Globalization, De-Industrialization and Mexican Exceptionalism 1750-1879

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Globalization, De-Industrialization and Mexican Exceptionalism 1750-1879 Globalization, De-Industrialization and Mexican Exceptionalism 1750-1879 by Rafael Dobado González (Complutense Madrid) Aurora Gómez Galvarriato (CIDE) Jeffrey G. Williamson (Harvard) June 2006 We are grateful for the excellent research assistant support supplied by David Clingingsmith, Ignacio de la Huerta, Pedro Glaser, Taylor Owings, Rodrigo Parral, and Pablo Tsutsumi. We also have benefited from help with the data, useful advice and criticism offered by Leticia Arroyo Abad, Luis Bértola, Amilcar Challu, Greg Clark, David Clingingsmith, John Coatsworth, Hector Garcia, Steve Haber, Enrique Llopis, Graciela Márquez, Gustavo Marrero, Javier Moreno, Kevin O’Rourke, Carlos Ponzio, Leandro Prados, Joan Roses, Dick Salvucci and Juan José Urquiola. Dobado is grateful to the Real Colegio Complutense at Harvard, the David Rockefeller Center for Latin American Studies and the Spanish Ministerio de Educación y Ciencia. Williamson acknowledges with pleasure financial support from the National Science Foundation SES- 0001362 and the Harvard Faculty of Arts and Sciences. 1 Abstract Like the rest of the poor periphery, Mexico had to deal with de-industrialization forces between 1750 and 1913, those critical 150 years when the economic gap between the industrial core and the primary-product-producing periphery widened to such huge dimensions. Yet, from independence to mid-century Mexico did better on this score than did most countries around the periphery. This paper explores the sources of Mexican exceptionalism with de-industrialization. It decomposes those sources into those attributable to productivity events in the core and to globalization forces connecting core to periphery, and to those attributable to domestic forces specific to Mexico. It uses a neo-Ricardian model (with non-tradable foodstuffs) to implement the decomposition, and advocates a price dual approach, and develops a new price and wage data base 1750-1878. There were three forces at work that account for Mexican exceptionalism: first, the terms of trade and Dutch disease effects were much weaker; second, Mexico maintained secular wage competitiveness with the core; and third, Mexico had the autonomy to devise effective ways to foster industry. The first appears to have been the most important. Rafael Dobado Gonzales Aurora Gómez Galvarriato Department of Economic History Division of Economics Universidad Complutense Madrid CIDE Somosaguas Campus Lomas de Sta. Fé 12010 Madrid 28223 Spain México D. F. Mexico [email protected] [email protected] Jeffrey G. Williamson Department of Economics Harvard University Cambridge MA 02138 USA and CEPR and NBER [email protected] JEL No. F1, N7, O2 2 1. Mexico and the Great De-Industrialization Debate The economic impact of the core on the periphery between 1750 and 1913 had its source in three forces. The first was a European policy movement away from anti-global mercantilism and towards pro-global free trade (Findlay and O’Rourke 2003). The second was a world-wide transport revolution that served to further integrate world commodity markets (O’Rourke and Williamson 1999: Ch. 3; Mohammed and Williamson 2004; Williamson 2006b: Chs. 2 and 3). It caused a boom in trade between core and periphery, created commodity price convergence for tradable goods between all world markets, and contributed to a rise in every country’s external terms of trade, especially in the periphery. The third came from the derived demand for industrial intermediates, like cotton, rubber and metals, which soared as manufacturing production led the way in the core. Thus, as core economies raised their industrial output shares, manufacturing output growth raced ahead of GDP growth. Rapid productivity growth lowered the cost and price of manufactures, and by so doing generated a soaring derived demand for raw materials. This event was reinforced by accelerating income per capita growth and a high income elasticity of demand for luxury consumption goods, like meat, tea, and coffee. Since industrialization was driven by unbalanced productivity advance favoring manufacturing relative to agriculture and other natural-resource based activities, the relative price of manufactures fell everywhere. The world transport revolution made it possible for the distant periphery to supply this booming demand for primary products. All three forces produced positive, powerful and sustained terms of trade shocks in the periphery, raising the relative price of primary products, and through an epoch which stretched over a century. Factor supply responses in the periphery facilitated these external demand shocks, reinforcing their comparative advantage in primary products and causing de- industrialization. 