Foundations of Complexity Economics Own Experiences

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Foundations of Complexity Economics Own Experiences PERSPECTIVES I will give a personal account of how this economics was arrived at, based on my Foundations of complexity economics own experiences. I will also not attempt to survey the hundreds of studies now in the W. Brian Arthur field. Rather, I will discuss how complexity economics came to be, what logic it is based Abstract | Conventional, neoclassical economics assumes perfectly rational agents on, what its major themes are and how it (firms, consumers, investors) who face well-defined problems and arrive at optimal links with complexity and physics. I will behaviour consistent with — in equilibrium with — the overall outcome caused by talk about ideas rather than technicalities, this behaviour. This rational, equilibrium system produces an elegant economics, and build from earlier essays of myself and 12–21 but is restrictive and often unrealistic. Complexity economics relaxes these others to illustrate the key points, noting that this approach has variants22,23 and assumptions. It assumes that agents differ, that they have imperfect information forerunners24,25, and it owes much to earlier about other agents and must, therefore, try to make sense of the situation they work by Thorsten Veblen1, Herbert Simon2 face. Agents explore, react and constantly change their actions and strategies in and Friedrich Hayek26. response to the outcome they mutually create. The resulting outcome may not be in equilibrium and may display patterns and emergent phenomena not visible to The logic of the approach equilibrium analysis. The economy becomes something not given and existing but Standard economics and fundamental uncertainty. Standard economics, called constantly forming from a developing set of actions, strategies and beliefs — neoclassical economics, studies how something not mechanistic, static, timeless and perfect but organic, always outcomes form in the economy from agents’ creating itself, alive and full of messy vitality. behaviour, and, to do so, it chooses to make several standard assumptions: For the past 150 years, economic theory Smith, economists noted that aggregate • Perfect rationality. It assumes agents each has viewed agents in the economy (firms, outcomes in the economy, such as patterns solve a well- defined problem using perfectly consumers, investors) as perfectly rational of trade, market prices and quantities of rational logic to optimize their behaviour. decision makers facing well-defined goods produced and consumed, form • Representative agents. It assumes, problems and arriving at optimal behavior from individual behaviour, and individual typically, that agents are the same as consistent with — in equilibrium with — behaviour, in turn, reacts to these aggregate each other — they are ‘representative’ — the outcome caused by this behaviour. This outcomes. There is a recursive loop. and fall into one or a small number view has brought much insight. But many It is this recursive loop that makes the (or distribution) of representative types. economists1–7 have pointed out that it is economy a complex system. Complexity, • Common knowledge. It assumes all based partly on assumptions chosen for the overall subject8–11, as I see it is not agents have exact knowledge of these mathematical convenience and, over the a science, rather it is a movement within agent types, that other agents are years, have raised doubts about whether it science, and it has roots in thinking developed perfectly rational and that they too is universally applicable. Since the 1990s, in the 1970s in Brussels, Ann Arbor and share this common knowledge. economists have instead begun exploring Stuttgart. It studies how elements interacting • Equilibrium. It assumes that the the economy as an evolving complex system, in a system create overall patterns, and how aggregate outcome is consistent with and out of this exploration has come a these patterns, in turn, cause the elements to agent behaviour — it gives no incentive different approach — complexity economics. change or adapt in response. The elements for agents to change their actions. Complexity economics sees the might be cells in a cellular automaton, or cars These assumptions are by no means economy — or the parts of it that interest in traffic, or biological cells in an immune perfectly rigid but they constitute an us — as not necessarily in equilibrium, its system, and they may react to neighbouring accepted norm. They are made not because decision makers (or agents) as not super- cells’ states, or adjacent cars, or concentrations theorists necessarily believe they are true, rational, the problems they face as not of B and T cells. Whichever the case, but because they greatly simplify analysis. necessarily well-defined and the economy complexity asks how individual elements The equilibrium assumption in particular not as a perfectly humming machine but react to the current pattern they mutually is basic to neoclassical theorizing. General as an ever-changing ecology of beliefs, create, and what patterns, in turn, result. equilibrium theory asks what prices and organizing principles and behaviours. The economics I will describe here quantities of goods consumed and produced The approach, which has now spread drops the assumptions of equilibrium and would be consistent with (in equilibrium throughout the economics profession, rationality. But it did not come from an with) the overall pattern of prices and got its start largely at the Santa Fe Institute attempt to discard standard assumptions, quantities in the economy’s markets — that (SFI) in the late 1980s. But the basic ideas of rather it came from a pathway of thinking is, would pose no incentives for those overall complexity economics have an even longer about how the economy actually works. patterns to change. Classical game theory history in economics. Even before Adam So instead of giving a formal description, asks what strategies or moves of one player 136 | February 2021 | volume 3 www.nature.com/natrevphys PERSPECTIVES 100 on their ideas of what others’ predictions 90 will be, which depend, in turn, on their 80 ideas of others’ predictions, and there is an 70 infinite regress. Further, if a shared rational 60 forecasting model did exist, it would quickly 50 negate itself: if it predicted few will attend, all would go; if it predicted many will 40 attend, nobody would go. Agents, therefore, 30 Numbers attending face fundamental uncertainty: they do not 20 know how other agents will decide on their 10 forecasts, and, yet, such knowledge determines 0 attendance. The problem is ill-defined. 