one of Australia’s most renowned theoretical economists (and subsequently a member of the Reserve Bank Board).
    [Show full text]
  • PDF File Created from a TIFF Image by Tiff2pdf
    Copyright ofFull Text rests with the original copyright owner and, except as pennitted under the Copyright Act 1968, copying this copyright material is prohibited without the pennission ofthe owner or its exclusive licensee or agent or by way ofa licence from Copyright Agency Limited. For infonnation about such licences contact Copyright Agency Limited on (02) 93947600 (ph) or (02) 93947601 (fax) THE ASCENDANCY OF AN IDEALIST ECONOMICS IN AUSTRALIA Evan Jones' The economics profession is a necessary evil. Economists exist to lecture. individuals, organisations and governments on the need for efficiency and restraint. Increasingly, it seems, they are more evil than necessary. Over the last forty years, economists in Australia have become more idealist, more arrogant and more influential. By 'idealist', I mean committed to conceptual structures derived from fixed axioms that are innocent of and immune to experience - in practice, the neoclassical paradigm. Moreover, this entails a corrunitment not merely to interpreting the world through this vision, but changing the world to make it fit the vision. The useful economist is a person cognisant of the social constitution of economic activity. He (or she) will be aware of the deep need of individuals for stability and regularity in the processes of economic life. S/he will be aware of the strong moral purpose that motivates people to resistance and action when confronted with instances of structured injustice (whether affe·cting themselves or others). S/he will be well read in history, and in the peculiarities of economic structures and processes in time and place. S/he will have some awareness of the technical and social dimensions that underlie the production of goods and services (or will defer to experts so informed).
    [Show full text]
  • Trevor Swan and Indian Planning: the Lessons of 1958/59
    Working Papers in Trade and Development Trevor Swan and Indian Planning: The Lessons of 1958/59 Selwyn Cornish and Raghbendra Jha November 2016 Working Paper No. 2016/19 Arndt-Corden Department of Economics Crawford School of Public Policy ANU College of Asia and the Pacific This Working Paper series provides a vehicle for preliminary circulation of research results in the fields of economic development and international trade. The series is intended to stimulate discussion and critical comment. Staff and visitors in any part of the Australian National University are encouraged to contribute. To facilitate prompt distribution, papers are screened, but not formally refereed. Copies may be obtained at WWW Site http://www.crawford.anu.edu.au/acde/publications/ Trevor Swan and Indian Planning: The Lessons of 1958/59 Selwyn Cornish and Raghbendra Jha Australian National University ABSTRACT Trevor Swan is commonly considered to be Australia’s most distinguished economist. As part of a visiting professorship at MIT during 1958-59 he spent nine months in India to assist in the formulation of India’s third five year plan and to contribute to the development of India’s premier research institutions. This paper provides an account of his work in New Delhi. Swan’s closest associates were Pitambar Pant from the Indian Planning Commission and Ian Little who was visiting from Oxford. Swan was of the view that India’s economic problems should be clearly understood and the best policy measures to address these should be devised. This varied considerably from the practice of central planning and state control being practiced in India at that time.
    [Show full text]