3 Eventually these three forces abated. A globalization backlash hit most of the world (except Britain, the Netherlands, and their colonies), causing a partial shift backwards to protection (Williamson 2006a). The rate of decline in real transport costs along sea lanes slowed down, approaching a late 20th century steady state (Mohammed and Williamson 2004). The rate of growth of manufacturing slowed down in the core as the transition to industrial maturity was completed. As these three forces abated, the resulting slow down in primary product demand growth was reinforced by resource-saving innovations in the industrial core, induced, in large part, by those high and rising primary product prices during the 19th century terms of trade upswing. Thus, the secular boom faded, eventually turning into a secular bust. Exactly when and where the boom turned to bust depended on export commodity specialization, but all periphery regions reached a terms of trade peak somewhere between the 1870s and World War I. This secular boom in the periphery terms of trade is illustrated well by Latin America. The region’s terms of trade underwent a steady increase from the 1810s to the early 1890s, and the improvement was especially dramatic during the first five decades. Furthermore, the increase is understated to the extent that it fails to take account of the likely quality improvement in traded manufactures relative to primary products: the quality-adjusted terms of trade in Latin America probably grew at a little more than 2.2 percent per annum between 1815-19 and 1855-59, and at a little more than 1.4 percent per annum between 1815-19 and 1890-94 (Williamson 2006b: Figure 1 and Appendix 1). This was a very big terms of trade boom, but Latin American experience was hardly unique since the increase was even bigger for Egypt, the Ottoman Empire (Turkey), Japan, Indonesia, and elsewhere in the periphery. During the terms of trade boom, rates of technological advance and human capital accumulation were so modest in the periphery that the living standard gap between it and the core surged to levels that were vastly wider at the end of the boom than at the beginning. Whether the modest rates of technological advance and human capital accumulation in the periphery were caused by de-industrialization has, of course, been a central issue in historical debate since it all 4 started. What all scholars agree on, however, was that the terms of trade boom caused de- industrialization in the periphery through Dutch disease and other effects. This paper establishes that Mexico obeyed the same laws of motion between 1750 (just before the Bourbon reforms) and 1879 (before the economic changes of the Porfiriato began). However, the differences between Mexico and the rest of the poor periphery were sufficiently pronounced to allow us to speak of Mexican exceptionalism. The rate of de-industrialization was far less than elsewhere in the periphery, suggesting that there were local forces at work that distinguished Mexican experience from the rest. Section 2 places de-industrialization within Mexican growth experience over almost two centuries after 1700. Section 3 describes Mexican de-industrialization and industrialization over more than a century before the Porfiriato. Section 4 presents a three-sector neo-Ricardian model with two tradables (silver exportables and textile importables) and one non-tradable (corn) which makes it possible to sort out the role of external terms of trade booms and local wage competitiveness. The remainder of the paper uses the model to decompose the sources of Mexican exceptionalism with de-industrialization. It turns out that there were three forces at work: first, the terms of trade and Dutch disease effects were weak compared with the rest of the periphery (Section 5); second, Mexico maintained better wage competitiveness vis a vis the core compared with the rest of the periphery, a result determined by relative productivity performance in food production (Section 6); and third, Mexico had the autonomy – something that most of the poor periphery did not – to devise effective policies to foster industry (Section 7). The first appears to have been the most important of the three. 2. Placing Mexican De-Industrialization in the Transitional Century Before 1879 It is very important to distinguish between economy-wide productivity levels and rates of growth, on the one hand, and industrial output and employment performance, on the other. This section starts with the former before dealing with the latter. 5 Mexican Economic Growth: Bourbon Reform, Insurgencia and Lost Decades In 1765, the Spanish government endorsed the Decree of Free Trade, by which restrictions regulating commerce between Spain and Spanish America were substantially modified. A century later, the Porfiriato (1876-1910) began to open Mexico to the global economy even further. In both cases, these liberal policies were followed by economic growth. But they also contributed to a rising inequality1 which helped provoke widespread social discontent, the Insurgencia that started in 1810 and the Revolution that started in 1910. The two movements generated immense violence, and they had much to do with the ending of Spanish colonial rule in one case and the Porfiriato in the other. Debates about colonial growth have been lively, mostly because the evidence is so scarce. Still, an optimistic view is on the rise (Klein 1998; Dobado and Marrero 2001, 2005; Ponzio 2005a).