0 20 40 60 80 100 One can model this situation by assuming Time (weeks) agents act inductively: each creates their own Fig. 1 | Attendance at the El Farol bar in the first 100 weeks. Agents attend if they believe the total set of plausible hypotheses or predictors, attendance that week will be no more than 60. Each creates their own set of plausible hypotheses or and, every week, acts on their currently predictors of attendance, and, every week, acts on their currently most accurate one. Figure reprinted most accurate predictor. In other words, a with permission from REF.12, AAAS. framework for studying the economy should involve agents that form individual beliefs would be consistent with the strategies or first research programme8,36–38. I was asked or hypotheses — internal models (possibly moves their rivals might choose — that is, to lead this programme, and, after many several simultaneously) — about how to would be the best course of action for that discussions, we realized that we kept coming respond to the situation they are in. player. Rational expectations economics back to the same question: what would Such agents could be implemented as asks what forecasting methods would economics look like if we went beyond the small, individual computer programs that be consistent with the outcomes these standard assumptions? could differ, explore and learn to get smart. forecasting methods brought about — For one thing, agents differ39. Companies How they could do this — how they could that is, would statistically, on average, in a novel market may have different get smart — was inspired by the work of be validated by outcomes. technologies, different motivations and computer scientist John Holland, who Overall, this equilibrium approach has different resources, and they may not know had spent much of his career developing worked quite well. It is a natural way to who their competitors will be or, indeed, methods by which computer algorithms examine questions in the economy and how they will think. They are subject to what could learn to play checkers/draughts or open these up to mathematical analysis, economists call fundamental uncertainty40. chess. Holland’s algorithms could ‘recognize’ and it illuminates a wide range of issues As John Maynard Keynes described this in the current state of the game and learn to in economics. I admire its elegance; it has 1937, “the prospect of a European war… the associate appropriate moves with it. The yielded, in Paul Samuelson’s words27, an rate of interest twenty years hence…. About moves would be fairly random to start with “austere aesthetic grace.” But it severely these matters there is no scientific basis on and not very useful, but, over many games, limits what can be seen. By its definition, which to form any calculable probability the program would learn which moves equilibrium makes no allowance for whatever. We simply do not know.”41 worked in which situations, ‘explore’ new the creation of new products or new As a result, the decision problem faced moves and drop ones that did not work — arrangements, for the formation of by agents is not logically defined and, so, it would get smarter. In economic problems, new institutions, for exploring new strategies, it cannot have a logical solution. It follows agents could start with their own arbitrarily for events triggering novel events, indeed, for that rational behaviour is not well-defined. chosen or random beliefs, learn which ones history itself.
Recommended publications
  • The Visible Map and the Hidden Structure of Economics1 Angela Ambrosino*, Mario Cedrini*, John B. Davis**, Stefano Fiori*, Marco
    The Visible Map and the Hidden Structure of Economics1 Angela Ambrosino*, Mario Cedrini*, John B. Davis**, Stefano Fiori*, Marco Guerzoni*,*** and Massimiliano Nuccio* * Dipartimento di Economia e Statistica “Cognetti de Martiis”, Università di Torino, Italy ** Marquette University and University of Amsterdam *** ICRIOS, Bocconi University, Milan Abstract The paper is a first, preliminary attempt to illustrate the potentialities of topic modeling as information retrieval system helping to reduce problems of overload information in the sciences, and economics in particular. Noting that some motives for the use of automated tools as information retrieval systems in economics have to do with the changing structure of the discipline itself, we argue that the standard classification system in economics developed over a hundred years ago by the American Economics Association, the Journal of Economic Literature (JEL) codes, can easily assist in detecting the major faults of unsupervised techniques and possibly provide suggestions about how to correct them. With this aim in mind, we apply to the corpus of (some 1500) “exemplary” documents for each classification of the Journal of Economics Literature Codes indicated by the American Economics Association in the “JEL codes guide” (https://www.aeaweb.org/jel/guide/jel.php) the topic-modeling technique known as Latent Dirichlet Allocation (LDA), which serves to discover the hidden (latent) thematic structure in large archives of documents, by detecting probabilistic regularities, that is trends in language text and recurring themes in the form of co-occurring words. The ambition is to propose and interpret measures of (dis)similarity between JEL codes and the LDA topics resulting from the analysis.