Recommended publications
  • The Role of the Price Revolution in European Industrialization: an Explanation with Respect to the Social and Economic Transformation of Europe
    Hacettepe University Graduate School of Social Sciences Department of Economics Master’s Program THE ROLE OF THE PRICE REVOLUTION IN EUROPEAN INDUSTRIALIZATION: AN EXPLANATION WITH RESPECT TO THE SOCIAL AND ECONOMIC TRANSFORMATION OF EUROPE Buğra Altuğ YILMAZ Master’s Thesis Ankara, 2019 THE ROLE OF THE PRICE REVOLUTION IN EUROPEAN INDUSTRIALIZATION: AN EXPLANATION WITH RESPECT TO THE SOCIAL AND ECONOMIC TRANSFORMATION OF EUROPE Buğra Altuğ YILMAZ Hacettepe University Graduate School of Social Sciences Department of Economics Master’s Program Master’s Thesis Ankara, 2019 i ii iii iv ABSTRACT [YILMAZ, Buğra Altuğ]. [The Role of the Price Revolution in European Industrializatıon: An Explanation With Respect to the Social and Economic Transformation of Europe]. [Master Thesis], Ankara, [2019]. The industrialization period of Europe was a milestone in the economic history. Its consequences are still faced by modern nation states. Hence, the roots of the Price Revolution – the great inflation of sixteenth century which was experienced in Europe – and its effects to this process was questioned in this thesis. First of all the social transformation of Europe – transition from feudalism to capitalism – was briefly analyzed by considering the mercantilist era as well. This period was important for us to focus on the monetization of the economies. At the same time, the relationship between the precious metal inflow, minting activities and the inflation was questioned. To create an insight on the case, price indexes of various cities in Europe and price trends of different sectors were given. Then, the demand base of the Price Revolution – its relationship with the population – was considered in the frame of quantity theory of money.
    [Show full text]
  • New Monarchs, Exploration & 16Th Century Society
    AP European History: Unit 1.3 HistorySage.com New Monarchs, Exploration & 16th Century Society I. “New” Monarchs: c.1460-1550 Use space below for A. Consolidated power and created the foundation for notes Europe’s first modern nation-states in France, England and Spain. 1. This evolution had begun in the Middle Ages. a. New Monarchs on the continent began to make use of Roman Law and declared themselves “sovereign” while incorporating the will and welfare of their people into the person of the monarch This meant they had authority to make their own laws b. Meanwhile, monarchies had grown weaker in eastern Europe during the Middle Ages. 2. New Monarchies never achieved absolute power; absolutism did not emerge effectively until the 17th century (e.g. Louis XIV in France). 3. New Monarchies also were not nation-states (in the modern sense) since populations did not necessarily feel that they belonged to a “nation” a. Identity tended to be much more local or regional. b. The modern notion of nationalism did not emerge until the late 18th and early 19th centuries. B. Characteristics of New Monarchies 1. Reduced the power of the nobility through taxation, confiscation of lands (from uncooperative nobles), and the hiring of mercenary armies or the creation of standing armies a. The advent of gunpowder (that resulted in the production of muskets and cannon) increased the vulnerability of noble armies and their knights b. However, many nobles in return for their support of the king gained titles and offices and served in the royal court or as royal officials 2.
    [Show full text]
  • 22-23 Silver DBQ Workshop.Pptx
    The Creation of a Global Trading Network DBQ Writing Workshop DBQ Essay • Will be part of the second session of the testing period. • In total, the second session will be 100 minutes, but you should allocate only 60 minutes (including reading period) for the writing of the DBQ. • The DBQ is 25% of the total AP Test grade. • The DBQ is scored out of 7 total possible points. • There will always be 7 documents, at least one of which will be a visual. • Students are required to bring in additional evidence from outside of the documents. • Nothing can get you multiple points! No double dipping! No double jeopardy! DBQ Essay Rubric • Contextualization- 1 point • Response must relate the topic of the prompt to broader historical events, developments, or processes that occur before, during, or continue after the time frame of the question. • Thesis- 1 point • Responds to the prompt with a historically defensible thesis/claim that establishes a line of reasoning. It may not simply restate or rephrase the prompt. • Evidence- 3 points • Evidence from the Documents: 2 points • 1 point: Uses the content from at least three documents to address the topic of the prompt • 2 points: Supports an argument in response to the prompt using at least six documents • Evidence beyond the documents: 1 point • Uses at least one additional piece of specific historical evidence (beyond that found in the documents) relevant to an argument about the prompt. • Analysis and Reasoning: 2 points • Sourcing: 1 point • For at least three documents, explains how or why the document’s POV, purpose, historical situation, and/or audience is relevant to an argument.
    [Show full text]
  • The Sustainable Debts of Philip II: a Reconstruction of Spain's Fiscal
    The Sustainable Debts of Philip II: A Reconstruction of Spain’s Fiscal Position, 1560-1598* Mauricio Drelichman Hans-Joachim Voth The University of British Columbia ICREA/Universitat Pompeu Fabra and and CIFAR CEPR This Draft: January 2010 Abstract: The defaults of Philip II have attained mythical status as the origin of sovereign debt crises. We reassess the fiscal position of Habsburg Castile, deriving comprehensive estimates of revenue, debt, and expenditure from new archival data. The king’s debts were sustainable. Primary surpluses were large and rising. Debt/revenue ratios were broadly unchanged across Philip’s reign. Castilian finances in the sixteenth century compare favorably with those of other early modern fiscal states at the height of their imperial ambitions, including Britain. The defaults of Philip II therefore reflected short-term liquidity crises, and were not a sign of unsustainable debts. * For helpful comments, we thank Daron Acemoglu, George Akerlof, Carlos Alvarez Nogal, Fernando Broner, Albert Carreras, Marc Flandreau, Caroline Fohlin, Regina Grafe, Avner Greif, Viktoria Hnatkovska, Angela Redish, Alberto Martín, Paolo Mauro, David Mitch, Kris Mitchener, Joel Mokyr, Lyndon Moore, Roger Myerson, Kevin O’Rourke, Sevket Pamuk, Richard Portes, Leandro Prados de la Escosura, Nathan Sussman, Alan M. Taylor, Francois Velde, Jaume Ventura, and Eugene White. Seminar audiences at American University, Harvard, Sciences Po, Hebrew University, UBC, UPF, UC Irvine, LSE, HEI Geneva, NYU-Stern, the ECB, and Rutgers, as well as the EHA meetings in Austin, the CREI / CEPR Conference on “Crises – Past, Policy, and Theory”, CIFAR, NBER, CEPR – ESSIM, the BETA Workshop, and the Utrecht Workshop on Financial History offered advice and constructive criticism.
    [Show full text]
  • The Columbian Exchange
    Portuguese and Spanish Overseas Expansion, 1450-1600 The rise of the New Monarchies led directly to European overseas expansion. The first phase (1450-1600) was dominated by Portugal and Spain. For various reasons, England and France lagged behind. It wasn’t until after 1600 that they, along with the Dutch, also established overseas trade routes and colonies. In this reading we will focus on the Portuguese and Spanish. The first question we must ask is why, after remaining on their own continent throughout the 1000-year-long medieval period (except, perhaps, for the Crusades to the Holy Land) did Europeans begin sailing to Africa, the Americas, and Asia in the 15th century? The answer lies in the desire of the New Monarchies to gain greater wealth and power. Motives for Overseas Exploration The Economic Motive The primary motive for overseas exploration was for the New Monarchies to increase their power by acquiring new sources of wealth. Having centralized their governments at the expense of the feudal nobility and Church, the New Monarchies sought other ways besides internal taxation to increase the wealth and power of their states. As we saw in the previous reading, France and Spain sought to dominate the divided Italian states – much to the dismay of Machiavelli. Besides war, marriage was also used to increase state power. Spain’s influence in Europe grew enormously with the succession of Ferdinand and Isabella’s grandson, Charles Habsburg to the throne of Spain as Charles V. Ruling both Spain and the Holy Roman Empire, the Habsburg dynasty was Europe’s most powerful.