    [Show full text]
  • The Complexity Economics Revolution
    The Complexity Economics Revolution J. Doyne Farmer Baillie Gifford Professor, Mathematical Institute, University of Oxford Director of Complexity Economics, Institute for New Economic Thinking at the Oxford Martin School External Professor, Santa Fe Institute Acknowledgements: I would like to thank Shanny Peer, Vince Bielski, Edward Kastenmeier and Andrew Weber for help editing, and Penny Mealy, Sander Bais, Karen Lawrence, Steve Lawton, Robb Lentz, Fotini Markopoulou and Elizabeth Rozeboom for valuable comments. This book is dedicated to my mentor, Thomas Edward Ingerson (1938 – 2019).1 INTRODUCTION ................................................................................................................... 3 Part I: WHAT IS COMPLEXITY ECONOMICS? 1 MAKING RANDOMNESS PREDICTABLE 1.1 Can we make better economic predictions? 1.2 Roulette: Random number generator or predictable physical system? 1.3 Why does the economy change? 1.4 Making chaos predictable 1.5 Is the economy chaotic? 2 THE ECONOMY IS A COMPLEX SYSTEM 2.1 What is a complex system? 2.2 Why is the economy a complex system? 2.3 How ideas from biology help us understand the economy 2.4 Economics = accounting + behavior 3 MAKING PREDICTIONS WITH NETWORKS OF SPECIALISTS 3.1 The ecology of production networks 3.2 The ecology of the economy predicts long term growth 3.3 Understanding the ecology of jobs to predict occupational unemployment 4 HOW SIMULATION HELPS US UNDERSTAND THE ECONOMY 4.1 What is a simulation? 4.2 Emergent phenomena are nonlinear 4.3 A housing bubble from the bottom-up 1 The Everyday Practice of Physics in Silver City, New Mexico. Appeared in Curious Minds: How a Child Becomes a Scientist, edited by John Brockman, 2004.
    [Show full text]
  • The Complementary Relationship Between Institutional and Complexity Economics: the Example of Deep Mechanismic Explanations
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive The complementary relationship between institutional and complexity economics: The example of deep mechanismic explanations Gräbner, Claudius 17 December 2016 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/77091/ MPRA Paper No. 77091, posted 26 Feb 2017 16:29 UTC The Complementary Relationship Between Institutional and Complexity Economics: The Example of Deep Mechanismic Explanations Claudius Gräbner [email protected] Revised version, February 2017 Abstract Analyzing economic systems from an evolutionary-institutional or a complexity perspective are two complementary approaches to economic inquiry. I discuss three arguments in favor of this hypothesis: (i) eminent institutional economists have considered the economy as what today could be considered a complex system; (ii) complexity economists lack meta- theoretical foundations which could be provided by institutionalist theory; and (iii) institutional economists could benefit from using methods of complexity economics. In this context, I argue that scholars considering the economy to be complex should seek to explain it by discovering social mechanisms instead of focusing on prediction. In order to distinguish between alternative explanations, scholars should refer to the deepness of an explanation, rather than to Occam’s razor. Keywords: agent-based computational economics, complexity economics, evolutionary- institutional economics, philosophy of science, systemism JEL Classification Codes: B25, B41, B52 Economics is undergoing a crisis: the general public becomes more and more skeptical of economic experts, student movements criticizing the current state of teaching economics gain ever more attention, and even within the scientific community criticism on the current state of affairs is growing (Earle et al. 2016). One reason for the failure of economics is its unwillingness to consider its object of inquiry as a complex system.