    [Show full text]
  • Environmental Thought During Spain's Golden Age, 1492-1618 by Harley
    Managing the Empire’s Wealth: Environmental Thought during Spain’s Golden Age, 1492-1618 By Harley Davidson Submitted to the graduate degree program in History and the Graduate Faculty of the University of Kansas in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy. ________________________________ Chairperson, Luis Corteguera ________________________________ Sara Gregg ________________________________ Greg Cushman ________________________________ Anton Rosenthal ________________________________ Santa Arias Date Defended: April 8, 2016 ii The Dissertation Committee for Harley Davidson certifies that this is the approved version of the following dissertation: Managing the Empire’s Wealth: Environmental Thought during Spain’s Golden Age, 1492-1618 ________________________________ Chairperson, Luis Corteguera Date approved: April 8, 2016 iii Abstract During the sixteenth century, or Spain's so-called "Golden Age," Spain's understanding of wealth, resource management, and cosmology underwent massive evolution in the face of gaining an empire in the Americas. Before the conquest of the Americas, resource scarcity and the need for careful resource management defined Spanish environmental thought. Afterward, the idea that the Americas could provide infinite wealth took precedence. But as the century progressed and the empire declined, people from different parts of Spanish society--municipal councilmen, conquistadors, royal cosmographers, and royal reformers--reconciled these two ideas into one line of thought: abundant
    [Show full text]
  • The Sustainable Debts of Philip II: a Reconstruction of Spain’S Fiscal Position, 1560-1598*
    The Sustainable Debts of Philip II: A Reconstruction of Spain’s Fiscal Position, 1560-1598* Mauricio Drelichman Hans-Joachim Voth The University of British Columbia ICREA/Universitat Pompeu Fabra and and CIFAR CEPR Abstract: The defaults of Philip II have attained mythical status as the origin of sovereign debt crises. The king failed to honor his debts four times during his reign. In this paper, we reassess the fiscal position of Habsburg Spain. New archival evidence allows us to derive comprehensive estimates of debt and revenue. These show that primary surpluses were sufficient to make the king’s debt sustainable for most of his reign. Spain’s debt burden was manageable up to the 1580s, and its fiscal position only deteriorated for good after the defeat of the “Invincible Armada.” We also estimate fiscal policy reaction functions, and show that Spain under the Habsburgs was at least as “responsible” as the US in the 20th century or as Britain in the 18th century. Our results suggest that the outcome of uncertain events such as wars may have more influence on a history of default than strict adherence to fiscal rules. JEL Classification Codes: H62, H63, F34, N24, N44 * For helpful comments, we thank Brian A’Hearn, Daron Acemoglu, Fernando Broner, Albert Carreras, Xavier Debrun, Marc Flandreau, Caroline Fohlin, Regina Grafe, Viktoria Hnatkovska, Alberto Martin, Paolo Mauro, David Mitch, Kris Mitchener, Joel Mokyr, Lyndon Moore, Roger Myerson, Kevin O’Rourke, Sevket Pamuk, Richard Portes, Angela Redish, Nathan Sussman, Alan M. Taylor, Francois Velde, Jaume Ventura, Marc Weidenmier, and Eugene White. Seminar audiences at American University, Harvard, Sciences Po, Hebrew University, UBC, UPF, UC Irvine, HEI Geneva, NYU-Stern, and Rutgers, as well as the EHA meetings in Austin, the CREI / CEPR Conference on “Crises – Past, Policy, and Theory”, CIFAR, NBER, CEPR –ESSIM, the BETA Workshop, and the Utrecht Workshop on Financial History offered advice and constructive criticism.