    [Show full text]
  • Where Does Econophysics Fit in the Complexity Revolution? Dave Colander (Middlebury College)
    Where does Econophysics fit in the Complexity Revolution? Dave Colander (Middlebury College) Early Draft Paper Prepared for the 2018 ASSA Meetings Philadelphia, PA. Jan 5th-7th Abstract A revolution is occurring in economics that is changing its scope and method. I call it the complexity revolution. The question I explore in this paper is: Where does econophysics fit in that revolution? I argue that the changing methods generally associated with the term econophysics are occurring because of advances in analytic and computational technology, and are not uniquely attributable to integrating physics and economics. Thus, using the term “econophysics” is likely to mislead people as to the nature of the complexity revolution. That complexity revolution involves an exploration of envisioning the economy as a complex evolving system driven by often unintended consequences of actions by purposeful agents. It is a vision that is more related to biology than to physics, and, at this stage of its development, is better thought of as an engineering revolution than a scientific revolution. Where does Econophysics fit in the Complexity Revolution? Dave Colander (Middlebury College) A revolution is occurring in economics. I call it the complexity revolution. Almost twenty years ago (Colander 2000) I predicted that in 50 to 100 years when historians of economics look back on the millennium, they would classify it as the end of the neoclassical era in economics and the beginning of the complexity era of economics. I stand by that prediction. The question I address in this paper is: Where does econophysics fit in that revolution?1 Before I turn to that question, let briefly summarize what I mean by the complexity revolution in economics.2 It is an expansion of the scope of economics to consider issues, such as complex dynamics, and semi-endogenous tastes and norms, that previously were assumed fixed.
    [Show full text]
  • Evolution and Complexity in Economics Revisited by Kurt Dopfer
    # 1102 Evolution and Complexity in Economics Revisited by Kurt Dopfer The Papers on Economics and Evolution are edited by the Max Planck Institute of Economics Evolutionary Economics Group, MPI Jena. For editorial correspondence, Evolutionary Economics Group please contact: [email protected] Kahlaische Str. 10 07745 Jena, Germany ISSN 1430-4716 Fax: ++49-3641-686868 by the author #1102 Evolution and Complexity in Economics Revisited by Kurt Dopfer University of St Gallen, Switzerland 1 #1102 Abstract The paper discusses recent trends in the sister sciences of evolutionary economics and complexity economics. It suggests that a unifying approach that marries the two strands is needed when reconstructing economics as a science capable of tackling the two key questions of the discipline: complex economic structure and evolutionary economic change. Physics, biology and the cultural sciences are investigated in terms of their usefulness as both paradigmatic orientation and as toolbox. The micro–meso–macro architecture delineated puts meso centre stage, highlighting its significance as structure component and as process component alike, thereby allowing us to handle the key issues of structure and change. 2 #1102 1 The rise of evolutionary economics The last three decades have seen an upsurge in the number of publications addressing themes that have come to be grouped under the heading of ‘evolutionary economics’. In a recent bibliometric account comprising the abstracts of articles published in all economic journals over the past half-century, Sandra Silva and Aurora Teixeira have been documenting the impressive magnitudes and structural dynamic of this trend – a trend that has accelerated tremendously in the last two decades, considering that 90 per cent of this body of research is recorded as having been published since 1990 (Silva and Teixeira 2009; EconLit database).
    [Show full text]
  • Short Waves in Hungary, 1923 and 1946: Persistence, Chaos, and (Lack Of) Control
    Short Waves in Hungary, 1923 and 1946: Persistence, Chaos, and (Lack of) Control Christopher A. Hartwell Professor of Financial Systems Resilience Bournemouth University, the Business School Bournemouth, UK [email protected] and Professor Kozminski University Warsaw, Poland ABSTRACT Monetary policies follow a complex and chaotic process, one that is enhanced when monetary growth is taken to the extreme, as in hyperinflation. While we have a basic understanding of the complex dynamics of hyperinflation, a less-explored phenomenon accompanying hyperinflationary episodes is the effect that they have on institutional development. Building on recent advances in economic history examining monetary policy and institutions, this analysis uses more explicit recourse to complexity theory and in particular complex adaptive systems to examine two separate hyperinflationary episodes in Hungary, 1923 and 1946. Delving into the institutional and cultural roots of the inflationary policies of the Hungarian government and detailing the institutional effects which succeeded hyperinflation, this paper shows that the twin experiences of Hungary were both chaotic and created a chaotic and complex aftermath, the results of which are still being felt. Indeed, Hungary’s 1923 and especially its 1946 hyperinflation shows that some economic chaos cannot be restrained by political institutions and in fact the institutions themselves were changed. When staring into the abyss, Hungary also found that the abyss stared back. JEL Codes: E42, N14, B52 Keywords: hyperinflation, complex adaptive systems, chaos, monetary policy, Hungary ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS: The author has a huge debt of gratitude to Ladislav Krištoufek at the Institute of Economic Studies, Charles University, for his assistance in the chaos calculations.
    [Show full text]
  • Can Neoclassical Economics Handle Complexity? the Fallacy of the Oil Spot Dynamic Magda Fontana
    Can Neoclassical Economics Handle Complexity? The Fallacy of the Oil Spot Dynamic Magda Fontana To cite this version: Magda Fontana. Can Neoclassical Economics Handle Complexity? The Fallacy of the Oil Spot Dynamic. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, Elsevier, 2010, 76 (3), pp.584. 10.1016/j.jebo.2010.08.010. hal-00911826 HAL Id: hal-00911826 https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-00911826 Submitted on 30 Nov 2013 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. Accepted Manuscript Title: Can Neoclassical Economics Handle Complexity? The Fallacy of the Oil Spot Dynamic Author: Magda Fontana PII: S0167-2681(10)00163-0 DOI: doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2010.08.010 Reference: JEBO 2590 To appear in: Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization Received date: 17-9-2008 Revised date: 25-8-2010 Accepted date: 26-8-2010 Please cite this article as: Fontana, M., Can Neoclassical Economics Handle Complexity? The Fallacy of the Oil Spot Dynamic, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization (2010), doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2010.08.010 This is a PDF file of an unedited manuscript that has been accepted for publication.
    [Show full text]
  • Whither Economic Complexity? a New Heterodox Economic Paradigm Or Just Another Variation Within the Mainstream?
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Heise, Arne Working Paper Whither economic complexity? A new heterodox economic paradigm or just another variation within the mainstream? ZÖSS Discussion Paper, No. 58 Provided in Cooperation with: University of Hamburg, Centre for Economic and Sociological Studies (CESS/ZÖSS) Suggested Citation: Heise, Arne (2016) : Whither economic complexity? A new heterodox economic paradigm or just another variation within the mainstream?, ZÖSS Discussion Paper, No. 58, Universität Hamburg, Zentrum für Ökonomische und Soziologische Studien (ZÖSS), Hamburg This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/148602 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available
    [Show full text]
  • Complexity Modelling in Economics: the State of Art
    Complexity modelling in Economics: the state of art. Bruna Bruno, Marisa Faggini, Anna Parziale Email: [email protected], [email protected], [email protected] Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche e Statistiche Dipartimento di Scienze Giuridiche University of Salerno Abstract The crisis happened in the world in the last years, describing a whole of interdependencies and interactions, highlighted the theory’s fundamental flaws of neoclassical economic theory: its unedifying focus on prediction and, above all, its inability to explain how the economy really works. It is the time to investigate economic phenomena not as derived from deterministic, predictable and mechanistic dynamics, but as history- dependent, organic and always evolving processes. Because this view implies new challenges and opportunities for policy, we will focus the attention on innovative components of Complexity Theory for the study of economics and the evaluation of public policies. Keywords: complex systems, economics, public policies Introduction The crisis happened in the world in the last years, describing a whole of interdependencies and interactions, highlighted the fundamental flaws of neoclassical economic theory: its unedifying focus on prediction and, above all, its inability to explain how the economy really works. The reductionist approach, applied by this theory, overlooks the dependencies or interconnections among elements and their influence on macroeconomic behaviour, and it too often failed as an analytical approach (Morin, 1992). Its goal is to reduce the overall behaviour of a system to a number of essential elements and studying disjointedly these parts, the system can be analysed in every detail. The reconstructed behaviour of this system is obtained just re-aggregating its components (principle of overlap).