    [Show full text]
  • AP European History - Chapter 14 Europe & the World: New Encounters 1500-1800 Class Notes & Critical Thinking
    AP European History - Chapter 14 Europe & the World: New Encounters 1500-1800 Class Notes & Critical Thinking Focus Question: Why did Europeans begin to embark on voyages of discovery and expansion at the end of the fifteenth century? AGE OF EXPLORATION AND CONQUEST (“Old Imperialism”) Critical Thinking: ► Motives: “God, Glory, Gold” Which “G” do you think drove exploration . Christian Crusaders in 11th & 14th centuries created European the most? interest in Asia and Middle East . Religious desire to convert pagan peoples in the New World . Rise of nation states (“New Monarchs”) resulted in competition for empires and trade ► Portugal and Spain sought to break the Italian monopoly on trade with Asia. Mercantilism: sought colonies to extend empire & gain more resources . Technology facilitated sea travel: astrolab, better maps . Commercial revolution resulted in capitalist investments in overseas exploration Means: Technological Innovations ► Compass: directionality improvements aided navigation ► Stern-post rudder & Lateen rig: increased maneuverability & ability to sail into the wind ► Portolani: charts used for navigation . Underestimated size of globe/oceans & didn’t take into account the curvature of the earth ► Quadrant: the earliest device used to find latitude . was a quarter-circle of wood . marked in degrees, with a plumb line and a sight along one edge . first taken to sea around 1460. ► Astrolabe: Another early latitude-measuring device. disc with degrees and a movable arm with sights, first known to be at sea about 1481. Impact
    [Show full text]
  • The Price Revolution in the 16Th Century: Empirical Results from a Structural Vectorautoregression Model
    W I R T S C H A F T S W I S S E N S C H A F T L I C H E S Z E N T R U M ( W W Z ) D E R U N I V E R S I T Ä T B A S E L August 2007 The Price Revolution in the 16th Century: Empirical Results from a Structural Vectorautoregression Model WWZ Working Paper 12/07 Peter Kugler, Peter Bernholz W W Z | P E T E R S G R A B E N 5 1 | C H – 4 0 0 3 B A S E L | W W W . W W Z . U N I B A S . C H The Author(s): Prof. Dr. Peter Kugler Center of Business and Economics (WWZ), University of Basel Petersgraben 51 CH-4051 Basel Prof. Dr. Peter Bernholz Center of Business and Economics (WWZ), University of Basel Petersgraben 51 CH-4051 Basel [email protected] A publication oft the Center of Business and Economics (WWZ), University of Basel. © WWZ Forum 2007 and the author(s). Reproduction for other purposes than the personal use needs the permission of the author(s). Contact: WWZ Forum | Petersgraben 51 | CH-4003 Basel | [email protected] | www.wwz.unibas.ch The Price Revolution in the 16th Century: Empirical Results from a Structural Vectorautoregression Model Peter Kugler and Peter Bernholz WWZ /University of Basel Abstract: This paper provides empirical evidence in favor of the hypothesis that the secular price increase in the 16th century is mainly caused by money supply developments as the discovery of new mines in Latin America.
    [Show full text]
  • Money, Prices, Wages, and 'Profit Inflation' in Spain, the Southern
    Money, Prices, Wages, and ‘Profit Inflation’ in Spain, the Southern Netherlands, and England during the Price Revolution era: ca. 1520 - ca. 1650 John H. Munro Professor Emeritus of Economics University of Toronto, Toronto, Canadá [email protected] Resumo Esse artigo reexamina a famosa tese de 1929 de Earl Hamilton sobre a “Inflação de lucros” e o “nascimento do capitalismo industrial moderno” durante o período da Revolução dos Preços (1520-1650), e as opiniões de seus inúmeros críticos. Baseado em novas fontes, minhas conclusões diferem de ambos: enquanto foram encontradas mais evidências a respeito da inflação de lucros na Inglaterra do que os seus críticos poderiam admitir, nenhuma foi encontrada sobre a região do sudeste holandês, onde os salários industriais tenderam a crescer mais que os preços industriais. Este estudo conclui com um exame sucinto dos efeitos sobre a inflação em dois outros fatores de custo: terra, em termos de aluguéis reais, e capital, em termos de juros reais, os quais caíram com a inflação. Ambos os custos ficaram atrás dos preços industriais no período moderno na Inglaterra e nos Países Baixos, apesar dos juros reais ficarem mais atrás que os aluguéis reais. Palavras-chave: moeda, cunhagem (moeda metálica), Revolução dos Preços, inflação, “inflação de lucros”, “deflação de lucros”, índices de preço ao consumidor, salários reais e nominais, artesãos de construção, pedreiros, Espanha, Inglaterra, Países Baixos, indústria de grande escala. Abstract This article re-examines Earl Hamilton’s famous 1929 thesis on ‘Profit Inflation’ and the ‘birth of modern industrial capitalism’ during the Price Revolution era (c. 1520 - c. 1650), and the views of his numerous critics.