    [Show full text]
  • Rethinking Economics Using Complexity Theory
    Rethinking Economics Using Complexity Theory Dirk Helbing, ETH Zurich, Department of Humanities, Social and Political Sciences, Clausiusstrasse 50, 8092 Zurich, Switzerland Alan Kirman, Professor Emeritus of Economics, Aix Marseille Université and Ecole des Hautes Etudes en Sciences Sociales, GREQAM, Centre de la Vieille Charité. 2, rue de la vieille charité, 13236 Marseille Cedex 02, France In this paper we argue that if we want to find a more satisfactory approach to tackling the major socio-economic problems we are facing, we need to thoroughly rethink the basic assumptions of macroeconomics and financial theory. Making minor modifications to the standard models to remove “imperfections” is not enough, the whole framework needs to be revisited.1 Let us here enumerate some of the standard assumptions and postulates of economic theory. 1. An economy is an equilibrium system. In other words, it is a system in which all markets systematically clear at each point of time, but where the equilibrium may be perturbed, from time to time by exogenous shocks. 2. Selfish or greedy behaviour of individuals yields a result that is beneficial to society – a modern, widespread, but inaccurate reformulation of the principle of the “invisible hand”. 3. Individuals and companies decide rationally. By this it is meant that individuals optimize under the constraints they are facing and that their choices satisfy some standard consistency axioms. 4. The behaviour of all the agents together can be treated as 1 David Colander, Michael Goldberg, Armin Haas, Katarina Juselius, Alan Kirman, Thomas Lux and Brigitte Sloth, The Financial Crisis and the Systemic Failure of the Economics Profession, Critical Review, Volume 21, Issue 2-3, 2009, Pages 249-267; Alan Kirman, The Economic Crisis is a Crisis for Economic Theory, CESifo Economic Studies (2010) 56 (4): 498-535; Andrew G.
    [Show full text]
  • The Role of Entropy in the Development of Economics
    entropy Article The Role of Entropy in the Development of Economics Aleksander Jakimowicz Department of World Economy, Institute of Economics, Polish Academy of Sciences, Palace of Culture and Science, 1 Defilad Sq., 00-901 Warsaw, Poland; [email protected] Received: 25 February 2020; Accepted: 13 April 2020; Published: 16 April 2020 Abstract: The aim of this paper is to examine the role of thermodynamics, and in particular, entropy, for the development of economics within the last 150 years. The use of entropy has not only led to a significant increase in economic knowledge, but also to the emergence of such scientific disciplines as econophysics, complexity economics and quantum economics. Nowadays, an interesting phenomenon can be observed; namely, that rapid progress in economics is being made outside the mainstream. The first significant achievement was the emergence of entropy economics in the early 1970s, which introduced the second law of thermodynamics to considerations regarding production processes. In this way, not only was ecological economics born but also an entropy-based econometric approach developed. This paper shows that non-extensive cross-entropy econometrics is a valuable complement to traditional econometrics as it explains phenomena based on power-law probability distribution and enables econometric model estimation for non-ergodic ill-behaved (troublesome) inverse problems. Furthermore, the entropy economics has accelerated the emergence of modern econophysics and complexity economics. These new directions of research have led to many interesting discoveries that usually contradict the claims of conventional economics. Econophysics has questioned the efficient market hypothesis, while complexity economics has shown that markets and economies function best near the edge of chaos.
    [Show full text]
  • Complexity and Policy Making I Ty an Ty D P Ol Ic Y Mak I Ng
    OECD INSIGHTS EDITED BY PATRICK LOVE AND JULIA STOCKDAle-OTÁROLA AND JU AND EDIT E D BY PATRICK LOV PATRICK D BY L IA STOCKDA IA le - O E , TÁRO L A DEBATE THE ISSUES: DEBATE THE ISSUES: COMPLEX ISSUES: THE DEBATE COMPLEXITY AND POLICY MAKING I TY AN D P OL ic Y MAK I NG OECD Insights Debate the Issues: Complexity and policy making This work is published under the responsibility of the Secretary-General of the OECD. The opinions expressed and arguments employed herein do not necessarily reflect the official views of OECD member countries. This document and any map included herein are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area. Please cite this publication as: OECD (2017), Debate the Issues: Complexity and policy making, OECD Insights, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264271531-en. ISBN 978-92-64-27152-4 (print) ISBN 978-92-64-27153-1 (PDF) ISBN 978-92-64-27158-6 (epub) Series: OECD Insights ISSN 1993-6745 (print) ISSN 1993-6753 (online) Revised version, June 2017 Details of revisions available at: http://www.oecd.org/about/publishing/Corrigendum_Debate_the_Issues- Complexity_and_policy_making.pdf Corrigenda to OECD publications may be found on line at: www.oecd.org/about/publishing/corrigenda.htm. © OECD 2017 You can copy, download or print OECD content for your own use, and you can include excerpts from OECD publications, databases and multimedia products in your own documents, presentations, blogs, websites and teaching materials, provided that suitable acknowledgement of OECD as source and copyright owner is given.
    [Show full text]