    [Show full text]
  • Isotopic Ag–Cu–Pb Record of Silver Circulation Through 16Th–18Th Century Spain
    Isotopic Ag–Cu–Pb record of silver circulation through 16th–18th century Spain Anne-Marie Desaultya,b,c,1, Philippe Telouka,b,c, Emmanuelle Albalata,b,c, and Francis Albarèdea,b,c aEcole Normale Supérieure de Lyon, F-69342 Lyon, France; bUniversité de Lyon, 69622 Villeurbanne, France; and cCentre National de la Recherche Scientifique, UMR 5276, 69364 Lyon Cedex 07, France Edited* by Donald J. DePaolo, University of California, Berkeley, CA, and approved April 13, 2011 (received for review December 6, 2010) Estimating global fluxes of precious metals is key to understanding other, which often makes provenance assignment insufficiently early monetary systems. This work adds silver (Ag) to the metals (Pb discriminating. More recently, the high precision of the multiple- and Cu) used so far to trace the provenance of coinage through collector–inductively coupled plasma mass spectrometry (MC- variations in isotopic abundances. Silver, copper, and lead isotopes ICPMS) technique (22) allowed Cu isotopes to be added to the were measured in 91 coins from the East Mediterranean Antiquity coinage tracers and a number of successful applications to the and Roman world, medieval western Europe, 16th–18th century identification of the sources of metals used for coinage have been Spain, Mexico, and the Andes and show a great potential for prove- suggested (23). Although copper is primarily alloyed with coinage nance studies. Pre-1492 European silver can be distinguished from silver to improve metal hardness and resistance, it was also used for Mexican and Andean metal. European silver dominated Spanish coin- monetary debasement (17). Copper has two stable isotopes of mass age until Philip III, but had, 80 y later after the reign of Philip V, been 63 and 65, and, in contrast to the large variations in radiogenic Pb flushed from the monetary mass and replaced by Mexican silver.
    [Show full text]
  • Transplantation of Asian Spices in the Spanish Empire 1518-1640
    Transplantation of Asian Spices in the Spanish Empire 1518-1640: Entrepreneurship, Empiricism, and the Crown Omri Bassewitch Frenkel Department of History and Classical Studies Faculty of Arts McGill University Montreal January 2017 A thesis submitted to McGill University in partial fulfillment of the requirements of the degree of Doctor of Philosophy © Omri Bassewitch Frenkel 2017 ii Abstract This dissertation focuses on the way in which Crown-sponsored attempts to transplant or domesticate commercially valuable Asian spices throughout the Spanish empire generated production, circulation and institutionalization of empirical knowledge throughout Spain’s imperial domains. Although largely unsuccessful, Spaniards perceived spice transplantations as an important component of Spain’s imperial expansion during the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries. Ventures for the introduction or domestication of spices were often initiated and run by networks of settlers, entrepreneurs, officials, friars, and natural historians, who, through empirical observation and experimentation, acquired specific expertise in that field. Successful spice transplantations attracted the attention of Spain’s imperial establishments, namely the Council of the Indies and the Casa de Contratación [known also as the “House of Trade”], which, in turn, engaged colonial administrators in Spanish America and the Philippines to call upon relevant experts for information regarding spice cultivation and processing. Consequently, experiments in the introduction and cultivation of spices were conducted in private and Crown estates in Spanish America, the Philippines and Spain, and the results thereof helped formulate Crown policies regulating spice cultivation and trade. It is maintained here that spice transplantation projects reflect an organizational culture in which policies were formed and decisions were made based on expert opinions obtained through empirical observations and experiments.
    [Show full text]